• Aucun résultat trouvé

Risk and Schooling Decisions in Rural Madagascar: a Panel Data Analysis

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "Risk and Schooling Decisions in Rural Madagascar: a Panel Data Analysis"

Copied!
32
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

DOCUMENT DE TRAVAIL DT/2006-08

Risk and Schooling Decisions in

Rural Madagascar: a Panel Data

Analysis

Flore GUBERT

(2)

RISK AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS IN RURAL MADAGASCAR: A PANEL

DATA ANALYSIS

1

Flore Gubert IRD, DIAL, Paris

gubert@dial.prd.fr

Anne-Sophie Robilliard IRD, DIAL, Paris

robilliard@dial.prd.fr

Document de travail DIAL

Juin 2006

ABSTRACT

Most households in rural Madagascar are engaged in agriculture and derive a large share of their income from the production of food or cash crops and from animal husbandry. However, agricultural yields can be extremely volatile due to weather conditions, pests, insects, rodents and other calamities. As a result, households record large fluctuations in their incomes that must be dealt with. Since the usual consumption-smoothing market mechanisms are quite limited in the Malagasy context, households need to rely on nonmarket mechanisms or to adopt multi-faceted strategies to cope with risk. In this paper, we examine the possibility that parents obtain informal income insurance by letting their children work. We test this hypothesis by examining the relationship between household income shocks and human capital investment in children. In particular, we investigate whether children’s propensity to join school and to drop out of school responds to transient shocks. We also investigate issues such as gender and intrahousehold resource allocation.

Key Words: Schooling decisions; Transitory shocks; Risk-coping strategies.

RESUME

La plupart des ménages ruraux malgaches tirent l’essentiel de leurs revenus de l’agriculture et sont exposés à un fort degré d’incertitude en raison de la fréquence et de l’intensité des aléas frappant les champs de culture ou les troupeaux. En l’absence de marchés du crédit ou de l’assurance, des moyens alternatifs pour éliminer ou atténuer les conséquences défavorables de cette incertitude doivent être trouvés par les ménages. Dans cet article, nous envisageons la possibilité que la mise au travail des enfants constitue un mécanisme de gestion des risques. Afin de tester cette hypothèse, nous examinons les déterminants de la scolarisation en cycle primaire d’un échantillon d’enfants issus de ménages ruraux. Nous examinons notamment le rôle des chocs de revenu subis par les ménages sur les probabilités d’entrée (dans) et de sortie hors de l’école de leurs membres en âge d’être scolarisés, en portant une attention particulière aux questions de genre et d’allocation intra-ménage des ressources. Les résultats indiquent que les chocs transitoires de revenu ont un impact significatif sur la probabilité de sortie de l’école mais pas sur la probabilité d’entrer à l’école. Cela suggère que la déscolarisation des enfants les plus âgés constitue un mécanisme de gestion du risque pour les ménages ruraux.

Mots-clés : Décision de scolarisation ; Chocs transitoires ; Stratégies de gestion des risques JEL Code : D91; I21; J24; O55.

1 We would like to thank Isabelle Droy, François Roubaud and INSTAT for making the data available. We thank Philippe De Vreyer for

providing the rainfall data in a user-friendly form. We thank seminar participants at the AFSE conference in Clermont-Ferrand, at the C3ED workshop on child labour, at the CSAE conference and at DIAL for helpful comments. Support from the French Ministry of Research through ACI ”Sociétés et cultures dans le développement durable” is gratefully acknowledged.

(3)

Contents

1. INTRODUCTION ... 4

2. RISK AND SCHOOLING DECISIONS : A REVIEW ... 5

3. EMPIRICAL STRATEGY ... 7

3.1. The first step ... 8

3.2. The second step ... 9

4. DATA AND DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS ... 10

5. EMPIRICAL RESULTS... 14

6. CONCLUSION ... 17

REFERENCES ... 19

List of tables

Table 1 : Dynamic attrition logit model with focus on lagged shocks ... 21

Table 2 : Frequency of shocks ... 22

Table 3a : Magnitude of shocks on rice fields, by year ... 23

Table 3b : Magnitude of shocks on cassava fields, by year ... 23

Table 4 : Probability to drop out from school and shocks... 24

Table 5 : Pairwise correlation of schooling rate, per capita income mean and deviation, and rainfall deviation (village level) ... 25

Table 6 : Summary statistics of variables used in income regressions ... 26

Table 7 : Fixed effects estimates of the determinants of income... 27

Table 8 : Summary statistics of variables used in entrant and dropout models... 28

Table 9 : Conditional logit of entrant model ... 29

Table 10 : Conditional logit of dropout model ... 30

Liste of figures

Figure 1 : Probability of school entry by gender ... 31

Figure 2 : Probability of school dropout by gender ... 31

(4)

1. Introduction

Most households in rural Madagascar are engaged in agriculture and derive a large share of their income from the production of food or cash crops and from animal husbandry. However, agricultural yields can be extremely volatile due to weather conditions, pests, insects, rodents and other calamities. As a result, households record large fluctuations in their incomes that must be dealt with. Since the usual consumption-smoothing market mechanisms are quite limited in the Malagasy context, households need to rely on nonmarket mechanisms or to adopt multi-faceted strategies to cope with risk. Such coping strategies include drawing down liquid assets, liquidating productive assets, borrowing from formal or informal lenders, increasing market hours-of-work, etc. In this paper, we examine the possibility that parents obtain an informal income insurance by letting their children work. Because our data set does not provide us with detailed information on child labor, we test this hypothesis by examining the relationship between household income shocks and human capital investment in children. In particular, we investigate whether children’s propensity to join school and to drop out of school responds to transient shocks1. We also investigate issues such as gender and intrahousehold resource allocation.

