• Aucun résultat trouvé

Unemployment Insurance and Subsequent Job Duration: Job Matching vs Unobserved Heterogeneity

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "Unemployment Insurance and Subsequent Job Duration: Job Matching vs Unobserved Heterogeneity"

Copied!
34
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

Montréal

Série Scientifique

Scientific Series

2001s-21

Unemployment Insurance and

Subsequent Job Duration:

Job Matching vs

Unobserved Heterogeneity

(2)

CIRANO

Le CIRANO est un organisme sans but lucratif constitué en vertu de la Loi des compagnies du Québec. Le

financement de son infrastructure et de ses activités de recherche provient des cotisations de ses

organisations-membres, d’une subvention d’infrastructure du ministère de la Recherche, de la Science et de la Technologie, de

même que des subventions et mandats obtenus par ses équipes de recherche.

CIRANO is a private non-profit organization incorporated under the Québec Companies Act. Its infrastructure and

research activities are funded through fees paid by member organizations, an infrastructure grant from the

Ministère de la Recherche, de la Science et de la Technologie, and grants and research mandates obtained by its

research teams.

Les organisations-partenaires / The Partner Organizations

•École des Hautes Études Commerciales

•École Polytechnique

•Université Concordia

•Université de Montréal

•Université du Québec à Montréal

•Université Laval

•Université McGill

•MEQ

•MRST

•Alcan inc.

•AXA Canada

•Banque du Canada

•Banque Laurentienne du Canada

•Banque Nationale du Canada

•Banque Royale du Canada

•Bell Québec

•Bombardier

•Bourse de Montréal

•Développement des ressources humaines Canada (DRHC)

•Fédération des caisses populaires Desjardins de Montréal et de l’Ouest-du-Québec

•Hydro-Québec

•Imasco

•Industrie Canada

•Pratt & Whitney Canada Inc.

•Raymond Chabot Grant Thornton

•Ville de Montréal

© 2001 Christian Belzil. Tous droits réservés. All rights reserved.

Reproduction partielle permise avec citation du document source, incluant la notice ©.

Short sections may be quoted without explicit permission, if full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.

Ce document est publié dans l’intention de rendre accessibles les résultats préliminaires

de la recherche effectuée au CIRANO, afin de susciter des échanges et des suggestions.

Les idées et les opinions émises sont sous l’unique responsabilité des auteurs, et ne

représentent pas nécessairement les positions du CIRANO ou de ses partenaires.

This paper presents preliminary research carried out at CIRANO and aims at

encouraging discussion and comment. The observations and viewpoints expressed are the

sole responsibility of the authors. They do not necessarily represent positions of CIRANO

(3)

Unemployment Insurance and Subsequent Job Duration:

Job Matching vs Unobserved Heterogeneity

*

Christian Belzil

Résumé / Abstract

Dans cet article, j'analyse le lien entre la durée des prestations

d'assurance-chômage, la durée du chômage et la durée de l'emploi subséquent. L'analyse est

faite à l'aide d'un modèle de durée avec états multiples et hétérogénéité

non-observée. À l'aide du modèle, je tente de faire la distinction entre deux hypothèses

possibles qui expliqueraient la corrélation négative entre durée de chômage et

durée de l'emploi subséquent; la durée des prestations augmente la durée de

l'emploi subséquent (un effet de matching), ou la corrélation négative est

expliquée par la sélection adverse. Les résultats tendent à supporter l'hypothèse de

sélection adverse tandis que l'effet de matching semble être faible.

The relationship between Unemployment Insurance (UI) benefit duration,

unemployment duration and subsequent job duration is investigated using a

multi-state duration model with multi-state specific unobserved heterogeneity. I examine two

potential explanations for the negative correlation between unemployment and

job spell durations; UI benefits increase job matching quality (the "Matching"

effect) vs unobserved heterogeneity ("Adverse Selection"). The Matching effect is

found to be weak. Although new jobs accepted within 5 weeks of benefit

termination seem to have a higher dissolution rate, the negative correlation

between unemployment and job duration is mostly explained by unobserved

heterogeneity. Various simulations indicate that increasing the maximum benefit

duration by one week will raise expected unemployment duration by 1.0 to 1.5

days but will raise expected job duration by 0.5 to 0.8 days only.

Mots Clés :

Assurance-chômage, matching de l'emploi, durée du chômage, durée de l'emploi

Keywords:

Unemployment insurance, job matching, unemployment duration, job duration

*

Corresponding Author: Christian Belzil, CIRANO, 2020 University Street, 25

th

floor, Montréal, Qc, Canada

H3A 2A5

Tel.: (514) 985-4000

Fax: (514) 985-4039

email: belzilc@cirano.qc.ca

This is a revised version of the paper "Contiguous Duration Dependence and Nonstationarity in Job Search". I

would like to thank Thierry Magnac, John Rust (the Editor), Chris Taber and an anonymous referee for helpful

comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

(4)

The e ect of Unemployment Insurance (UI) on the labor market is one of

the most active areas of research in modern labor economics. The payment ofUI bene tsincreasesthe welfareof riskaverse workers a ectedby adverse

employment shocks andraises theirreservationwages. As aconsequence,UI

is expected to raise the duration of unemployment. At the same time, the payment of unemployment compensation can introduce strong disincentive

e ects in the labor market. In particular, the payment of UI bene ts can

sometimes induce the unemployed toreduce their search intensity. 1

While the positive correlation between UI bene t generosity and

unem-ployment duration is well established at the empirical level, whether it is

caused mostly by a decrease insearchintensity oran increase inreservation wages remain an open question.

2

The e ect of UI on the labor market is

not limited to unemployment duration only. UI can also a ect subsequent

job duration. Since bene t generosity is expected to raise reservation wages of the unemployed, it should therefore a ect the quality of subsequent job

matches. 3

Althoughthe e ectsofUI onunemploymentdurationisrelatively

well documented, very little isknown about the e ects of UI onthe quality of labor market adjustments. This paper proposes ananalysis of the e ects

of UI bene t duration from an angle which has, so far, been neglected in

the literature. The empiricalanalysis is based on the idea that UI bene ts should not only a ect the escape rate out of unemployment but also

subse-quent job duration. Ifincreases inthe escape rate out of unemploymentare

explained by signi cant decreases in reservation wages, those who are close tobene ttermination might acceptjobs which they are likelyto quitinthe

future. In other words, given a certain level of bene t duration, those who

leaveunemploymentearlier (with alongerpotentialbene tdurationahead)

1

Foratheoretical analysisofmoralhazardandUnemploymentInsurance,see Hopen-haynandNicolini(1997).

2

Meyer(1990)andHanandHausman(1990)havefoundasigni cantincrease(spikes) in theescaperateoutof unemploymentwhen unemploymentbene tslapse. Thismight suggestthat searchintensityincreasessubstantiallyshortlybeforebene ttermination.

3

Althoughmoste ortsdevotedtothee ectsofUIonlabormarketshaveconcentrated onthedurationofunemployment,earlyattemptstocapturetheimpactofUIonthelabor marketsseemtohavefocusedonthee ectsofUIbene tsonre-employmentearnings(see Ehrenberg and Oaxaca, 1976 or Classen, 1977). To my knowledge, Belzil (1990) is the

(5)

lesslikelytodissolve,acceptedjobdurationsshouldbesensitivetoUIbene t

duration. I referto this e ect as the \Matching" hypothesis. The Matching

hypothesis is a type of structural state/duration dependence which implies anegative correlationbetween unemploymentdurations and subsequent job

durations.

