• Aucun résultat trouvé

Snell envelope and the pricing of American-style contingent claims

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "Snell envelope and the pricing of American-style contingent claims"

Copied!
71
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem Reference

Snell envelope and the pricing of American-style contingent claims

80-646-08 Stochastic calculus I

Geneviève Gauthier

HEC Montréal

(2)

Introduction Notation The problem

Tari…cation Snell’s problem Reference

The riskless security

Market model

The following text draws heavily on Isabelle Cormier’s (UQAM) master’s thesis.

(3)

Introduction Notation The problem

Tari…cation Snell’s problem Reference

Notation I

Let’s …rst establish the notation that will be used in this text: the triple(Ω,F,P)represents a …nite probability space (Card()<) on which the …ltration

F= fFt :t =0,1, ...,Tgis built.

(4)

Introduction Notation The problem

Tari…cation Snell’s problem Reference

Notation II

We will use the market model introduced in the article written in 1981 by J. Michael Harrison and Stanley R.

Pliska: so, there are on the marketK +1 …nancial securities, whose prices at time t are given by a random vector

!S

t = St0,St1, ...,StK >

each component of which is a random variable taking a

…nite number of strictly positive values. Thus, such a stochastic process as S =n!S

t :t=0,1, ...,To

models the evolution of the security prices on the market.

(5)

Introduction Notation The problem

Tari…cation Snell’s problem Reference

Notation III

The …rst security has a particular status riskless investment (less risky!), i.e.

8ω 2Ω,8t =1, ...,T,St0(ω) St0 1(ω). We may also assume, without loss of generality, that

8ω 2Ω,S00(ω) =1.

(6)

Introduction Notation The problem

Tari…cation Snell’s problem Reference

Notation IV

Since the market value of one dollar is not the same at di¤erent times, investment gains and losses cannot be directly compared if they don’t occur at the same time.

For that reason, we must study the discounted price process β!S where the adapted, strictly positive-valued, stochastic process β=fβt :t =0,1, ...,Tg, de…ned as

βt = 1 St0,

represents our discount factor at each time point.

From Harrison and Pliska’s Theorem 2.7 (1981, p. 228), we know that, if our market model contains no arbitrage opportunities, there exists at least one risk-neutral probability measure Q according to which the discounted price processes for the securities are martingales.

(7)

Introduction Notation The problem

Tari…cation Snell’s problem Reference

The problem I

Mathematically speaking, a European-style contingent claim is a non-negative random variable, FT measurable since the said contingent claim can only be exercised at maturity, that is at time T.

As a consequence, the holder of such a contingent claim is passive in the sense that he or she has no decision to make during the lifetime of the contingent claim.

(8)

Introduction Notation The problem

Tari…cation Snell’s problem Reference

The problem II

An American-style contingent claim, by contrast, can be represented as an F adapted stochastic process X =fXt :t =0,1, ...,TgwhereXt represents the contingent claim value at time t if it is exercised at that time.

The holder of an American-style contingent claim must therefore ask himself or herself, at each time period during the lifetime of the aforementioned contingent claim, whether it is better to exercise his or her claim or to wait.

(9)

Introduction Notation The problem

Tari…cation Snell’s problem Reference

The problem III

The random time τ:Ω ! f0, ...,Tg,representing the time when the holder of the contingent claim exercises his or her claim, must be such that 8t 2 f0, ...,Tg,

fω 2Ωjτ(ω) =tg 2 Ft since the decision to exercise the claim at timet can only be made based on the information available at that time. It is therefore a stopping time.

In what follows, the set of random times representing the time of exercise is de…ned as

Λ0 =fτ: ! f0, ...,Tg jτ is a stopping timeg.

(10)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Pricing an American-style contingent claim I

Similar to the European-style contingent claim, the price of an American-style contingent claim can be viewed from two angles : the contingent claim seller’s perspective, and the buyer’s perspective.

(11)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Pricing an American-style contingent claim II

In what follows, Φdenotes the set of admissible investment strategies (Harrison and Pliska, 1981, p.

226), a strategy

!ϕ =n!ϕt = ϕ0t,ϕ1t, ...,ϕKt :t =1, ...To being a predictable stochastic process indicating, at each time and for each security, the number of shares being held.

Reminder. An investment strategy is said to be admissible if it is self-…nancing and its market value is never negative.

An admissible strategy thus is such that the investor is never in a debt position.

That doesn’t mean however that short sales are prohibited.