Almost no studies except Jacoby & Skoufias (1997) for India, Jensen (2000) for Côte d’Ivoire and Sawada (2003) for Pakistan have empirically explored the connection between financial market imperfections and human capital investment. Yet this question is important for at least two reasons. First, it can shed a new light on what determines child labor and may consequently suggest new possible remedies for it. Indeed, if households’ incapacity to handle

1It is not obvious, however, that for children school and work compete for time. Increasing hours of work may

(5)

temporary income shocks appears to be a more important determinant of school attendance than poverty, it suggests that programs aimed at helping poor parents handle emergencies may be more effective in keeping poor children in school than program aiming either at reducing poverty itself or at reducing school costs for the poor as a whole. Second, examining this question can clarify one of the mechanisms through which transient poverty causes chronic poverty.

Using five rounds of household panel data from four regions of Madagascar, we find that transitory income affects children’s school dropout behaviors significantly. Our analysis also suggests that parents in our sample favor girls in terms of education. Although this last result might appear surprising, it is actually in line with existing studies on education in Madagascar which generally find a ”negative” gender gap when focusing on school enrollment rates (see e.g. Cogneau, Dumont, Glick, Razafindrakoto, Razafindravonona, Randretsa & Roubaud 2003). Lastly, we find weak evidence of resource competition among siblings.

The paper is organized as follows. We begin by briefly reviewing the literature on the use of child labor as a form of self-insurance. The empirical strategy is then outlined in section 3. In section 4, we describe our data. In section 5, we present the results. Section 6 concludes the paper and suggests directions for future work.

2. Risk and Schooling Decisions: a Review

If the role of family income in determining child school attendance, enrollment or attainment has been widely explored in the literature, the impact of income fluctuations on the dynamics of school attendance and/or on child labor is comparatively a neglected issue even though recent empirical studies have been partially filling the gap for the last ten years. Using the

(6)

ICRISAT data set on a panel of Indian rural households, Jacoby & Skoufias (1997) examine whether fluctuations in family income affect school attendance in the face of financial market incompleteness. They find that child school attendance does decline when poor households are hit by a shock. They also find that school attendance is more responsive to aggregate than to idiosyncratic shocks. Using data from the Côte d’Ivoire Living Standard Survey (CLSS), Jensen (2000) find that school enrollment rates declined by between one-third and one-half in regions that had adverse weather shocks in 1986 and 1987. Sawada (2003) examines the role of permanent and transitory income changes in educational investments using household panel data from rural Pakistan. Unlike Jacoby & Skoufias (1997), which analyzes the variability of school attendance, the focus is on school entry and dropout behaviors. Results suggest that transitory income affects children’s school entry and dropout behaviors significantly and that schooling response to transitory income is consistently larger for daughters than sons. In a forthcoming paper using a panel data set in one region of Tanzania, Beegle, Dehejia & Gatti (2006) find that transitory income shocks lead to increases in child labor and to decreases in school attendance. They also find that households with assets are able to offset approximatively 80% of these shocks.

The question of whether volatile income in an environment of imperfect insurance or capital markets leads to lower investments in education has also been empirically investigated in urban areas. Using longitudinal employment survey data collected in metropolitan Brazil, Duryea, Lam & Levison (2003) find that an unemployment shock to the household head significantly increases the probability that a child enters the labor force and decreases the probability that she advances in school. Their estimates suggest that these effects can be large, with increase of as much as 60% in the probability of entering employment for 16 year-old girls. By contrast,

(7)

Parker & Skoufias (2006) find that, in urban Mexico, time devoted by boys and girls to schooling is unaffected by labor market shocks. However, when examining the effect of the same shocks on children’s school attendance in the next school year, the authors find a significant decrease in the probability that the children will continue. The authors also find evidence of more effective efforts to protect family investments on children’s human capital for boys than girls.

Finally, several studies have examined the role of cash transfers on households’ school en-rollment and child work decision (see e.g. Skoufias & Parker 2001, Bourguignon, Ferreira & Leite 2003, Schultz 2004, de Janvry, Finan & Sadoulet 2006). In a forthcoming paper, de Jan-vry et al. (2006) examine whether children who benefit from Progresa conditional transfers in rural Mexico are protected from the impacts of shocks on school enrollment and work. They find that shocks such as unemployment or illness of the household head have large effects in taking children out of school and that because of strong state dependence, children who dropped out of school are less likely to subsequently re-enroll. They also find that the Progresa transfers completely protect children from the impact of shocks on school enrollment.

3. Empirical Strategy

Our goal is to estimate the extent to which school attendance responds to income fluctuations under missing or incomplete credit and/or insurance markets. We do so in two steps. We first derive an estimate of agricultural income shocks. We then regress schooling decisions (either to enter into school or to dropout of school) on this estimate and other explanatory variables such as child age.

(8)

3.1.The first step

We adopt Paxson (1992)’s approach to construct our measure of transitory agriculture income shocks by using the following regression equation:

Yirt= β0+ Xit1+ Xit2+ Xrt3+ (XitPOXrtT)β4+ λi+ θt+ εTit

where Yirt denotes agricultural income accruing to household i in region r in year t. XitP is a vector of physical and human assets - such as the demographic structure of the household, detailed information on its land holdings and their quality, and physical assets; XT

it is a vector

of household-specific shock variables and XT

rt is a set of regionspecific shocks such as rainfall

-that affect transitory income. XP it

N XT

rt is a cross-product term that is included in recognition

of the fact that the effect of unexpected rainfall on agricultural income depends on farm char-acteristics. Unobservable determinants of the permanent component of income are captured by the household fixed effect λi. Finally, θtis a time-specific fixed effect and εirt is a random error

term. The fitted value of the third and fifth terms in the right-hand side, i.e., the fitted value of XT

itβ2+ (XitP

N XT

rt)β4, provides a consistent estimate of a component of income for household

i in period t that is transitory and could not be anticipated. It is this measure of transitory income that will be used as a source of variation in our subsequent specifications.

