• Aucun résultat trouvé

Computing the short-run equilibria

Dans le document The DART-Europe E-theses Portal (Page 163-168)

5.3 Short-run equilibrium

5.3.2 Computing the short-run equilibria

We restrict our attention to symmetric short-run equilibria. The formal defi-nition is the following.

Definition 5.1. A short-run equilibrium at timetis defined by a vector of in-vestment decisions(δtN, δTt )∈[0,1]2, a price vector (pt, wt), and an allocation of resources (gtN, gtT, lt) satisfying:

• the market equilibrium for non-tradable goods (5.4),

• the equation of perfect labor mobility (5.5),

3δit1 because of the borrowing constraint.

Short-run equilibrium

• the labor market equilibrium (5.6),

• the investment functions of both sectors (5.10),

and such that no entrepreneur would get a strictly higher instantaneous rate of return by changing its investment decisionδti.

A short-run equilibrium depends on the endogenous state variablesκt,dNt ,dTt , KtT, and the exogenous state variableLt. Note that the decisions (δtN, δtT), the real exchange rate pt, and the investment rates (gtN, gtT) can be determined independently of the wage rate wt and the labor composition lt. Then, lt is given by equation (5.5) andwt by equation (5.6). Therefore, we can focus on the determination of the former variables.

We classify short-run equilibria according to the value taken by the real exchange rate pt. We distinguish equilibria H corresponding to pHt > qN from equilibriaLcorresponding to pLt < qN. Ahigh equilibriumH is charac-terized by an appreciated real exchange rate, which entails a high return on investment in the non-tradable sector (ρN Ht > r). Entrepreneurs of this sector invest in productive capital and finance part of this investment by borrowing abroad (δNt = 1). On the contrary, alow equilibrium L is characterized by a depreciated real exchange rate, which entails a low instantaneous return on investment in the non-tradable sector (ρN Lt < r). Due to their short time hori-zon, the entrepreneurs from sector N do not invest in production (δNt = 0).

Instead of borrowing, they send their internal funds abroad to get the world rate r, so that their net debt decreases. In accordance with stylized facts 1, 2, 3 and 4, we identify equilibriaH with tranquil times and equilibriaLwith crisis times. The following proposition gives conditions for the existence and uniqueness of both kinds of equilibria.

Proposition 5.1.

Define κ¯t and κt by the following equations:

¯ κt =

βAT +ηqN αAT −rdTt 1−h+ηqN (1−β)ANqN −ηqN αqNAN −rdNt

1−h+ηqN

, (5.11)

κt =

βAT +ηqN αAT −rdTt 1−h+ηqN

(1−β)qNAN . (5.12)

There is a unique equilibrium H such that pHt > qN if and only ifκt <¯κt. There is a unique equilibrium L such that pLt < qN if and only if κt > κt. Proof. See appendix E.1.

In all the following we assume that κt < κ¯t to ensure that equilibrium H always exists.4

Since κt <κ¯t, equilibria H and Lsimultaneously exist when κt < κt <κ¯t. This situation of multiple equilibria makes it possible to model balance-of-payments crises as self-fulfilling real depreciations where a jump from the high equilibrium H to the low equilibrium L is triggered by a pure change in expectations. For example, as usual in the literature on multiple equilibria, agents can use a sunspot variable to coordinate on one of the two equilibria.

Suppose there is sunspot variable St ∈ {0,1} that follows a Markov process and denote ω ∈ (0,1) the instantaneous probability of transition between 1 and 0. A possible coordination scheme could be the following: agents co-ordinate on equilibrium L when St = 0 and κt > κt and on equilibrium H in all other cases. Then, if the economy is in equilibrium H at time t, the probability that it falls into a crisis between t and t+dt is equal to 0 when κt ≤κt and to ω dt when κt > κt. We say the economy is financially fragile when the condition κt > κt is satisfied.

Figure 5.1 graphically illustrates the existence of multiple equilibria.5 It represents the equilibria as the intersection of two relationships between gNt andpt. The II schedule corresponds to the investment decision in sector N and the NN schedule corresponds to the market clearing condition for N goods.6 Both relationships are increasing. On the one hand, a higher investment gNt induces a higher demand for N goods and provokes a real appreciation.

On the other hand, a higher relative price pt increases the profits of sector N and, through the borrowing constraint, the level of investment gtN. It also increases the return on investment in this sector, which creates a discontinuity at pt =qN.

What does the balance-of-payments crisis produced by this model look like? It consists of a sudden real depreciation and a decrease in investment.

4We will see that this is the case in the stationary state.

5We have not represented the discontinuity atpt=qT since it does not produce multiple equilibria.

6The equation of the NN schedule is gtN = 1−βη ANηpβAtκTt 1{pt<qT} αAT−rdTt

κt(1−h+ηpt) and the equation of the II schedule isgtN=1{pt>qN}αptAN−rdNt

1−h+ηpt .