AnalternativeexplanationforthecorrelationbetweenUIbene tduration and subsequentjob durationisthe \Adverse Selection" hypothesis. Adverse

selectioncanarisefromunobservedcharacteristicsofindividuals(unobserved

heterogeneity) and is commonly believed to result in a negative correlation between unemployment duration and subsequent job durations. That is,

some individualsmay have attributes that makethem less attractiveto

em-ployersbut whicharenot observed by theeconometrician. Theseindividuals are more likely to have longer unemployment spells and shorter subsequent

job durations. If one fails tocontrolfor this type of unobserved

heterogene-ity, thereisa dangerof \spuriousstate dependence" thatcould resultinthe nding that longer unemployment durations imply shorter subsequent job

durations. In this paper I attempt to control for unobserved heterogeneity

inorder toavoid makingspurious inferencesabout the relationship between unemploymentduration and subsequent job duration. Byconditioning ona

person's unobserved type, I can assess whether there is indeed a structural

relationship between unemployment duration and subsequent job duration oronlyaspuriousone. Given dataonboth unemploymentdurationand job

duration and information on bene t duration, identifying the \Matching"

e ect from pure unobserved heterogeneity istherefore relatively simple. For asetofindividualsentitledtothesame maximumbene tduration(say0for

thesakeoftheargument),theobserved correlationbetweenjobdurationand

unemployment durationcan beused to infer the importanceof the Adverse SelectionHypothesis. Conditionalonaspeci ctype,individualvariationsin

bene t duration provide information on the marginal e ects of bene t

du-ration on both unemployment and subsequent job durations (the Matching hypothesis).

At the outset, I must say that subsequent job duration is only one of

the potential measures of job matchquality. However, for reasonsdiscussed in Section 2, it is the one I focus on. To be consistent with the

terminol-ogy used in the literature, I use the term \maximum bene t duration" to

(6)

ignate the number of weeks of bene t remaining at a given point in time

(given elapsedunemploymentduration). I useamulti-statehazardmodelto

investigate how the subsequent job hazard function is related to unemploy-ment duration aswellas unemployment bene t duration. The modelhas 2

states (unemployment duration and accepted job duration). The empirical

workiscarriedonCanadiandata whichcomefromadministrative lesofthe Canadian UI program.

4

More details are found in Section3 and Section4.

The results indicate that both hypotheses contribute to explain the

ob-served correlation between unemployment duration and accepted job dura-tion, although the Matching e ect appears much weaker than the sorting

e ect explainedby bi-variateunobserved heterogeneity. The Matching

e ec-t seems to exist only within a short period before bene t termination. In particular, the escape rate out of unemployment seems to increase

signi -cantly within 5 weeks of bene t termination and new jobs accepted within

this 5weekperiodseemtohaveahigherdissolution rate. At thesame time, and aftercontrolling for individual variations in bene t duration, there is a

strong negative correlation between unobserved heterogeneity a ecting

un-employmentdurationandunobserved heterogeneitya ectingsubsequentjob duration. As the Matching e ect seems present only shortly before bene t

termination, very few individuals would be a ected by a counterfactual

in-crease in bene t duration. The results of various simulations indicate that increasing the maximum bene tduration by one week would raise expected

unemployment duration by 1.0 to 1.5 days but raise expected job duration

by only 0.5to 0.8days.

The paper is organized as follows. In the next section (Section 2), I

present some theoretical arguments which willbe used as guidelines for the

econometricmodel. In Section3,I present the Canadian UI system. In Sec-tion4,Idescribethedataanddiscussthesamplingmethod. Theeconometric

speci cation is discussed in Section 5 while the results are in Section 6. In

Section7,I simulatethe e ects of anincreasein bene tdurationonaverage unemployment durationand average accepted job duration. The conclusion

is inSection 8.

4

Theadministrative lesof theCanadian UIprogramarenowmaintainedbyHuman ResourcesDevelopmentCanada.

(7)

fect of UI

The empiricalanalysispresented inthis paperisbased onthe ideathat

non-stationary (decreasing) reservation wages create an identi able dependence between completed duration, re-employment wages and subsequent job

du-ration. Inthis section, I illustratethis ideausing a simplejob search model.

The modelisused asaguidelineforthe speci cationof theempiricalmodel. The theoretical framework is as follows. Initially; a group of homogenous

workers are laid o and search for a new job while unemployed. Elapsed

unemploymentduration isdenoted  u

. They searchfor wages from aknown (stationary) distribution function, F(w) .The wage (w) is understood to be

thesumofamonetarypaymentandanon-monetarycomponentwhichcould

representjobquality. AllindividualsareentitledtoUIbene tfora nite pe-riod (denoted T). Current bene t entitlement,given elapsedunemployment

duration, b( u ), isdescribed as follows: b( u )= ~ b when  u T b( u )=0 when  u >T

Althoughitwould bestraightforward tointroduceanexogenous layo

prob-abilitywithoutchangingtheresults,Iassumethattheyarenolayo s. While

unemployed,individualsreceiveatmostoneo erperperiodwithprobability 

u

. When employed, the o erprobability is e

:Witha nitebene tperiod,

it is easy to show that the value of unemployed search, V u

(b( u

));decreases

monotonicallyuntilT andremainsconstantbeyondT. 5 Itisunderstoodthat V u (b( u

)) represents the value of continuing search taking intoaccount that

search ispossibleuponre-employment. The value of accepting employment,

atwagew, isdenoted V e

(w):Clearly,V e

(w)isstationaryandtheescaperate

out of unemployment,  u ( u );is given by  u ( u )= u f1 F(w  u )g where w  u

is the unemployed reservation wage. This reservation wage, w  u

; is de ned as

5

(8)

V e (w u )=V u (b( u ))

and it is easy to show that w   u

decreases monotonically until bene t termi-nation.

Given knowledge of  u

( u

);it iseasy torecover the unemployment

dura-tion density g( u ): That is g( u )= d(1 exp ( R  u 0  u (s)ds) d u

The escape rate out of the accepted job,  e (w a ); is independent of job tenure,  e

; but depends onthe accepted wage, w a ; and is simply  e (w a )= e f1 F(w a )g

As the re-employment wage depends on realized unemployment duration through the reservation wage, the mean accepted wage may beexpressed as

follows E(w a )= 1 Z 0 " Z 1 w  u ( f(w) 1 F(w  u ) wdw )# g( u )d u (1)

where f(:) isthe density of wage o ers.