Our specification differs in three ways from Paxson (1992)’s. First, in Paxson’s income equation, rainfall is not interacted with farm characteristics so that heterogeneity in households’ land holdings is not accounted for in her measure of transitory income shocks. Second, Paxson uses cross-sectional data on farm household income and cannot control for unobserved household fixed effect. Third, Paxson ignores other possible types of shock (e.g., pests, thefts and rodents)

(9)

that can potentially strongly (and unexpectedly) influence agricultural income.

3.2.The second step

The longitudinal structure of our data set allows us to classify the sampled children into one of the following mutually exclusive categories: (i) no schooling; (ii) entrant; (iii) continuing schooling and (iv) dropout. We follow Sawada (2003)’s approach and construct simple models of binary dependent variables related to two sequential schooling decisions: whether to enter into school and whether to drop out from school. We define two binary variables as follows:

ENTit = 1 if child enters school at time t

= 0 if child does not enter school at time t DRPit = 1 if child drops out of school at time t

= 0 if child stays in school at time t

The entrant model is conditional on the sample of children without previous schooling (S∗

it−1 ≤ 0), i.e., children belonging to categories (i) or (ii), while the dropout model is

con-ditional on the sample of children with some schooling (Sit−1 > 0), i.e., children belonging to categories (iii) or (iv).

(10)

The relevant conditional probabilities can be written as: P (ENTit= 0) = P ¡ Sit≤ 0 | Sit−1≤ 0¢= 1 − F (αh+ Xitπ) (3.1) P (ENTit= 1) = P¡Sit∗ > 0 | Sit∗−1≤ 0 ¢ = F (αh+ Xitπ) (3.2) P (DRPit= 0) = P ¡ Sit> 0 | Sit−1> 0¢= 1 − F (γh+ Xitβ) (3.3) P (DRPit= 1) = P ¡ Sit≤ 0 | Sit−1> 0¢= F (γh+ Xitβ) (3.4)

where αh and γh represent household specific fixed effects and X is a vector of independent

variables including the transient income estimate constructed in step 1. We estimate these models as discrete response models with household fixed effects assuming that F (•) is a logistic distribution function.

4. Data and Descriptive Statistics

The data come from a survey jointly administered by Madagascar’s national statistical institute (INSTAT) and the Institut de Recherche pour le Developpement (IRD) through the Project MADIO (see e.g. Droy, Ratovoarinony & Roubaud 2000). The survey has been conducted every year since 1995 in four distinct regions of the country. These regions differ in terms of soil quality, annual rainfall pattern, and population densities. They were chosen because each of them illustrates at least one important issue in terms of agricultural development. In the first round, approximately 500 households were randomly chosen in each region from an exhaustive list. These households were surveyed again every year, and households that had moved or were unwilling to be surveyed were replaced by new households with similar characteristics from the

(11)

same region. The resulting sample consists of 5,046 households surveyed over the period 1995 to 2002. Unfortunately, not all survey rounds can be used for our study since some of the questions related to education that we use to construct our in- and out-of-school variables were not asked in 1996. Furthermore, only households with school-aged children are included in our sample. As a result, the sample we use consists of about 2,200 households surveyed at least twice over the period 1997 to 2002.

The data set has several features that make it particularly appropriate for the proposed analysis. First, it provides rich and reliable information on production, assets and personal characteristics of all household members including their school enrollment status. It also includes detailed information on crop losses in each of the six rounds.

An important issue in the empirical analysis of panel data is the extent of sample attrition. Even though there is no necessary relationship between the size of sample loss from attrition and the existence or magnitude of attrition bias, we need to explore the determinants of panel attrition and investigate whether it is selectively related to some variables of interest. In partic-ular, given the focus of the paper, namely the occurence of shocks and their impact on schooling decisions, we need to examine whether the likelihood of household or individual attrition is cor-related with shocks. In order to do so, we conduct a dynamic attrition analysis by estimating attrition hazards, i.e., probabilities of exiting the sample in the current period conditional on being in the sample in the previous period, as a function of all the lagged variables of interest. The model to be estimated is as follows:probabilities of exiting the sample in the current period conditional on being in the sample in the previous period

(12)

where the outcome variable Ait equals 1 if the individual attrites at time t, conditional on still

being respondent at time t−1 (0 otherwise). It is a function of past shocks such as income shocks or demographic shocks. The vector Xit−1 are lagged individual characteristics, with coefficient vector θ, and vit is an error term. In the empirical analysis, we also include year dummies interacted with village dummies. Estimates are shown in Table 1. They reveal that attrition propensity is not affected by our measures of shocks, indicating that attrition bias should not be a concern in our analysis. We likewise find that these variables are not significant predictors of entry into the sample.2