(12)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Pricing an American-style contingent claim III

Seller’s perspective. The seller’s …rst goal is to ensure that, if he adequately invests the amountx obtained from selling the contingent claimX, then, at time τ when the buyer exercises his claim, he is able to meet his obligation, i.e. to pay the amountXτ. The minimum price acceptable to the seller of contingent claimX is therefore

xsup =inf x 0 9!ϕ 2 Φsuch that V0 !ϕ =x andVτ !ϕ X

τ,8τ0 .

(13)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Pricing an American-style contingent claim IV

Buyer’s perspective. If the buyer borrows an amount x at timet =0 in order to buy the contingent claim X then, at timeτ when he exercises his claim, he wants to be able to pay back his debt, i.e. there must exist an investment strategyφ such thatV0 !

φ = x and Vτ !

φ +Xτ 0. Thus, the maximum price that the buyer of the contingent claimX is ready to pay out is

xinf =sup 8<

:x 0 9!

φ 2Φ such thatV0 !

φ = x and Vτ !

φ +Xτ 0 for some τ0

9=

;

(14)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Inequalities

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Theorem

If the market model contains no arbitrage opportunities, then, for any martingale measureQ,

X0 xinf sup

τ2Λ0

EQ[βτXτ] xsup.

Remark. In solving Snell’s problem, we obtain a stopping time τ satisfying EQ[βτ Xτ ] =supτ2Λ0EQ[βτXτ], which allows us to determine the latter quantity without the need to know every stopping time in the set Λ0

(15)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Proof - First inequality

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

The …rst inequality comes from the fact thatX0 belongs to the set

8<

:x 0 9!

φ 2Φsuch that V0 !

φ = x andVτ !

φ +Xτ 0, for some τ0

9=

;. Indeed, let’s choose the strategy !

φ that consists, throughout time interval[0,T], of holding portfolio ( X0,0, ...,0)(a debt ofX0 shares of the riskless security) and let’s setτ=0. Then

V0 !

φ = ( X0,0, ...,0) !S

0 = X0 and

Vτ !

φ +Xτ =V0 !

φ +X0 =0.

(16)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Proof - Third inequality I

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Let’s choose arbitrarily

x0 2 x 0 9!ϕ 2Φsuch that

V0 !ϕ =x andVτ !ϕ X

τ,8τ2 Λ0

.

That choice is such that there exists a strategy !ϕ 2 Φsuch thatV0 !ϕ =x0 andVτ !ϕ X

τ for any stopping time τ2Λ0. Thus, based on the latter inequality, we state that

8τ2Λ0,EQ[βτXτ] EQ βτVτ !ϕ . (1)

(17)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Proof - Third inequality II

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Since the market contains no arbitrage opportunities, the stochastic processβV !ϕ is a (Q,F) martingale (Harrison and Pliska, 1981, Proposal 2.8, p. 230). The ”Optional Stopping Theorem” (Revuz and Yor, Theorem 3.2, p. 65) implies that, for any bounded stopping time τ,

EQ βτVτ !ϕ =EQ β0V0 !ϕ which leads to the following:

8τ0,EQ βτVτ !ϕ = EQ β0V0 !ϕ

= β0x0

= x0.

(18)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Proof - Third inequality III

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

By substitution into inequality (1) EQ[βτXτ] EQ βτVτ !ϕ , we obtain

8τ2 Λ0,EQ[βτXτ] x0 hence

sup

τ2Λ0EQ[βτXτ] x0. Since the choice ofx0 was arbitrary, then

sup

τ2Λ0

EQ[βτXτ]

inf x0 0 9!ϕ 2 Φsuch that V0 !ϕ =x0

andVτ !ϕ X

τ,8τ2Λ0

= xsup.

(19)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Proof - Second inequality I

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Let’s choose arbitrarily

x0 2 8<

:x 0 9!

φ 2Φ such thatV0 !

φ = x andVτ !

φ +Xτ 0 for someτ2 Λ0

9=

; thus establishing the existence of an admissible strategy

!φ 2Φsatisfying V0 !

φ = x0 and Vτx

0

!φ +Xτx

0 0,for some τx0 2 Λ0. Thus, given that βτ

x0 >0,

0 EQh

βτx

0 Vτx

0

!φ +Xτx

0

i

= EQh βτ

x0Vτx

0

!φ

i+EQh βτ

x0Xτx

0

i .