Equation 2.1illustrateshow re-employmentwages depend on

unemploy-mentdurationthroughthereservationwage. Inordertoillustratethe Match-ing e ect, it is convenient to look at the post-unemployment job duration

survivor function conditional on unemployment (realized) duration. It is

de ned as Pr( e  j u )=S( e j u ) Because both V e (W) and  e (w a

) are independent from job tenure, the job duration survivor function is easy to derive. Bearing in mind that the

dis-tributionof observed wages dependsonunemploymentdurationthroughthe

reservationwage,theconditionalsurvivorfunction,S( e

j u

),istheexpected survivor function, ES(

e

(9)

e u e u wa e a Z 1 w  u exp(  e  e (s)) ( f(s) 1 F(w   u ) ) ds (2)

While (2.1) establishes the negative relationshipbetween unemployment

duration and re-employment wages, (2.2) illustrates that declining reserva-tion wages createa negative relationshipbetween unemployment and

subse-quentjobduration. Altogether,(2.1) and(2.2)illustratetheMatchinge ect

of UI. As intuitive as it is, the matching e ect of UI may turn out to be much weaker than what one would normally expect. In reality, UI is known

to su er from potential moral hazard problems. If a signi cant fraction of

the unemployed use UI to nance household activities (including leisure), or search less intensively when entitled to more generous bene ts, changes

in the escape rate out of unemployment may be explained by changes in

search intensity and it is not altogether clear that a matching e ect of UI would prevail at all possible levels of unemployment duration. As well, and

as mentioned above, Adverse Selection could alsocause a spurious negative

correlation between unemployment duration and subsequent job duration. For instance, if those individuals who have a low search intensity are also

those who have ahigh propensity to quittheir subsequent job, the negative

correlation between unemployment and job duration would exist indepen-dently of the Matching e ect. The need for a exible estimation method,

in which the true e ect of bene t duration can be separated from Adverse

Selection, is thereforequite obvious.

As is usually the case in applied econometrics, the investigator is faced

with the option of estimating a fully structural version of the model or a

reduced-form version. In the present case, it seems natural to model job matchquality using data on accepted job durationand focus on a

reduced-form version of the model. First, modeling job and unemployment duration

(asopposedtoafullyspeci edstructuralmodel)willallowustoavoid mak-ing strong parametric assumptions about the key parameters of the model,

such as the wage distribution. Second, as in most administrative data sets,

re-employment wages are not fully reliable and are truncated beyond a cer-tain level. Finally, modeling job and unemployment durations exibly will

avoid imposing smooth unemployment exit rates. Indeed, the sudden

(10)

model based on the rationalexpectation hypothesis. For allthese reasons, I

focus on the reduced-form version of the model and use the durationof the

subsequent job asa measure of job matchquality.

3 The Canadian Unemployment Insurance

Sys-tem

The econometric model is estimated from a panel of Canadian labor force participants which is extracted from the Longitudinal Labor Force File of

Employment and Immigration Canada. In what follows, I provide a brief

discussion of the Canadian UI system. The Canadian Unemployment Insur-ancesystem(nowcalledEmploymentInsurance)wasestablishedin1940. As

mostUIsystemsinwesterncountries,itsfundis nancedbypremiacollected

from employers and employees. After having remained intact between 1940 and 1971, Canada's UI system was changed substantially in 1971. The

in-crease incoverage and inthe bene trate, which tookplace in1971-72,were

substantial. At the same time, the maximum bene t period was extended and the minimumperiodof employment requiredto qualify forbene ts was

reduced. Although the 1971-72 changes were partially reversed by changes

made between 1977 and 1979 (small reduction in the replacementratio and

in the maximum bene t duration, the Canadian UI system remained quite generous (compared tomost US states) over the period of the current

anal-ysis.

As in many countries, the rules determining bene t durationin Canada are set by the government through a formula that depends on individual

previous labormarkethistory. Basically,those individualswho have worked

more than a minimum number of weeks (10 to 14 weeks depending on the regional unemployment rate) can qualify for unemployment bene t. Unlike

many US states, Canadian workers who quit their jobs are eligible for UI

compensation. During the periodcovered by the data, those who quit their job couldhave been penalizedfor aperiod of6 weeks. Whilethe exogeneity

of the maximum bene t periodfor job quitters can be questioned seriously,

those individuals who have been laid o cannot in uence the length of the bene t period once unemployed. As a consequence, it is reasonable to

(11)

as-exogenous. Indeed, this isa standard assumption inthe literature.

The analysispresentedinthis paperisbasedonasampleof young males

who have experienced a layo between January 1976 and February 1978. Over this period, the average bene t period was slightly decreased after

changes to the UI regulations. This change took place in September 1977.

In the sample used in this study, the di erence in maximum bene t dura-tion between those who have experienced job separation before September

77 and those after is around 3 weeks. 6

For all those individuals who have

experienced a layo in between January 1976 and February 1978, the ben-e t rate has however remained constant at 66% of insurable earnings. The

maximum insurable earningsare typicallyadjusted yearly tore ect changes

in the average industrial salary. Over the sampleperiod,individuals had to workbetween10to14weeksinordertoqualifyforbene t(dependingonthe

regionalrateofunemployment). The potentialbene tdurationiscalculated

from the number of weeks of employment over the 52 week period and the local rate of unemployment at the time. Except for those working in the

shing industry (excluded inthis study), there are no variationsin UI rules

according toindustry.

4 The Data

In this section, I describe the original data set and then explain the

sam-pling method. The data are constructed as an event history data set and covers a period going from January 1972 until December 1984. It contain

several pieces ofinformationaboutemploymentand unemployment spellsof

arandomsampleofCanadianlaborforceparticipants. Thedataareactually based on amerge of several administrative les such asRecords of

Employ-ment(ROE) and theUnemploymentInsurance administrative les andthey

enable the researcher to recreate the sequence of labor market states occu-pied by a given individual. As is usually the case with administrative data,

information on insured spells of unemployment (such as bene t durations

and the weekly bene t level) are relativelyaccurate. However, the data are much less reliable when it comes to evaluating the labor market status of

6

Foranindepthanalysisofthee ectsofthechangesinlegislationonboththeduration andtheincidenceofunemployment,seeBelzil(1995).

(12)

beyond bene t termination.

The Records of Employment (ROE) identify the reason for separation

and provide information about job tenure, age, experience and industry. In Canada, rms are legally required to issue a ROE for every job separation

that takes place. The measure of experience available is the total number

of weeks of employment from 1972 until 1984. It is therefore reliable for youngerworkers. TheUnemploymentInsurance le, alongwithsomepartial

income tax records le, give information about potential bene t duration

for the unemployed, weekly insurable earnings, unemployment duration, UI bene t leveland the numberof weeksof bene tentitlementleftwhena new

job is accepted. The employer code available is used to identify individuals

who have been laido and returned with the same employer subsequently. The key UI variables are de ned asfollows;

 Initial (maximum) Bene t Duration: The maximum number of

weeks of UI bene ts that an individual can draw as recorded in the

UnemploymentInsurance Fileby thedateof theformalapplication. It iscalculatedbasedonthenumberofweeks worked duringthe previous

year, up to a certain maximum (around 45) which may depend itself

on the local rate of unemployment. When an individual experiences a subsequent spell (under the same claim), initial bene t duration is

reduced by the numberofweeks used duringthe previous spell. Given

the legislative changes and individual di erences in previous employ-mentandunemployment,thereissubstantialsamplevariationininitial

entitlement at the beginning of a spell. For a few individuals in the

sample,themaximumbene tdurationisindeed0week. 7

This is read-ily seen in the table reserved for summary statistics (Table 1). The

meaninitialbene t durationis33weeks but the standard deviationis

14weeks.

 Potential bene t duration: The di erence between maximum

ben-e t duration and elapsed unemployment duration. When elapsed

du-rationexceedsmaximumbene tduration,potentialbene tdurationis set to 0.