In the first part of the empirical section, the dependent variable is a measure of income that includes both cash and imputed value for in-kind income from various sources (farm production which includes food and cash crops and animal husbandry; non farm production which includes forestry, handicrafts, fishing and small trade; earnings from wage work; and rents from land). Turning to our measures of income shocks, different types and levels of risk are considered. First, we use household level information on negative shocks resulting from pests, rodents, birds or locusts. For each type of crop (rice, maize, roots and tubers), households were asked to give a score of losses on their fields as well as on their stocks in each survey round. Shock scores vary between 0 (no loss) and 3 (harvest reduced to nothing). We use this information to measure transitory household-specific shocks. Second, region-specific risk, which affects all households in a given region, is captured by rainfall data. Both the standard deviation of rainfall from its long-term average and its squared are included in the regression. Rainfall data come from the NASA/GSFC Laboratory for Atmospheres as a contribution to the GPCP, an international research project of the World Meteorological Organization’s Global Energy and

(13)

Water Exchange program.3 Third, in order to introduce some heterogeneity in household-level sensitivity to climatic shocks, we introduce the cross-product of soil types and rainfall deviation in rice-growing observatories (rice being the main food crop in Madagascar). Some descriptive statististics on household-specific shocks are given in Tables 2, 3a and 3b. Although their economic and agroclimatic environment differ, all households in the sample face relatively high levels of income risk. As highlighted by Table 2, the frequency of shocks over time is particularly high in rice fields since nearly 33% of the 942 households that were interviewed in all five rounds experienced shocks in their rice fields in four or five rounds. This proportion falls to 7.4% when shocks in maize fields are considered. As pointed out by Beegle et al. (2006), the high frequency of shocks in rice fields raises the concern that our shock measures might pick up unobserved household characteristics rather than identifying an exogenous source of variation in income. The inclusion of household fixed effects in all subsequent specifications will at least partially control for this. Tables 3a and 3b report the magnitude of shocks in rice and cassava fields respectively in each survey round. While complete crop destruction is uncommon, shocks appear to be substantial in magnitude : 20% of households on average report heavy losses in their ricefields in each survey round. Moreover, shocks experienced by households in their fields appear to be not purely idiosyncratic.

In the second part of the empirical section, the construction of the dependent variables of the entry-drop out models is made possible by using information on schooling attendance from the panel of individuals. Transitions in and out of school are then coded as described in section 3. Figures 1 and 2 show the distribution of both dependent variables by age and gender. Not

3Detailed information is available at http://precip.gsfc.nasa.gov/ . Monthly ground measures on rainfall are

also available for each observatory but are missing for years 2001 and 2002. Correlations between these measures and those provided by the NASA vary between 0.85 and 0.94 depending on the observatory under concern.

(14)

surprisingly, the profiles indicate important variations with age: entry probability increases steeply between age 4 to 7 - when it reaches a high of 35% for boys and 40% for girls - and decreases afterwards; drop-out probability is lower than 10% under 12 and increases to reach 40% at age 18. Figure 3 confirms that the proportion of children involved in domestic and agricultural labor increases with age.

In order to give some ground to the assumption that transitory shocks and schooling decisions are connected, Table 4 reports the proportions of sample children who dropped out from school in each observatory and each year, depending on whether their household experienced a shock or not. No clear picture emerges from it. The figures reveal higher probabilities of dropping out from school for children belonging to households having reported shocks in their ricefields in two observatories out of three (Antalaha and Marovoay). But shocks in maize fields are paradoxically associated with lower probabilities of dropping out from school in three observatories out of four. Table 5 reports pair wise correlations of schooling rates at the household level, per capita income mean and deviation, and rainfall deviation. While schooling rates appear to be strongly correlates with mean per capita income in all observatories, they are significantly correlated with income and rainfall deviation only in Antalaha and Tuléar. These results suggest that schooling rates may be responsive to both idiosyncratic and common shocks at least for a subset of households. This will be investigated more rigorously in the following section.

5. Empirical Results

In addition to the measures of shocks described in the previous section, the vector of regressors in the income regressions includes rice field area, the percentage of irrigated land, the composition

(15)

of the livestock owned by the household and the number of male and female elders, adults, young adults, children aged between five and fifteen and children who are younger than five. For the observatory of Antalaha, where a large share of cultivated land is devoted to vanilla, the vector of regressors also includes variables related to the number of vanilla trees owned by each household. Summary statistics by observatory are provided in Table 6.

Table 7 reports the fixed effects estimates of the determinants of total income for each observatory (Antalaha, Antsirabe, Marovoay and Tulear). For most of the variables, coefficients are in line with expectations. Rice land area is found to significantly raise total income and so does the percentage of irrigated land. Family labor is also found to give positive returns. For transitory shock variables, the deviation of annual rainfall from its long-term average has a significant impact on income in all observatories. However, the effect is positive in only three observatories (Antalaha, Antsirabe and Tuléar) and negative for Marovoay. This last result probably stems from the fact that most rice fields in Marovoay are irrigated and that heavy rains could be detrimental to the irrigation infrastructure or to the capacity of households to properly drain their fields. The effet of rainfall on income is found to be convex rather than concave in all observatories but Marovoay. There is also substantial variability across soil types in the responsiveness of crop income to rainfall. Most of the other transitory shock variables are found to negatively affect crop income, even though coefficients are not always significant. Rice being by far the predominant culture in Marovoay, a negative shock in rice fields (interacted with area planted in rice) is found to significantly decrease crop income. The same is true in Antalaha and Tulear for maize production. Last, the null hypothesis that there are no household fixed effects is strongly rejected in all income regressions.

(16)

gender indicator variable, child-specific variables include child age (not reported), child’s relation to head and rank among brothers and sisters, as well as the number of older and younger siblings by gender. In addition to household fixed effects, which capture both invariant and unobservable characteristics of the households, we also introduce year fixed effects to control for village-level shocks or changes in the local availability of schools.