(20)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Proof - Second inequality II

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Besides, sinceβV !ϕ is a (Q,F) martingale and τx0 is a bounded stopping time, we can use the ”Optional Stopping Theorem” and obtain

EQh βτx

0Vτx

0

!φ i

= EQh

β0V0 ! φ

i

= β0x0

= x0.

(21)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Proof - Second inequality III

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

As a consequence,

0 EQh

βτ

x0Vτx

0

!φ

i+EQh βτ

x0Xτx

0

i

= x0+EQh βτx

0Xτx

0

i x0+ sup

τ2Λ0EQ[βτXτ] hence

sup

τ2Λ0

EQ[βτXτ] x0.

(22)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Proof - Second inequality IV

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Since the choice ofx0 was arbitrary, sup

τ2Λ0EQ[βτXτ]

sup 8>

><

>>

: x0 0

9!

φ 2Φsuch that V0 !

φ = x0 and Vτ !

φ +Xτ 0, for some τ0

9>

>=

>>

;

= xinf.

(23)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Example I

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Let’s consider the following three-period binomial model

ω S00(ω) S01(ω)

S10(ω) S11(ω)

S20(ω) S21(ω)

S30(ω)

S31(ω) Q(ω)

ω1 1

80

1.115 100

1.1152 125

1.1153

156,25 0.343

ω2

1 80

1.115 100

1.1152 125

1.1153

100 0.147

ω3 1

80

1.115 100

1.1152 80

1.1153

100 0.147

ω4 1

80

1.115 100

1.1152 80

1.1153

64 0.063

(24)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Example II

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

ω S00(ω) S01(ω)

S10(ω) S11(ω)

S20(ω) S21(ω)

S30(ω)

S31(ω) Q(ω)

ω5 1

80

1.115 64

1.1152 80

1.1153

100 0.147

ω6 1

80

1.115 64

1.1152 80

1.1153

64 0.063

ω7 1

80

1.115 64

1.1152 51.20

1.1153

64 0.063

ω8 1

80

1.115 64

1.1152 51.20

1.1153

40.96 0.027

(25)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Example III

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

So, the …ltration is F0 = f?,g

F1 = σffω1,ω2,ω3,ω4g,fω5,ω6,ω7,ω8gg F2 = σffω1,ω2g,fω3,ω4g,fω5,ω6g,fω7,ω8gg F3 = all events inΩ

(26)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Example IV

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Exercise. It follows that Card(Λ0) =26. (Check by yourself...

if you have time!)

Partial answer. If we represent the stopping timeτ as a point inRCard(),

(τ(ω1), τ(ω2), τ(ω3), τ(ω4), τ(ω5), τ(ω6), τ(ω7),τ(ω8)), then the 26 stopping times inΛ0 are

(0,0,0,0,0,0,0,0) (1,1,1,1,1,1,1,1) (2,2,2,2,2,2,2,2) (3,3,3,3,3,3,3,3) (1,1,1,1,2,2,2,2) (1,1,1,1,2,2,3,3) (1,1,1,1,3,3,2,2) (1,1,1,1,3,3,3,3) (2,2,2,2,1,1,1,1) (2,2,3,3,1,1,1,1) (3,3,2,2,1,1,1,1) (3,3,3,3,1,1,1,1) (2,2,2,2,2,2,3,3) (2,2,2,2,3,3,2,2) (2,2,3,3,2,2,2,2) (3,3,2,2,2,2,2,2) (2,2,2,2,3,3,3,3) (2,2,3,3,2,2,3,3) (2,2,3,3,3,3,2,2) (3,3,2,2,2,2,3,3) (3,3,2,2,3,3,2,2) (3,3,3,3,2,2,2,2)

(3,3,3,3,3,3,2,2) (3,3,3,3,2,2,3,3) (3,3,2,2,3,3,3,3) (2,2,3,3,3,3,3,3)

(27)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Example V

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Exercise. Check that the probability measureQ given in the table is the only measure that makes the discounted price of the risky security a martingale.

Exercise. Justify why Q is also called the risk-neutral measure.