7

(13)

calculated frominformationon weekly insurable earnings.

4.1 Sampling Method

The data set used in this paper contains 2610 individual records of labor markethistoriesforyoung maleswhohavesu ered ajobseparationbetween

January1976and February1978. Eachindividualwasbetween 18and25at

the time of the jobseparation and was followed until1984 through adminis-trativerecords. Consequently, the numberof spellsattached toeachrecords

varies considerably across individuals. 8

Out of these 2610 records, 1910 are coded as layo swhile 700 individualsquit tobecome unemployed.

Asa rststep,Iretainthe1910individualswhohaveexperiencedalayo .

Asasecondstep, Iexcludethe1001caseswhereunemploymentwasfollowed by a job with the previous employer as wellas the 700 individuals quo quit

their job. This is because those individuals who returned to their previous

employer are most likelyto be ontemporary layo s and are likelyto have a

distinct search behaviorfrom those who were displaced permanently. Those who quit their jobare more likely tohave aweaker attachment tothe labor

market. 9

Theresultingsamplecontains909individualswhohaveexperienced

an involuntary job separation. Most of these individuals (889 cases) have found a new job with a di erent employer while 20 of them have been lost

bythe UIauthoritieswhichmeansthatI observenosubsequent jobduration

for these individuals. Given that reported unemployment duration is likely to be unreliable for these individuals, I censor unemployment duration at

50 weeks. In terms of the subsequent jobs, these 909 individual records are

classi ed as followed;

 464 subsequent job durations whichwere later terminatedby alayo

 289 subsequent job durations terminated by a quit.

8

Although the original le contains information on multiple unemployment and em-ploymentspells, for the current study, I only had access to asingle unemployment and jobspellperindividual.

9

Belzil(1995)hasperformedaseparateanalysisofthosewhoareontemporarylayo s and found that the e ect of UI bene t on unemployment duration and re-employment duration (unemployment incidence) di ered substantially from the e ects obtained for thoseindividualswhoacceptedanewjob.

(14)

 20cases where the unemployment spell isthe last recorded state.

Withadministrativedata,itisquitediÆculttocollectinformationon

in-dividuals who become non-participants. Among allindividualsexperiencing

alayo duringthisperiod(notonlyyoungworkers), only3.7%haveactually left the accepted job to leave the labor force. However, as this information

is actually estimated from the existence of subsequent employment

record-s, this number can only be viewed as an estimate. As I look only at young maleswhomarewellknowntohaveahighturnoverrate,only15%(136/909)

are still employed with same employer at the end of 1984. To summarize,

each individual contributes, at most, one unemployment duration-accepted job durationsequence. Somesummary statistics are found inTable1.

(15)

Some Sample Statistics

Variable Mean Stand. Dev.

Experience(weeks) 127 61

Previous Earnings (1977 dollars) 240 120

Duration of unemployment (weeks) 14 18 Maximum Bene t Period (weeks) 33 14

Potential Bene t period (atre-employment) 6 3

UnemploymentBene ts ( 1977 dollars) 122 30 Previous Job Duration (weeks) 22 29

Accepted Earnings(current dollars) 223 102

Duration of Accepted job (weeks) 35 65

% inPrimary Sector 7.1 -% inConstruction 7.2 -% inManufacturing 18.7 -% inTransportation 11.0 -% inTrade 13.6 -% inFinance 11.2 -% inServices 15.4 -% inAdministration 15.3 -Notes:

 Earnings and unemployment bene ts are measured in 1977 Canadian

dollars.

 For the period over which job separation took place, the maximum bene t level was around145$ per week.

(16)

True State Dependence from Spurious

S-tate Dependence

The analysispresented inthispaperisbasedonamulti-stateduration

mod-el which is used to estimate the e ects of unemployment insurance bene t duration on subsequent job match quality (subsequent job duration). Job

durationis de ned as the waitingtime until the subsequent job(followinga spellofunemployment)isterminated voluntarily. Themodelhasthe

follow-ingfeatures;

 Thedistributionof subsequentjob durationdependsoncompleted

un-employment duration (contiguous duration dependence) and the

de-pendence is speci ed such that I can distinguish between a potential bene t duratione ect and ageneral unemploymentduratione ect.

 The escape rate out of unemployment depends on the potential

(re-maining)bene t period (atime-varying co-variate).

 Unemployment duration and accepted job duration are stochastically relatedthrough unobserved heterogeneity.

5.1 Modeling the Hazard Functions

Inordertoestimatethee ectofbene tdurationonsubsequent jobduration I have to model two separate durations; unemployment duration and

sub-sequent job duration. Because semi-parametric estimations of each hazard

function would require the estimation of a very large number of parameters on top of the already large number of regression parameters which I have

to estimate, I restrict myself to a parametric representation of the baseline

hazardfunctions. I howeverestimatethedistributionof theunobserved het-erogeneity terms using a exible method.

As a starting point, I model the hazard function for the durationof

un-employment. This is the hazard function given maximum bene t duration t



. At this stage, it is useful to discuss duration dependence. Duration

(17)

caused by unobserved (neglected)heterogeneity. The speci cation of a

haz-ardfunctionwherepotentialbene tdurationchangeseveryweekwillcapture

durationdependence inthe search behaviorofthe unemployed causedbyUI bene t exhaustion. Other duration e ects will typically be captured in the

baselinehazard.

Ispecifytheunemploymenthazardfunctionasproportionalhazards mod-el with a time varying covariate (potentialbene t duration) modeland

un-observed heterogeneity and aWeibull (ratherthan non-parametric)baseline

hazard. 10

Denoting unemployment duration(in continuous time) by  u

, let-ting Z

u

denote the set of time-invariantcovariates and X( u

) the potential

bene t durationat agiven point in time,it is easyto see that

Pr( u t u +1j u t u )=exp f exp(Z u ' u +Æ(X(t u ))X(t u )+log" u +h  0 (t u ; ))g (3) where h  0 (t u ; ) =log((t u +1) t u

) and is a parameter to be estimated.

X(t u

)isthedi erencebetweenmaximumbene tduration(t 

)minuselapsed unemploymentduration indiscrete time (t

u ); that is X(t u )=Max(t  t u ;0)

The marginale ect of potentialbene t durationonthe unemployment haz-ard, Æ(X(t

u

)), is discussed in more details below. I assume that UI bene t

entitlement changes between intervals (from one week to another) but

re-mains constant within each interval (between t u

and t u

+1): The vector of time invariant regressors (Z

u

) includes age (as measured at the start of the

unemploymentspell),experience and industrialclassi cation.

For observations censored at t u , Pr( u t u )= tu 1 Y s=1 exp ( exp(Z u ' u +Æ(X(s))X(s)+log" u +h  0 (s; ))) (4) 10

Notethatmosttheoreticalmodelsbasedonjobsearchorjobmatchingarguments pre-dictthatthejobhazardratesaredecliningwithtenure. Empiricalevidencealsosuggests thatjob exitratesaredecliningwithtenure(seeDevineandKiefer,1991,forasurvey).

(18)

around 30 weeks while the maximum is 45 (for 7 individuals). Because UI

oÆcials report that recorded unemployment durationis likely to be

inaccu-rate for those who have very long durations, I censor every duration at 50 weeks.