Tables 9 and 10 report the estimated coefficients of the entrant and dropout models re-spectively. Two alternative specifications are presented. In the first one, we use the transitory income shock variable derived from the income regressions described above. In the second one, in order to check for robustness, we use a more reduced-form specification where shocks incurred by households in their ricefields are introduced directly in the equation. In order to account for the relative importance of rice in households’ income-generating activities, this shock variable is interacted with the size of land cultivated in rice. Unanticipated demographic events are also accounted for through the introduction of a variable measuring the number of elderly household members exiting the sample from one year to another.4

In the entrant model, the coefficient of transitory income is positive but not significant, implying that neither a positive income shock nor a negative one influences the probability of entrance to school. On the other hand, the death (or moving-out) of an elderly household member in the last 12 months is found to significantly decrease the probability of entrance to school. Turning to child-specific variables, girls are found to have a consistently higher probability to enter school than boys, and household heads appear to favour their own offsprings.

4Unfortunately, the survey questionnaire does not allow to identify the causes of individual attrition. Our

assumption here is that death is the cause of attrition for most elderly members, even though some of them may have decided to move out. Death is often synonymous of tremendous ritual expenditures and constitutes as such a utility risk households have to deal with.

(17)

The result for girls is not surprising in the Malagasy context and has been observed by other researchers (see e.g. Cogneau et al. 2003). Results do not significantly differ when one substitutes reported shocks in ricefields for transitory change in household income (specification 2).

Turning to the dropout model, the coefficient of transitory income is consistently nega-tive, which implies that higher transitory income reduces the probability of dropping out from schooland, by symmetry, that households facing negative shocks tend to withdraw their children from school. This result suggests that households in rural Madagascar face binding borrowing constraints and divert child time away from education when confronted with negative income shocks. Results also indicate that having younger brothers increases the probability to drop out from school. With the exception of age and rank among siblings, none of the other child-specific variables is found to have discernable effects on school dropout. Here again, substituting re-ported shock in rice fields for transitory change in household income provides comparable results: the bigger the magnitude of shock in rice fields and the bigger the size of land devoted to rice cultivation, the higher the probability to drop out from school.

6. Conclusion

Consumption-smoothing market mechanisms are quite limited in the Malagasy context. As a result, most rural households - whose incomes can be extremely volatile due to weather con-ditions, pests, insects, rodents and other calamities - need to rely on nonmarket mechanisms or adopt multi-faceted strategies to cope with risk. In this paper, we have examined whether crop shocks and other types of shocks affect schooling decisions for children. We argue that this would indicate that parents obtain an informal income insurance by letting their children work.

(18)

Using five rounds of household panel data from four regions of Madagascar, we investigated whether children’s propensity to join school and to drop out of school responds to transient shocks. We also investigated issues such as gender and intrahousehold resource allocation. In order to do so, we first derived an estimate of agricultural income shocks and then regressed schooling decisions (either to enter into school or to dropout of school) on this estimate and other explanatory variables such as child age.

We find that transitory income affects children’s school dropout behaviors significantly but not school entrance. This result is consistent with the observation that children’s participation to household chores and agricultural activities increases with age. Parents who need to put their children to work will rely on their older rather than younger children. The probability of school entrance appears nevertheless to be sensitive to shocks in the demographic structure of the household since it is negatively correlated with the death or moving out of elderly household members. Our analysis also suggests that parents in our sample favor girls in terms of education. Lastly, we find weak evidence of resource competition among siblings.

The paper can be extended in two directions. First, in order to understand what types of mecanisms could mitigate households reliance on children labor to cope with risk, it would be interesting to investigate whether different types of households respond to shocks differently. Second, the paper would also benefit from a complementary empirical analysis of whether house-holds facing more volatile income stream get lower education outcomes, as found by Kazianga (2005) in Burkina Faso. This is left for further research.

(19)

References

Beegle, K., Dehejia, R. & Gatti, R. (2006), ‘Child labor and agricultural shocks’, Journal of Development Economics . (forthcoming).

Bourguignon, F., Ferreira, F. & Leite, P. (2003), ‘Conditional cash transfers, schooling and child labor: Micro-simulating brazil’s bolsa escola program’, World Bank Economic Review 17(2), 229—254.

Cogneau, D., Dumont, J., Glick, P., Razafindrakoto, M., Razafindravonona, J., Randretsa, I. & Roubaud, F. (2003), Madagascar, in C. Morrisson, ed., ‘Education and Health Expenditures and Poverty Reduction in East Africa: Madagascar and Tanzania’, OECD Development Centre Studies.

de Janvry, A., Finan, F. & Sadoulet, E. (2006), ‘Can conditional cash transfer programs serve as safety nets in keeping children at school and from working when exposed to shocks?’, Journal of Development Economics . (forthcoming).

Droy, I., Ratovoarinony, R. & Roubaud, F. (2000), ‘Les observatoires ruraux à madagascar. une méthodologie originale pour le suivi des campagnes’, Stateco 95.

Duryea, S., Lam, D. & Levison, D. (2003), ‘Effects of economic shocks on childrenŠs employment and schooling in brazil’, PSC Research Report #03-541 .

Jacoby, H. & Skoufias, E. (1997), ‘Risk, financial markets and human capital in a developing country’, Review of Economic Studies 64, 311—335.

Jensen, R. (2000), ‘Agricultural volatility and investments in children’, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 90(2), 399—404.

(20)

Kazianga, H. (2005), ‘Income risk and schooling decisions in burkina faso’.

Parker, S. & Skoufias, E. (2006), ‘Job loss and family adjustments in work and schooling during the mexican peso crisis’, Journal of Population Economics . (forthcoming).