(28)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Example VI

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Let’s consider, as an American-style contingent claim, a put option with an 80-dollar strike price. The value of such a put at timet, if the put is exercised, is

Xt =max 80 St1,0

and its discounted value at timet, if again the put is exercised, is

Yt =βtXt =1.115 tmax 80 St1,0

(29)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Example VII

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Yt = βtXt =1.115 tmax 80 St1,0

ω Y0 Y1 Y2 Y3

ω1 0 0 0 0

ω2 0 0 0 0

ω3 0 0 0 0

ω4 0 0 0 1.115163 =11.5424

ω5 0 1.11516 =14.3498 0 0

ω6 0 1.11516 =14.3498 0 1.115163 =11.5424

ω7 0 1.11516 =14.3498 1.11528.802 =23.1656 1.115163 =11.5424 ω8 0 1.11516 =14.3498 1.11528.802 =23.1656 1.11539.043 =28.1634

(30)

Introduction Tari…cation

Inequalities Proof Example Snell’s problem Reference

Example VIII

Pricing an American-style contingent claim

Note that one of the random times representing, for each ω, a time when the option value is the greatest is

(τ(ω1), τ(ω2), τ(ω3), τ(ω4), τ(ω5), τ(ω6), τ(ω7),τ(ω8))

= (3,3,3,3,1,1,2,3).

But such a random time is not a stopping time, since

fω2:τ(ω) =2g=fω7g2 F/ 2

i.e., in order to be able to maximize our gains, we would need, at the time of deciding whether to exercise, to know the future. By contrast, it will be possible for us, using the stopping times, to maximize our expected gain conditionally on the information available at decision times (whether to exercise the contingent claim or not). This idea will be made more precise later on.

(31)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Formulation of Snell’s problem I

Let Y =fYt :t =0,1, ...,Tgbe a stochastic process, F adapted.

For all t 2 f0,1, ...,Tg, we can de…ne the set of stopping times taking their values in the set ft, ...,Tg:

Λt =fτ: ! ft, ...,Tg jτ is a stopping timeg. Note thatΛT ΛT 1 ... Λ0.

Snell’s problem is as follows: can we determine a stopping time τ 2Λ0 satisfying

E[Yτ ] = sup

τ2Λ0

E[Yτ] (2) In other words, we are looking to determine, for each of the ω2Ω, the time τ (ω) when we should stop the stochastic processY in order to maximize the expected value of the random variable Yτ.

(32)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Simpli…ed situation I

The …ltration contains no information

Let’s assume that 8t2 f0,1, ...,Tg,Ft =f?,Ωg. Under such conditions, sinceYt is Ft measurable, then Yt is constant, i.e. there exists a real numberyt for which

8ω2 Ω,Yt(ω) =yt.

(33)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Simpli…ed situation II

The …ltration contains no information

Moreover, that special …ltration is such that

Λ0 =fτ0,τ1, ...,τTg (3)

where 8ω2,τt(ω) =t.

Indeed, if τ is any stopping time (with respect to the

…ltration F) then8t 2 f0,1, ...,Tg,

fω 2:τ(ω) =tg 2 Ft =f?,g. Thus, if there exists a k 2 f0,1, ...,Tgfor which τ(ω) =k,then

fω2 :τ(ω) =tg= ift =k

? otherwise , which means that any stopping time existing in such a

…ltered probability space is constant. If we restrict ourselves to the stopping times taking their values in the set f0,1, ...,Tgthen there areT +1 possible values for k, hence equation (3).

(34)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Simpli…ed situation III

The …ltration contains no information

If we rewrite equation (2) E[Yτ ] =supτ2Λ0E[Yτ]

keeping in mind this special situation only, we observe that resolving Snell’s problem, in this context, amounts to determine t such that

yt = max

t2f0,1,...,Tgyt. (4) It’s obviously a trivial problem, but it is not useless to explain the steps of the solution, because there will be similar steps, less obvious, in solving the general case.

(35)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Simpli…ed situation IV

The …ltration contains no information

The basic idea is to introduce an auxiliary sequence fzt :t =0,1, ...,Tgde…ned as

zt = max

u2ft,...,Tgyu. Note that this sequence is decreasing (i.e.

8t 2 f1, ...,Tg,zt zt 1) and

zt =maxfyt, zt+1g. (5) Let’s set

t =minft 2 f0,1, ...,Tg j zt =ytg (6) and let’s show thatt satis…es equation (4).

(36)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Simpli…ed situation V

The …ltration contains no information

From the de…nition of t , we observe that

z0 =z1=...=zt zt +1 ... zT. (7) Indeed, if there existed t 2 f0,1, ...,t 1gsuch thatzt is striclty greater thanzt+1, then, from equation (5), zt =maxfyt, zt+1g>zt+1. It would therefore follow that zt =yt, which would contradict the de…nition oft . As a consequence, zt zt+1.