In order to take intoaccount that the e ect of a decrease in one week of

bene tentitlementmaychangeasbene tterminationapproaches,Iestimate a more general speci cation where the e ects of potential bene t period is

allowed to vary over the duration of unemployment. This is accomplished

using the following set of variables; X(t u ); X 20 29 , X 10 19 ; X 6 9 and X 1 5 : These variables are de ned as follows;

X 20 29 =X(t u ) if X(t u )29and 0 if not X 10 19 =X(t u ) if X(t u )19and 0 if not X 6 9 =X(t u ) if X(t u )9and 0if not X 1 5 =X(t u ) if X(t u )5and 0if not

Altogether,thesevariablesmeasuretheremainingweeksofUIbene tateach

point inthe unemploymentspell. Withmore than 29weeks remaining,only potentialbene t duration (X(t

u

))takes non-zero values. When the number

of weeks of UI bene t remaining lies between 20 and 29, both X(t u

) and

X 20 29

takenon-zero values. As asimilarargumentisappliedtothe remain-ing segments (1 to 5 and 6-9), it follows that the marginal e ect of a week

of UI bene t is captured by summing the coeÆcients appropriately. As the

potentialbene t period decreases with elapsedunemploymentduration, the marginale ect ofanadditionalweek ofbene trepresentsthe counterfactual

e ectofmovingbackwardintime,away frombene ttermination. Itisgiven

by

(19)

20 29 10 19 weeks,  Æ +Æ 20 29 +Æ 10 19 +Æ 6 9

when the current entitlement is between 6

and 9 weeks  Æ +Æ 20 29 +Æ 10 19 +Æ 6 9 +Æ 0 5

within5weeksof bene ttermination.

As anexample, ifthe sumof allthe coeÆcientsfromÆ+Æ 20 29 +Æ 10 19 + Æ 6 9 +Æ 0 5

is negative, this indicates that, within 5 weeks from bene t ter-mination, the hazard decreases with each additional week of potential

(re-maining) bene t duration or, in other words, that the hazard increases as

the individualapproaches bene ttermination. The e ect of losingaweek of bene t is therefore simplythe opposite of the appropriate sum of the spline

parameter estimates.

Finally, the last componentof the modelis subsequent job duration. As stated earlier,accepted job durationis understood asthe waiting time until

the individualquitsthe accepted job andis meant tomeasure the quality of

the job match. Accepted job spellsterminated by reasonsother than a quit areconsideredascensored acceptedjobdurations. Thissimplymeansthata

jobterminated by layo was stillacceptabletothe worker. Given my

objec-tiveto estimate the e ects of UI bene t duration onaccepted job duration, I must allow the accepted job hazard to depend on completed

unemploy-ment duration as well as a measure of bene t termination. I simplymodel

accepted job duration using a proportional hazard with a Weibull baseline distribution. As I do with unemployment duration, I assume that recorded

job duration takes discrete values which are generated from a continuous

randomvariable, j

; whichhazard function isgiven by

h j ( j jt u ;" j )=exp (Z 0 j  j + 0 t u + 1 t u;50 +X(t u )+log" j )  1 j (5) where Z j

is a vector of regressor including experience, age and industrial classi cationdummies. Thee ectofunemploymentdurationismeasuredby

t u

(when durationisbeloworequal to50) and t u;50

(a binary variableequal

to1forthose unemployed more than50weeks) while X(t u

)is thenumberof weeks ofbene t leftwhen theindividual leftunemploymenttoaccepta new

job. For instance, X(t u

) is 0 for all those who found a job following bene t

(20)

tion left to vary over the total bene t duration period and make use of the variables X(.),X 20 29 ,X 10 19 ;X 6 9 and X 1 5

in order toobtain the ex-post

e ect of potential bene t duration onaccepted job duration. The associat-ed parameters are;  20 29 ; 10 19 ; 6 9 and 0 5

:As forthe unemployment

hazards, the e ects of potential bene t duration on accepted job hazards is

measured by the sum of the appropriate coeÆcients.

5.2 Constructing the Likelihood Function

I construct the likelihood function as if exact spell lengths are unknown but I assume that the interval during which failure time takes place are

known. The likelihood function can easily be constructed. If we assume

that conditional on unobserved heterogeneity, unemployment duration and accepted job durationare independent,the likelihoodfunction issimplythe

product oftwoindividualdensities. Noting that the numberof accepted job spells (M) is smaller than the number of unemployment spells (N), the 2

components are asfollows

 Unemployment Duration L u (t u j t  ;" u )= N Y i=1 [1 exp ( exp(Z 0 u  u +ÆX(t ui )+log" u +h  0 (t ui ; )))] c u i " tui 1 Y s=1 exp ( exp(Z 0 u  u +ÆX(s)+log" u +h  0 (s; ))) #

The censoring indicator,c u i

;equals 1 ifa spelliscompleted (between t ui

and t

ui

+1)and 0if right censored.

 Accepted Job Duration

L j (t ji j t  ;t u ;" j )= M Y h 0 j  i c j i

(21)

4 t ji 1 Y s=1 exp ( exp(Z 0 j  j + 0 :t u + 1 :t u;50 +:X(t u )+log" j +h  0 (s; ))) 5 where c j i

is the censoring indicatorfor accepted job durationand is de ned

similarly as c u i

: Given these de nitions, the conditional likelihood function,

L(t ui ;t ji jt i ;" u ;" j ); is simply L(t u ;t j j" u ;" j ;t  )=L u (t u j" u ;t  ):L j (t j jt  ;t u ;" j ) (6) 5.3 Unobserved Heterogeneity

Estimationofthemodelby likelihoodtechniquesrequiresthattheindividual

unobserved heterogeneity terms be integrated out. In the paper, I consider

the case where " u

and " j

follow a bi-variatediscrete distribution and where both"

u and"

j

havetwopointsofsupport. Thedistributionissummarizedas

follows;Pr (" u =" u 1 ;" j =" j 1 )=p 1 ;Pr(" u =" u 2 ;" j =" j 1 )=p 2 ,Pr(" u =" u 1 ;" j = " j 2 )=p 3 and Pr(" u =" u 2 ;" j =" j 2 )=p 4 for " u 1 >" u 2 and " j 1 >" j 2 : In this case, 4 points of support and three free probabilities need to be estimated: The

likelihood functions to be maximized is an average of 5.4 over all possible combinationsofunobserved heterogeneity. Inordertoimplementthe model,

I de ne the population proportions as logistic transforms. 11

The model is

estimated with the Maximum Likelihood application in Gaussi 3.2.26 on a

Pentium 200. The loglikelihoodfunctionismaximizedusing the BFGS and the BHHH algorithms.

6 Empirical Results

In this section, the empirical results are presented. The main parameter estimates and the marginal e ects of approaching bene t termination are

discussed in Section6.1 whilegoodness of tis discussed in Section6.2.