Paxson, C. H. (1992), ‘Using weather variability to estimate the response of savings to transitory income in thailand’, American Economic Review 82(1), 15—33.

Sawada, Y. (2003), ‘Income risks, gender and human capital investment in a developing country’, CIRJE Working Paper F-98 .

Schultz, P. T. (2004), ‘School subsidies for the poor: evaluating the mexican progresa poverty program’, Journal of Development Economics 74(1), 199—250.

Skoufias, E. & Parker, S. (2001), ‘Conditional cash transfers and their impact on child work and school enrollment: evidence from the progresa program in mexico’, Economia 2(1), 45—86.

(21)

Table 1 - Dynamic attrition logit model with focus on lagged shocks

Dependent variable is 1if individual attrites in current period, 0 otherwise

Lagged individual characteristics

Age 0.188

(0.000)***

Age squared -0.003

(0.008)***

Sex (1: Girl; 0: Boy) 0.169

(0.000)***

Child of head -0.548

(0.000)***

Rank if child of head -0.159

(0.000)***

Lagged household characteristics

Consumption per capita (/1,000,000) -0.045

(0.658)

Household size 0.093

(0.000)***

Lagged shock variables

Transitory income 0.382

(0.212) Number of elderly members who either died or moved out 0.116

(0.263)

Village x Year dummies Included but not shown

Intercept -4.338 (0.000)***

Number of observations 21,787

Robust p values in parentheses

(22)

Table 2 - Frequency of shocks

Rice fields Maize fields

Number of shocks across five survey

rounds Freq. Percent Freq. Percent

0 29 3.1 366 38.9 1 110 11.7 200 21.2 2 213 22.6 171 18.1 3 281 29.8 136 14.4 4 227 24.1 58 6.2 5 82 8.7 11 1.2 Total 942 100 942 100

(23)

Table 3a - Magnitude of shocks on rice fields, by year

Observatory Year No loss Moderate losses Heavy losses

Harvest reduced to nothing Antalaha 1998 19.6% 56.7% 23.5% 0.2% 1999 38.8% 47.6% 13.6% 0.0% 2000 4.0% 27.0% 63.2% 5.7% 2001 33.3% 48.8% 17.4% 0.6% 2002 52.9% 20.6% 26.1% 0.3% Antsirabe 1998 50.6% 32.9% 16.1% 0.3% 1999 41.3% 35.1% 22.9% 0.7% 2000 8.4% 24.7% 66.1% 0.8% 2001 64.8% 15.9% 18.9% 0.5% 2002 67.3% 12.0% 19.5% 1.2% Marovoay 1998 58.3% 19.0% 22.6% 0.2% 1999 28.2% 20.0% 35.4% 16.3% 2000 44.1% 26.5% 24.4% 5.1% 2001 54.6% 24.9% 16.9% 3.7% 2002 53.2% 28.5% 17.7% 0.6%

Note: In Tulear, the fourth observatory, households do not produce rice.

Table 3b - Magnitude of shocks on cassava fields, by year

Observatory Year No loss Moderate losses Heavy losses

Harvest reduced to nothing Antalaha 1998 76.0% 15.8% 8.3% 0.0% 1999 81.9% 12.9% 4.9% 0.4% 2000 61.5% 13.2% 17.2% 8.0% 2001 96.9% 2.3% 0.8% 0.0% 2002 87.8% 7.5% 4.5% 0.2% Antsirabe 1998 82.3% 9.7% 8.0% 0.0% 1999 73.4% 11.8% 14.2% 0.7% 2000 53.9% 21.0% 24.3% 0.8% 2001 90.7% 2.8% 4.5% 2.0% 2002 99.0% 0.5% 0.5% 0.0% Marovoay 1998 97.6% 0.5% 2.0% 0.0% 1999 94.2% 2.5% 2.5% 0.8% 2000 95.5% 1.6% 2.5% 0.4% 2001 97.1% 2.3% 0.4% 0.2% 2002 97.3% 1.6% 1.2% 0.0% Tulear 1998 41.8% 32.6% 19.1% 6.5% 1999 68.8% 16.0% 10.7% 4.5% 2000 31.2% 10.3% 18.5% 40.0% 2001 32.8% 13.9% 36.8% 16.5%

(24)

Table 4 - Probability to drop out from school and shocks

Shocks on rice fields

Antalaha Antsirabe Marovoay Tulear

No loss Partial or complete loss No loss Partial or complete loss No loss Partial or complete loss No loss Partial or complete loss 1998 4.3% 13.3% 9.0% 11.7% 15.6% 15.7% - - 1999 15.0% 9.7% 16.4% 13.7% 12.6% 14.5% - - 2000 5.3% 9.5% 13.6% 7.0% 12.4% 15.5% - - 2001 8.8% 13.0% 12.3% 12.0% 10.6% 15.4% - - 2002 5.9% 8.5% 14.6% 9.9% 12.0% 11.0% - -

Shocks on maize fields

Antalaha Antsirabe Marovoay Tulear

No loss Partial or complete loss No loss Partial or complete loss No loss Partial or complete loss No loss Partial or complete loss 1998 10.8% 21.6% 8.9% 13.0% 15.6% 16.7% 17.6% 17.0% 1999 11.3% 20.0% 15.8% 13.8% 15.0% 5.0% 18.1% 11.9% 2000 8.7% 12.5% 6.3% 7.8% 14.8% 5.0% 16.6% 12.8% 2001 11.4% 18.8% 14.8% 10.3% 13.6% 6.8% 13.6% 13.3% 2002 7.1% 12.5% 12.7% 14.7% 12.0% 3.3% - -