But, since the sequence ofzt is decreasing, thenzt =zt+1. Besides, expression (7) shows that t truly is the index we are after, since

yt =zt =z0= max

t2f0,1,...,Tgyt.

(37)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

General situation I

Snell’s problem

Now, let’s see how to adapt the ideas from the previous section to any …ltration.

The key to the problem solution lies in building a proper version of the decreasing sequence satisfying equation (5) zt =maxfyt, zt+1g.

Let’s set Zt =

8<

:

YT ift =T

maxfYt,E[Zt+1jFt]g ift 2 f0, ...,T 1g.

(38)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

General situation II

Snell’s problem

The stochastic process Z =fZt :t =0,1, ...,Tgis adapted to the …ltration F.

Indeed, E[Zt+1jFt]andYt beingFt measurable, maxfYt,E[Zt+1jFt]gis also measurable.

It is to be noted that, thus de…ned, the sequence

fZt :t =0,1, ...,Tgis not necessarily decreasing ω byω, but it is decreasing in terms of conditional expectations.

(39)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Example I

Snell’s problem

ω Y0 Y1 Y2 Y3 Q

ω1 0 0 0 0 0.343

ω2 0 0 0 0 0.147

ω3 0 0 0 0 0.147

ω4 0 0 0 =11.5424 0.063

ω5 0 =14.3498 0 0 0.147

ω6 0 =14.3498 0 =11.5424 0.063

ω7 0 =14.3498 =23.1656 =11.5424 0.063 ω8 0 =14.3498 =23.1656 =28.1634 0.027

(40)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Example II

Snell’s problem

ω Z0 Z1 Z2 Z3

ω1 =5.0321˙ =1.0388 0 0

ω2 =5.0321˙ =1.0388 0 0

ω3 =5.0321˙ =1.0388 =3.4627 0 ω4 =5.0321˙ =1.0388 =3.4627 =11.5424 ω5 =5.0321˙ =14.3498 =3.4627 0 ω6 =5.0321˙ =14.3498 =3.4627 =11.5424 ω7 =5.0321˙ =14.3498 =23.1656 =11.5424 ω8 =5.0321˙ =14.3498 =23.1656 =28.1634

(41)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Example III

Snell’s problem

Calculation of the preceding table entries:

8ω 2 fω1,ω2g, E[Z3jF2] (ω) = 0

Z2(ω) = maxfY2(ω),E[Z3jF2] (ω)g

= maxf0;0g=0 8ω 2 fω3,ω4g, E[Z3jF2] (ω) = 16

1.1153 0.063

0.21 =3.4627 Z2(ω) = maxfY2(ω),E[Z3jF2] (ω)g

= maxf0;3.4627g=3.4627

(42)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Example IV

Snell’s problem

8ω 2 fω5,ω6g, E[Z3jF2] (ω) = 16

1.1153 0.063

0.21 =3.4627 Z2(ω) = maxfY2(ω),E[Z3jF2] (ω)g

= maxf0;3.4627g=3.4627 8ω 2 fω7,ω8g,

E[Z3jF2] (ω) = 16 1.1153

0.063

0.09 + 39.04 1.1153

0.027

0.09 =16.5287 Z2(ω) = maxfY2(ω),E[Z3jF2] (ω)g

= maxf23.1656;16.5287g=23.1656

(43)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Example V

Snell’s problem

8ω 2 fω1,ω2,ω3,ω4g, E[Z2jF1] (ω) = 3.46270.21

0,7 =1.0388

Z1(ω) = maxfY1(ω),E[Z2jF1] (ω)g

= maxf0;1.0388g=1.0388 8ω 2 fω5,ω6,ω7,ω8g,

E[Z2jF1] (ω) = 3.46270.21

0.3 +23.16560.09

0.3 =7.9885 Z1(ω) = maxfY1(ω),E[Z2jF1] (ω)g

= maxf14.3498;7.9885g=14.3498 8ω 2

E[Z1jF0] (ω) = 1.0388 0.7+14.3498 0.3=5.0321˙

(44)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Example VI

Snell’s problem

Interpretation. Zt represents, conditionally to the

information available at timet, the maximum between the discounted value of the option if it is exercised at that time and its expected discounted value if it is exercised subsequently, at a time judiciously chosen.

Zt is thus the discounted value of the American option at time t.