11

Standarderrorsforallp's can beobtainedusingthe deltamethod. Itcanbeshown thatthecorrelationbetween"

u and"

j

canbeevaluatedbythefollowingexpression; Corr(" u ;" j )= p1p4 p2p3 p (p 1 +p 3 )(p 2 +p 4 )(p 1 +p 2 )(p 3 +p 4 )

. It follows that the restriction needed to

imposeindependence(acorrelationof0)between" u and" j issimplyq 3 =q 1 q 2 :Testing forindependence(giventhat"

u 1 6=" u 2 and" j 1 6=" j 2

)canbeachievedwithalikelihoodratio statisticwhichhasa

2 1

(22)

tion and Subsequent Job Duration

The main parameter estimates are found in Table 2. I present two set of

estimates; those obtained when past earnings are introduced (column 1) and those obtained when it is omitted(column2). I doso because previous

earningsare possibly correlated with unobserved heterogeneity. 12

The e ect of previous earnings on the exit rate out of unemployment is found to be

positive(0.38)and indicates that, otherthings equal, those withhigher

pre-unemployment earnings leave unemployment faster. 13

The e ect of bene t level is negative (-0.28) and indicates that, all else equal, those receiving

higher level of bene ts tend to leave unemployment later. Both results are

standard in the literature. The estimate for (0.93) indicates the presence ofnegativedurationdependence (thehazardfunctiondecreases withelapsed

unemploymentduration).

Ashasbeenfoundintheliterature,thee ectofpotentialbene tduration (captured inthe Æ's)varies with the levelof potentialbene t duration. The

spline estimates are -0.31 (Æ 0 5 ), -0.20 (Æ 6 9 ), -0.06 (Æ 10 19 ), 0.01 (Æ 20 29 ) and -0.03 (Æ). Only Æ 0 5 , Æ 6 9 and Æ 10 19

are signi cantly di erent from 0. In order to facilitate the understanding of the spline estimates, I have

summarized the marginal e ects of approaching bene t exhaustion for all

rangesconsidered. Inordertoillustratethee ect ofmovingclosertobene t termination,thesumofallappropriateparametersismultipliedby-1. These

marginale ects are found in Table 3. There isclear evidence that before19

weeksfrombene ttermination,potentialbene tdurationhas practicallyno

impactonunemploymenthazards. With10to19weeks ofbene t left,losing anadditionalweek (approaching bene tterminationby one week)raisesthe

hazard by 0.08 while between 6 to 9 weeks, the increase is 0.27. The e ect

is particularly strong within 5 weeks from bene t termination; the hazard increases by 0.58 for each additionalweek.

The exiblespeci cation ofthe e ect ofbene tdurationonaccepted job

duration (with ;  20 29 ; 10 19 ; 6 9 and  0 5

) allows me to compare the exit rate out of the subsequent job atvarious levels of potential bene t

du-12

Theparameter estimatesforage, experience and industrydummyregressors canbe foundinBelzil (2000).

13

(23)

Table 2) are -0.02 ( 0 5 ), -0.04( 6 9 ), -0.01( 10 19 ), 0.00 ( 20 29 ) and 0.01

(). In general, they are less signi cant than the unemployment duration

spline estimates. While only  0 5

and  6 9

appear reasonably signi can-t, a likelihood ratio test for the joint signi cance of the spline estimates

( 0 5

::.=... 20 29

=0)isrejectedatthe 5%level(thep-value is0.05). 14

The

spline estimates are therefore jointly signi cant. Similar to the unemploy-ment hazards, I have transformed the spline estimates into marginale ects

of approaching bene t termination on accepted job hazards. These

esti-mates, also found in Table 3, can be used to investigate the importance of the Matching e ect atvarious rangesof potential bene t duration. Overall,

I nd a patternrelativelysimilar tothe one observed for the unemployment

hazards; the e ect ofpotentialbene tis positive and stronger around bene- t termination. However, the parameter estimates are generally much lower

(in absolute values) than the e ect of potential bene t duration on

unem-ployment hazards. The Matching e ect is practically non-existent until the individual is left with less than 9 weeks of bene t duration. Within 6 to 9

weeks of bene t termination, every week of bene t lost translates into an

increase of 0.0392 in the accepted job hazard (as summarized in Table 3). Within 5 weeks, the e ect is 0.0639. After controlling for bene t duration,

the e ect ofan additionalweekof unemploymentonsubsequent job

hazard-s is positive (0.0256) but insigni cant. While the evidence in favor of the Matching e ect appears relatively weak, the importance of unobserved

het-erogeneity is well illustrated by the signi cance of the correlation estimate.

I nd the correlation between unemployment duration and subsequent job durationunobserved heterogeneity to be -0.60 and the asymptotict-ratio is

larger than 10. This should be taken as evidence that those who tend to

experience longer spells of unemployment are also those who tend to expe-rience shorter job spells. The parameter estimate for (

0

) is positive (0.03)

but insigni cant and indicates that, after conditioning on bene t duration,

unemploymentduration has nosigni cant e ect on subsequent jobhazards. Finally,thescaleparameterofthesubsequentjobhazardfunction( =0:85)

indicatesnegative durationdependence.

The estimatesincolumn2arethoseobtained whenpreviousearningsare included. Overall, the resultsappear una ected by the exclusionof previous

14

(24)

menthazardby afactor 0.61 between 0to5weeksfrombene ttermination,

by a factor of 0.28 between 6 and 9 weeks, and by 0.08 between 10 and 19

weeks from bene t termination. However, bene t duration does not seem to matter really when individuals are more than 19 weeks away from

ben-e t termination. As in the model with previous earnings, the estimates of

the e ect of potential bene t duration on subsequent job hazards indicate that most of the matching e ects of UI bene ts are located within 10weeks

from bene t exhaustion; the marginal e ect is around 0.06 within 5 weeks

from bene t termination and 0.03 between 6 and 9 weeks. Beyond 9 weeks, the spline estimates imply very low marginal e ects and, as a consequence,

there is practically noMatching e ect. The test for the joint signi cance of

 1 5 ; 6 9 ; 10 19 and  20 29

rejects the null hypothesis at5% and indicates that there is asigni cant matching e ect (the p-value is0.042).

To summarize,I nd some supportfor apositive e ect ofunemployment

bene t durationon subsequent job match quality. However, the results also indicatethatthee ectsofbene tdurationonunemploymenthazardsand

ac-ceptedjobhazards are locatedmostly within5weeksof bene ttermination.

When individualsare morethan 10weeks away frombene texhaustion, po-tentialUIbene tdurationhasvirtuallynoe ectonsubsequentjobduration.

ItshouldalsobenotedthatintheshortintervaloverwhichI ndaMatching

e ect of UI bene t duration, job hazards are much less sensitive to bene t termination than unemployment hazards. At the same time, I nd strong

evidence of a negative (and signi cant) correlation between unemployment

durationand jobduration. There istherefore muchsupportfor the Adverse Selection hypothesis.