(25)

Table 5 - Pairwise correlation of schooling rate, per capita income mean and deviation, and rainfall deviation (village level)

Antalaha Antsirabe Marovoay Tuléar

Mean income per capita 0.095 0.180 0.150 0.073

(0.000)*** (0.000)*** (0.000)*** (0.003)***

Deviation of income per capita from 0.040 0.013 0.011 0.076

long-term average (0.079)* (0.523) (0.609) (0.005)***

Deviation of rainfall from long-term average 0.063 0.007 0.022 0.065

(0.002)*** (0.705) (0.278) (0.008)***

p values in parentheses

(26)

Table 6 - Summary statistics of variables used in income regressions

Antalaha Antsirabe Marovoay Tulear

Total annual household income 6,003,789 3,446,310 5,449,929 1,919,666

(7,549,550) (3,217,945) 5,430,779 2,481,261

Physical Assets

Number of vanilla trees aged 3- 304.5

(781.2)

Number of vanilla trees aged 3-8 364.8

(942.7)

Number of vanilla trees aged 8+ 123.0

(450.3)

Land area (acres) 133.7 81.2 130.3

(117.1) (102.4) (140.1) % of irrigated land 0.27 0.79 0.68 (0.39) (0.34) (0.43) Number of bullocks 0.53 0.87 0.96 0.65 (1.26) (1.34) (2.14) (1.32) Number of buffalos 0.26 0.63 1.15 4.51 (0.86) (2.92) (5.17) (11.14) Number of cows 0.39 0.46 0.57 1.73 (3.67) (0.95) (2.75) (6.16) Number of pigs 0.20 0.55 0.26 0.01 (0.86) (1.21) (1.33) (0.48) Human Assets

Number of children aged 5- 0.96 1.23 0.96 1.47

(0.95) (1.08) (0.99) (1.21)

Number of children aged 5-15 1.56 1.66 1.55 1.76

(1.38) (1.41) (1.35) (1.65)

Number of young adults aged 15-20 0.59 0.70 0.64 0.70

(0.83) (0.92) (0.88) (0.90)

Number of adults aged 20-65 2.00 2.18 2.15 2.04

(0.93) (0.96) (1.05) (1.01)

Number of elders aged 65+ 0.17 0.16 0.20 0.12

(0.44) (0.46) (0.47) (0.36)

Shock Variables

Rainfall deviation -17.5 -46.7 -61.4 -7.1

(164.8) (169.9) (112.6) (131.1)

Rainfall deviation squared 27.5 31.0 16.4 17.2

(24.1) (29.7) (23.3) (21.0)

Rice field shock 0.85 0.69 0.72 0.00

(0.82) (0.85) (0.92) (0.02)

Rice field shock x area planted in rice 130.3 54.7 119.1

(201.0) (136.4) (279.5)

Maize field shock 0.10 0.66 0.09 1.27

(0.44) (0.86) (0.39) (1.41)

Other field shock 0.74 0.44 0.06 0.83

(0.98) (0.80) (0.31) (1.21)

Tuber. Field shock 0.25 0.26 0.05 0.94

(0.62) (0.63) (0.30) (1.13)

(27)

Table 7 – Fixed effects estimates of the determinants of income

Dependent variable is log(total income)

Antalaha Antsirabe Marovoay Tulear

Farm characteristics

Number of vanilla trees aged 3- 0.0000

(3.19)***

Number of vanilla trees aged 3-8 0.0000

(3.79)***

Number of vanilla trees aged 8+ 0.0001

(3.13)***

Land area (acres) 0.0010 0.0011 0.0016

(6.57)*** (7.21)*** (11.83)***

% irrigated 0.0267 0.0319 0.0955

(0.83) (1.20) (3.37)***

Number of children aged 5- 0.0432 0.0345 0.0136 -0.0204

(2.32)** (2.34)** (0.89) (0.53)

Number of children aged 5-15 0.0774 0.0474 0.0342 0.0853

(4.96)*** (3.52)*** (2.75)*** (2.49)**

Number of young adults aged 15-20 0.0918 0.0573 0.0885 0.0403

(4.49)*** (3.70)*** (5.48)*** (0.86)

Number of adults aged 20-65 0.1223 0.0787 0.1320 -0.0525

(5.96)*** (4.69)*** (8.81)*** (1.15)

Number of elders aged 65+ -0.0121 0.0160 0.0524 0.0805

(0.26) (0.31) (1.26) (0.51) Number of bullocks 0.0409 0.0584 0.0127 0.0815 (3.46)*** (5.57)*** (2.29)** (3.68)*** Number of buffalos 0.0238 0.0189 0.0113 0.0297 (1.55) (5.46)*** (5.33)*** (8.98)*** Number of cows 0.0088 0.0828 0.0224 0.0181 (0.58) (7.13)*** (6.28)*** (3.32)*** Number of pigs 0.0140 0.0350 0.0026 (1.03) (4.46)*** (0.37) Rainfall Variables

Rainfall deviation from long-term average 0.0014 0.0002 -0.0015 -0.0032

(11.37)*** (3.04)*** (8.89)*** (5.30)***

Rainfall deviation squared(a) 0.0222 0.0013 -0.0008 0.0245

(23.60)*** (2.88)*** (1.09) (5.99)***

Rainfall deviation x Plain area(a) -0.0022 -0.0008 0.0008

(3.50)*** (0.61) (1.40)

x Low ground area(a) -0.0029 -0.0002 -0.0017

(1.08) (0.25) (0.43)

x Tavy area(a) 0.0064 -0.0304 0.2074

(0.76) (2.67)*** (1.45)

x Tanety area(a) -0.0002 0.0094 -0.0068

(0.15) (3.80)*** (1.62)