Short-run equilibrium

pLt qN pHt pt

NN gNt

α ηAN

II

1−β η AN

H

L

Figure 5.1: Short-run equilibrium of the market for non-tradable goods.

The overall decrease in investment—which is necessary to provoke the fall of the relative price pt as can be seen from equation (5.4)—hides a strong sectoral asymmetry. Investment increases in sector T, due to the lower unitary installation cost ηpt, and stops in sector N, because the instantaneous rate of return ρNt falls below r. There is also a reversal of the capital account of sector N, since entrepreneurs send their profits abroad and stop issuing debt. Notice that the stop of capital inflows to the non-tradable sector is a consequence, and not a cause, of the crisis. The possibility of capital outflows from entrepreneurs, and not sudden stops, is the key to our crisis mechanism.

Because of the borrowing constraint, entrepreneurs of sector N are still able to service their past debt during a crisis (see appendix E.2).

The multiplicity of equilibria comes from a strategic complementarity be-tween investment decisions within sector N. As more entrepreneurs invest in productive capital, the increased demand for N goods provokes an apprecia-tion of the real exchange rate. This raises the instantaneous profitability of sector N, which is the pay-off perceived by myopic entrepreneurs for investing in production. Note that entrepreneurs from sector N could invest during the crisis. The stop of investment is due to the unwillingness, and not to the inability, to invest. In this regard, the crisis mechanism is similar to the one developed in chapter 3 and differs from chapter 4. It is compatible with stylized fact 5.

Our main point is that this reinforcing mechanism only produces multiple equilibria when κt exceeds κt. A large non-tradable sector, relative to the size of the tradable sector, destabilizes the economy by making it financially fragile. Here is the rationale behind this result. When the investment gNt falls down to zero, one of the components of demand vanishes and a fall of the price pt is necessary to clear the market. The lower the residual fraction of demand (consumption and investment stemming from sector T), the more depreciated the new real exchange rate. Thus, the demand stemming from sector T stabilizes the movements of the real exchange rate. It is clear from equation (5.4) that a rise inκt tends to increase the importance of the unstable components of demand compared to the stabilizing demand from sector T.

We conclude this section with some comparative statics results. A rise in κt moves the NN schedule upward and leaves the II schedule unchanged so that both pHt and pLt decrease (except if pHt = qT). A rise in h moves down the part of the NN schedule where p < qT and moves up the part of the II schedule where p > qN, which increases bothpHt and pLt. Therefore, we have

κtpt < 0 and ∂hpt > 0 in both equilibria H and L. These results deserve a few comments:

• A higher level of financial development h allows the entrepreneurs to borrow more abroad, which results in a higher demand for N goods because of the installation cost of capital. In the short run, the economy adjusts to these larger capital inflows with a real appreciation.

• A larger relative size of the non-tradable sector κt leads to a real de-preciation because it increases the supply of non-tradable goods with regard to its demand, a mechanism at work in the long-run adjustment to capital inflows. Note that this mechanism ensures that crisis times cannot last forever. If the economy is in equilibrium L, investment only takes place in the tradable sector so that κt slowly moves downward.

This increases pL and ρN and eventually makes it profitable to resume investing in sector N.

Finally, let us notice that∂hκt >0. A more developed financial system dimin-ishes the size of the financial fragility zone. This is due to the fact that it fuels a higher investment gtT in sector T, which increases the stabilizing component of demand and smoothes the fall of the relative price in case investment sud-denly stops in sector N. On the contrary, we have ∂dTt κ < 0. A rise in the corporate debt of sector T increases the size of the financial fragility zone.

Long-run dynamics

5.4 Long-run dynamics

The long-run dynamics consists in the evolution of the five state variables (κt, dNt , dTt , KtT, Lt). The dynamics of (κt, dNt , dTt ) can be determined inde-pendently of those of KtT and Lt. Then, an initial condition on K0T and the exogenous trajectory of Lt complete the description and determine the evolution of the wage rate wt.

In this section, we follow the same strategy as in chapter 4 and study the lucky long-run dynamics, defined as a trajectory where the economy is always in the high equilibriumH and no crisis occurs. Then, in the next section, we will determine whether this lucky dynamics go through periods of financial fragility, i.e. periods for which the relative size of the non-tradable sector κt is strictly greater than the threshold κt. In particular, we will determine conditions under which the lucky stationary state is financially fragile. Of course, should a crisis occur in the stationary state or along the lucky dynam-ics, the path followed by the economy would not be a stationary state or a lucky dynamics any more. As we do not wish to elaborate on the dynamics of an economy in crisis, that is, in equilibrium L, we begin this section by describing them briefly.

Dans le document The DART-Europe E-theses Portal (Page 163-168)