6.2 Goodness of Fit

As is commonly done in applied microeconometrics, empirical frequencies (unemploymentandsubsequentjobdurations)canbecomparedtopredicted

frequencies in order to evaluate the relevance of the model. This is

particu-larly important in a framework where the baseline distribution is estimated using parametric methods. The unemployment duration frequencies are in

Table 4A and the subsequent job duration frequencies are in Table 4B. A

(25)

frequen-duration. Whilethe predicted subsequent durationfrequencies appear tobe

below actual job duration frequencies at short duration and exceed actual

(26)

Parameter Estimates

(1) (2)

Unemp. duration -

-Log Earnings 0.3822 (2.88)

-Bene t level (log) -0.2834 (3.01) -0.2935(2.92) Duration Dependence ( ) 0.9256 (6.68) 0.9221(6.58)

RemainingBene tDuration

Æ (1 5) -0.3076 (3.01) -0.3325(2.64) Æ (6 9) -0.1978 (2.27) -0.2032(2.36) Æ (10 19) -0.0567 (2.02) -0.0612(1.93) Æ (20 29) 0.0126 (1.18) 0.0139(0.85) Æ -0.0307 (0.83) -0.0298(0.56) Unobs. heterogeneity " u 1 0.5387 (2.89) 0.5832 (3.12) " u 2 0.3628 (2.28) 0.3394 (2.42) " j 1 0.3923 (3.18) 0.3623 (2.90) " j 2 0.2638 (2.02) 0.2341 (1.79) P 1 0.0645 (2.00) 0.0589 (1.83) P 2 0.3745 (2.57) 0.4005 (3.24) P 3 0.3834 (3.04) 0.3905 (2.36) Corr(" u ;" j ) -0.6020 (10.03) -0.6201 (9.63)

(27)

(1) (2)

Accepted job duration

Duration Dependence ( ) 0.8471 (4.24) 0.8395 (5.15) Unemp. Duration ( 0 ) 0.0256 (1.68) 0.0200 (1.68) Unemp. Dur 50 ( 1 ) 0.2015 (1.67) 0.1956 (1.74)

Bene tDuration Left

 X(1 5) -0.0247 (1.88) -0.0327 (1.90)  X(6 9) -0.0393 (1.68) -0.0356 (1.65)  X(10 19) -0.0067 (1.02) -0.0074 (1.39)  X(20 29) 0.0012 (0.57) 0.0059 (0.95)  X(tu) 0.0056 (0.89) 0.0059 (0.78) Log likelihood -1343.9 -1348.0 Notes:

Asymptotic t-ratios in parentheses.

Thep-valueforthelikelihoodratiotestforthenullthat X(1 5)

..=..

X(20 29) =

0is 0.0531 in column 1 and 0.042 in column 2. Estimates obtained under the null hypothesis can be found in Belzil (2000).

(28)

The Marginal E ects of Approaching Bene t Termination

on Unemployment and Subsequent Job Hazards

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Unemp. Unemp Sub. Job Sub. Job

Hazards Hazards Hazards Hazards

Prev. Earnings included excluded included excluded

Weeks of Bene t Left 0-5 0.5812 0.6128 0.0639 0.0627 6-9 0.2736 0.2803 0.0392 0.0300 10-19 0.0758 0.0771 -0.0001 -0.0056 20-29 0.0181 0.0159 -0.0068 -0.0118 30-50 0.0307 0.0298 -0.0056 -0.0059

Note: The marginale ectsof approaching bene ttermination, foundin

col-umn 1 and column 2, represent the e ect of losing an additional week of

potential bene t duration on unemployment hazards. The marginal e ects

of approaching bene t termination,found incolumn3 and column4, repre-sent the e ect of losing an additional week of potential bene t durationon

acceptedjobhazards. Bothofthemarecomputedusingtheappropriatesum

of the spline estimates (the Æ 0

s and the  0

(29)

Goodness of Fit: Unemployment Duration (1) (2) predicted actual freqencies freqencies Weeks 1-4 0.43 0.40 5-8 0.15 0.13 9-12 0.07 0.08 13-16 0.05 0.06 17-20 0.03 0.05 21-24 0.03 0.04 25-28 0.02 0.02 29-more 0.20 0.12 Table 4B

Goodness of Fit: Subsequent Job Duration

(1) (2) predicted actual frequencies frequencies Weeks 1- 10 0.16 0.19 11-20 0.13 0.17 21-30 0.15 0.15 31-40 0.09 0.08 41-50 0.05 0.06 51-60 0.05 0.04 61-70 0.05 0.03 71-more 0.32 0.28

(30)

ployment and Accepted Job Durations: Some

Simulations

At this stage, it seems natural to investigate the e ects of increasing

maxi-mum bene t duration. I have performedsimulations for two di erent types of individual; one entitled to 25 weeks and one entitled to 45 weeks. In

both cases, I have computed the increase in mean unemployment duration and mean accepted job duration following an increase of 1 week in

maxi-mum bene t duration. I have performed those simulations for both model

speci cations reported inthe paper.

Overall, the results indicate that the unemployment duration elasticity

ranges from 0.15 and 0.20. In terms of weeks, these estimates indicate that

increasingpotentialbene tdurationbyanadditionalweekwillincreasemean unemploymentdurationby 1.5to 1.1days

15

. The e ects of bene t duration

on accepted job durations are smaller. The elasticities range from 0.10 to

0.13. Increasingpotentialbene t durationby 1 week willincrease mean job durationby less than 1 day; the increase in job durationranges from 0.5to

0.8days. Althoughthee ect ofanincrease inbene tdurationmightappear

weak, one should bear in mind that the parameter estimates indicate that the matching e ect is located mostly at the end of the bene t period. As

a consequence, for all those leaving unemployment with a potential bene t

durationsuperior to5weeks, anincrease inbene tdurationhas virtuallyno

impactonthe subsequent jobhazardrate. Tosummarize,althoughboththe unemployment duration and accepted job duration e ects of an increase in

bene t durationare small, the increase inunemployment durationis higher

than the increase in accepted job duration. The negative e ects of bene t durationtherefore tend todominate the positive e ects.

16

15

The e ects of bene t duration on unemployment duration appear consistent with simulationresultsreportedbyvariousauthors. Forinstance,HamandRea(1987)report that anincrease of1weekin bene t durationincreasesunemployment durationby0.16 to 0.20week. Forareview, seeDevine andKiefer(1991). AsfarasI know,thee ect of bene tdurationonjobdurationcannotbecomparedtoanystudy.

16

All the results reported previously are based on the hypothesis that the matching e ects of UIbene ts aremeasured bythe waiting timeuntil an individual will quit the postunemploymentjob. Inordertochecktherobustnessoftheresultstothede nitionof

(31)

Simulatingthe E ects of an Increase in Bene t Duration (1) (2) (3) (4) %Unemp:Duration %Benefit:Duration %Job:Duration %Benefit:Duration Ben. dur 25 weeks 45 weeks 25 weeks 45 weeks

Table 3,col1 0.19 0.16 0.13 0.11

Table 3,col2 0.20 0.15 0.13 0.10

Note: Simulationshavebeen computedatthemaximumbene tduration

of 25weeks and 45 weeks.

8 Conclusion

It is generally considered that UI bene t generosity induces those who have losttheirjobtoremainunemployedforlongerperiods. Thee ectsofUI

bene- tgenerosityonthequalityofpost-unemploymentlabormarketadjustments

are however not as clear. In this paper, I have tried to measure the e ects of potential UI bene t duration on the quality of subsequent job matches

and investigated whether the correlation between completed unemployment

duration and subsequent job duration is explained by Job Matching or by Adverse Selection.

Overall, I nd the Job Matching e ect to be weak. While there is a

structural e ect of bene t duration taking place shortly before bene t ter-mination,the negative correlation between unemployment and job duration

isde ned asthewaiting timeuntil theacceptedjob isterminated either byalayo ora quit. This canbejusti ed bythefact that thedistinctionbetweenquits andlayo scan sometimes beinsigni cant. Despitethefact thatacceptedjob durationis re-de ned,the changesintheestimatesofbene tdurationontheacceptedjobdurationhazardfunction are quite marginal. The resulting elasticities (ranging between 0.08 and 0.11)indicate that anincreaseof 1week in bene t durationwillincrease acceptedjob duration by 0.4 to0.8day. MoredetailscanbefoundinBelzil (2000).