Other Transitory Shock Variables

Rice field shock x area planted in rice -0.0005 0.0001 -0.0003

(5.02)*** (0.78) (6.27)***

Maize field shock -0.0300 -0.0086 -0.0757 -0.0038

(1.18) (0.73) (3.06)*** (0.14)

Other field shock -0.0323 -0.0099 -0.0129 0.0334

(2.32)** (0.85) (0.45) (1.15)

Tuber. field shock 0.0141 0.0047 0.0381 0.0094

(0.77) (0.33) (1.23) (0.27)

Year dummies Included but not shown

Constant 13.7386 14.1109 14.3498 12.9852

(194.79)*** (233.10)*** (283.89)*** (80.07)***

Number of observations 3,261 3,597 3,223 2,320

Number of households 1,235 847 1,094 996

(28)

Table 8 - Summary statistics of variables used in entrant and dropout models

Entrant model Dropout model

Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev. Dependent variables

P(Enter) 0.271 0.444

P(Drop out) 0.182 0.386

Independent variables

Sex (1: Girl; 0: Boy) 0.482 0.500 0.489 0.500

Age 6.3 2.1 12.1 3.1

Child of head 0.817 0.387 0.881 0.324

Rank if child of head 3.4 2.8 3.5 2.4

Number of older sisters 1.4 1.2 1.0 1.1

Number of older brothers 0.8 0.9 1.3 1.2

Number of younger sisters 1.5 1.4 1.2 1.1

Number of younger brothers 0.8 0.9 1.4 1.3

Number of elderly members who either

died or moved out 0.1 0.3 0.0 0.1

Transitory change in household income -0.030 0.097 -0.042 0.110

Rice field shock x rice area 98.7 213.7 128.7 238.8

Number of observations 5,789 6,379

(29)

Table 9 - Conditional logit of entrant model

(1) (2)

Characteristics of the child

Sex (1: Girl; 0: Boy) 0.455 0.463

(0.004)*** (0.003)***

Child of head 1.902 1.901

(0.000)*** (0.000)***

Rank if child of head -0.130 -0.128

(0.005)*** (0.005)***

Age dummies Included but not shown

Number of siblings

Number of older sisters -0.010 -0.008

(0.913) (0.935)

Number of older brothers 0.029 0.019

(0.747) (0.826)

Number of younger sisters 0.156 0.143

(0.127) (0.158)

Number of younger brothers 0.086 0.076

(0.389) (0.446)

Shock variables

Number of elderly members who either died or moved out -2.894 -2.907

(0.000)*** (0.000)***

Transitory change in household income 0.278

(0.697)

Rice field shock x rice area -0.000

(0.989)

Village x year dummies Included but not shown

Number of observations 5,789 5,848

Number of households 996 1005

p values in parentheses

(30)

Table 10 - Conditional logit of dropout model

(1) (2)

Characteristics of child

Sex (1: Girl; 0: Boy) -0.119 -0.110

(0.405) (0.442)

Child of head -0.134 -0.127

(0.599) (0.619)

Rank if child of head -0.097 -0.104

(0.021)** (0.013)**

Age dummies Included but not shown

Number of siblings

Number of older sisters -0.043 -0.036

(0.621) (0.675)

Number of older brothers 0.084 0.081

(0.323) (0.340)

Number of younger sisters 0.122 0.123

(0.141) (0.134)

Number of younger brothers 0.199 0.195

(0.013)** (0.014)**

Shock variables

Number of elderly members who either died or moved out 0.588 0.599

(0.104) (0.096)*

Transitory change in household income -1.534

(0.007)***

Rice field shock x rice area 0.000

(0.044)**

Village x year dummies Included but not shown

Number of observations 6,379 6,430

Number of households 713 718

p values in parentheses

(31)

Figure 1 - Probability of school entry by gender 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 Boys Girls

Figure 2 - Probability of school dropout by gender

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Boys Girls

(32)

Figure 3 - Percentage of boys and girls involved in household duties or agricultural labor, 2002 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15

Girls - Household duties Girls - Agricultural labor

Figure

Table 1 - Dynamic attrition logit model with focus on lagged shocks
Table 2 - Frequency of shocks
Table 3b - Magnitude of shocks on cassava fields, by year
Table 4 - Probability to drop out from school and shocks
+7

Références

Documents relatifs

While individuals in poverty (according to the EU definition) report sharply lower levels of well-being than when they are not in poverty, Table 2 does not tell us anything about

This treatment improves the tensile strength of the fibers, in addition to substantial gains to interfacial adhesion when in an epoxy supporting polymer.. The former effect is

/ La version de cette publication peut être l’une des suivantes : la version prépublication de l’auteur, la version acceptée du manuscrit ou la version de l’éditeur. Access

We then subtract the number of Singapore’s public trans- portation smart card system users from our calculated value of urban mobility to estimate the share of private

Leur ponctuation intonative diverge toutefois, dans la mesure où la différence de Fo des deux topiques y est plus significative (Figure 7) ; Fo = 229 Hz pour la première syllabe de

“The next decade of land policy in Africa: ensuring agricultural development and inclusive growth”.. According to the young people

Les pesticides sont largement utilisés dans le monde entier pour lutter contre les champignons et les insectes qui détruisent les plantes cultivées et leurs

The enhanced features show that the quantum correlations of the pure crystal are not destroyed by partial deuteration and Raman spectra are consistent with separable proton and