(45)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Lemma 1 I

Snell’s problem

Theorem

Lemma 1. For all t 2 f0, ...,Tg,

8τ2 Λt, Zt E[YτjFt], (8) i.e.

Zt sup

τ2Λt

E[YτjFt] and, more particularly,

Z0 sup

τ2Λ0E[YτjF0].

(46)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Lemma 1 II

Snell’s problem

Proof of Lemma 1.

We will proceed by backward induction on t. When t =T,then

ΛT =fτ: ! fTg jτ is a stopping timeg, i.e. ΛT contains one stopping time only, the one identically equal to T. Since ZT =YT =E[YT jFT], inequality (8)8τ2 ΛT,ZT E[YτjFT] is clearly satis…ed.

Now, let’s assume that inequality (8)8τ2 Λt, Zt E[YτjFt] is veri…ed for somet 2 f1, ...,Tgand let’s show that is also veri…ed for index t 1.

(47)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Lemma 1 III

Snell’s problem

Let’s choose arbitrarily a stopping time τ2Λt 1. We will evaluate the expectation on the right side of inequality (8) 8τ2 Λt,Zt E[YτjFt]by breaking it down according to the values taken by τ:

E[YτjFt 1]

= E YτIfτ=t 1gjFt 1 +E YτIfτ>t 1gjFt 1

= E Yt 1Ifτ=t 1gjFt 1 +E Yτ_tIfτ>t 1gjFt 1 .(9) First, we’re going to tackle the second term in the equality stated above.

(48)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Lemma 1 IV

Snell’s problem

Given that τ_t, or the maximum of the two stopping times t andτ, is itself a stopping time, which besides belongs to Λt since, by its very de…nition, it takes its values in the set ft, ...,Tg, the induction hypothesis then allows us to state that

Zt E[Yτ_tjFt]. (10)

(49)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Lemma 1 V

Snell’s problem

On another front, fτ>t 1g 2 Ft 1 since fτ>t 1gc 2 Ft 1. Indeed,

fτ t 1g=

t[1

j=0

fτ=jg

| {z }

2Fj Ft 1

| {z }

2Ft 1

2 Ft 1 (11)

implies that Ifτ>t 1g is Ft 1 measurable.

(50)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Lemma 1 VI

Snell’s problem

It follows that

E Yτ_tIfτ>t 1gjFt 1

= Ifτ>t 1gE[Yτ_t jFt 1]

= Ifτ>t 1gE[E[Yτ_tjFt]jFt 1] Ifτ>t 1gE[ZtjFt 1]

Ifτ>t 1gmax| fYt 1,{zE[ZtjFt 1]g}

=Zt 1

= Ifτ>t 1gZt 1

where the …rst inequality comes from expression (10) Zt E[Yτ_tjFt].

(51)

Introduction Tari…cation Snell’s problem

Simpli…ed situation General situation

Example Lemma 1 Example Lemma 2 Lemma 3 Summary Example Reference

Lemma 1 VII

Snell’s problem

What about the …rst term in equation (9) E[YτjFt 1] = E Yt 1Ifτ=t 1gjFt 1 +E Yτ_tIfτ>t 1gjFt 1 ? From the de…nition of Zt 1, we have that

Zt 1 =maxfYt 1,E[ZtjFt 1]g Yt 1, hence

E Yt 1Ifτ=t 1gjFt 1 E Zt 1Ifτ=t 1gjFt 1

= Zt 1Ifτ=t 1g.

Références

Documents relatifs

“the distance between the robot and the human operator is always greater than or equal

Given a3, Circ is not a circumstance with respect to which the truth expressed by (A) is at the same time a priori and contingent, and, furthermore, it is unclear how there

Section 2 sets out some definitions and notations, Section 3 derives the density of the two- sided Parisian stopping time, Section 4 gives the result for the asymptotic tail

So, we shall provide contingent solutions to the first-order system of differential equations (1), which are by definition the solutions to the contingent

DEFINITION 2.1. It is clear that if S satisfies the No-Arbitrage property, then the fact that f is maximal in Ka already implies that f is maximal in K. The set of

In Section 3, this approach allows us to derive non asymptotic error bounds for deterministic approximation schemes such as cut-off techniques, Euler type discrete time

(1) By looking in detail to the movements of the body segments and their dispersion it appears that large corrective responses are observed only after 200 to 300 ms following the

Then, in Section 2, we write down the model for the observed price dynamics and study the associated risk-minimizing strategy taking into account liquidity costs and market