(32)

ployment bene t duration will only have a marginal e ect on subsequent

job duration. The results of various simulationsindicatethat increasingthe

maximum bene t duration by one week will raise expected unemployment durationby1.0 to1.5daysbut expectedjobdurationby0.5to0.9daysonly.

It is well known that an increase in unemployment hazards can be

ex-plainedby anincrease insearche ort, a decrease inreservation wages orby implicit recall arrangements between workers and rms. Since workers

re-turningtothesame employerare eliminatedfromthe sample,the larger

sen-sitivity of unemployment hazardstobene t termination, whencompared to subsequentjobhazards, seemstoindicatethatreservationwages donotdrop

substantially. Perhaps, the increase in unemployment hazards is explained

mostly byanincrease insearche ort. At thesametime, thestrong negative correlation between unemployment durationheterogeneity and accepted job

duration heterogeneity is harder to explain. As unobserved heterogeneity is

meantto capture the e ects of all omittedcharacteristics onunemployment andjobdurationoutcomes, givingastructuralinterpretationtothe negative

correlation (after controllingfor bene t duration) can beseen as hazardous.

As stated before, Adverse Selection is one of the potential interpretation of the strong negative correlation between unemployment durationand

subse-quent job duration. If individuals, who have a strong taste for leisure or

household production, tend to exhaust their bene ts and accept jobs that last long enough to re-qualify for UI bene ts, the data would certainly

ex-hibitnegativecorrelation between unemploymentjobdurationandaccepted

jobduration. Assearch e ortisinherentlyunobservable, thistypeofsorting e ect is probably unavoidable. This suggests an avenue for future research.

Structuraljobsearchmodels,whichareestimatedfrommicro-dataandbased

onthe maintainedhypothesisthat individualsstartsearching oncetheyhave losttheirjob,shouldperhapsbemodi edtotakeintoaccountthathousehold

production(or leisure)is asubstitute tojob search activities.

9 References

(33)

Belzil, Christian (1990) "Unemployment Insurance, Unemployment and Labour Market Transitions: An Empirical Analysis with Canadian Data"

Unpublished DoctoralDissertation, Graduate School, CornellUniversity.

Classen, K.P. (1977) "The E ects of Unemployment Insurance on the

Du-ration of Unemployment and Subsequent Earnings" Industrial and Labor

Relations Review 30 (8):438-444.

Devine,TheresaandKiefer, NicholasM.(1991)EmpiricalLaboreconomics:

The Search Approach. Oxford University Press, New York

EhrenbergR.G.andRonaldOaxaca(1976)"UnemploymentInsurance, Du-ration of Unemployment and Subsequent Wage Gain" American Economic

Review 66: 754-766.

Han,Aaron andHausman, Jerry(1990)"FlexibleParametricEstimationof

Duration andCompetingRisk Model". Journal of Applied Econometrics,5,

:325-353.

Ham, John and Rea, Samuel (1987) "Unemployment Insurance and Male

UnemploymentDurationinCanada",JournalofLaborEconomics,5 (3):325-53.

Hopenhayn,Hugo and Juan Pablo Nicolini(1997) \OptimalUnemployment Insurance", Journal of PoliticalEconomy" , 105 (2): 412-38.

Meyer, Bruce (1990)"UnemploymentInsurance andUnemploymentSpells", Econometrica, 58 (4): 757-782.

(34)

Liste des publications au CIRANO *

Cahiers CIRANO / CIRANO Papers (ISSN 1198-8169)

99c-1

Les Expos, l'OSM, les universités, les hôpitaux : Le coût d'un déficit de 400 000 emplois

au Québec — Expos, Montréal Symphony Orchestra, Universities, Hospitals: The

Cost of a 400,000-Job Shortfall in Québec / Marcel Boyer

96c-1

Peut-on créer des emplois en réglementant le temps de travail? / Robert Lacroix

95c-2

Anomalies de marché et sélection des titres au Canada / Richard Guay, Jean-François

L'Her et Jean-Marc Suret

95c-1

La réglementation incitative / Marcel Boyer

94c-3

L'importance relative des gouvernements : causes, conséquences et organisations

alternative / Claude Montmarquette

94c-2

Commercial Bankruptcy and Financial Reorganization in Canada / Jocelyn Martel

94c-1

Faire ou faire faire : La perspective de l'économie des organisations / Michel Patry

Série Scientifique / Scientific Series (ISSN 1198-8177)

2001s-20

Estimating the Intergenerational Education Correlation from a Dynamic

Programming Model / Christian Belzil et Jörgen Hansen

2001s-19

The Bootstrap of the Mean for Dependent Heterogeneous Arrays / Sílvia

Gonçalves et Halbert White

2001s-18

Perspectives on IT Outsourcing Success: Covariance Structure Modelling of a

Survey of Outsourcing in Australia / Anne C. Rouse, Brian Corbitt et Benoit A.

Aubert

2001s-17

A Theory of Environmental Risk Disclosure / Bernard Sinclair-Desgagné et

Estelle Gozlan

2001s-16

Marriage Market, Divorce Legislation and Household Labor Supply /

Pierre-André Chiappori, Bernard Fortin et Guy Lacroix

2001s-15

Properties of Estimates of Daily GARCH Parameters Based on Intra-Day

Observations / John W. Galbraith et Victoria Zinde-Walsh

2001s-14

A Ricardian Model of the Tragedy of the Commons / Pierre Lasserre et Antoine

Soubeyran

2001s-13

Carbon Credits for Forests and Forest Products / Robert D. Cairns et Pierre

Lasserre

2001s-12

Estimating Nonseparable Preference Specifications for Asset Market Participants /

Kris Jacobs

2001s-11

Autoregression-Based Estimators for ARFIMA Models / John W. Galbraith et

Victoria Zinde-Walsh

2001s-10

Heterogeneous Returns to Human Capital and Dynamic Self-Selection / Christian

Belzil et Jörgen Hansen

Références

Documents relatifs

There is some bivariate evidence that life satisfaction actually falls with unemployment duration in the ECHP data, but this change in life satisfaction for the unemployed is

Apparition of γ -ZrH hydrides (~2 wt.%) (potentially metastable) at the end of cooling in both cases Not shown here but presence of metastable γ -ZrH hydrides also observed at

Une approche comme celle que nous allons développer dans cette thèse, fondée sur la faculté interne qu'est la syntaxe, conduit à remettre en cause le présupposé référentialiste et

In order to isolate the causal effect of an extension of the maximum benefits payment period, we compared the future of beneficiaries in stream 2 who would have been in stream

C’est dans la deuxième perspective que notre recherche s’inscrit en adoptant une approche contingente pour expliquer la relation entre la taille et le niveau de la formalisation

Decreased levels of homoarginine and asymmetric dimethylarginine in children with type 1 diabetes: associations with cardiovascular risk factors but no effect by

Country- specific estimates based on a multivariate discrete-time duration model, which takes into account dynamic selection issues and the endogeneity of benefit receipt,

This non-stationarity implies that individuals with different lengths of benefit entitlement should have different optimal paths of reservation wage and search effort over time (Van