• Aucun résultat trouvé

Does income distribution affect innovation?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "Does income distribution affect innovation?"

Copied!
84
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

DOES INCOME DISTRIBUTION AFFECT INNOVATION? by

Apiwat Ratanawaraha M.Phil., Land Economy University of Cambridge, 1997

B.Eng., Urban Engineering University of Tokyo, 1996

Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of

Master in City Planning at the

Massachusetts Institute of Technology June 2002

@2002 Apiwat Ratanawaraha

All rights reserved

The author hereby grants to MIT permission to reproduce and to distribute publicly paper and electronic copies of this thesis document in whole or in part.

Signature of Author ... ...

Department Urban Studies and Planning May 16, 2002

Certified by. - - - - ---...-... Professor Alice H. Amsden

Department of Urban Studies and Planning

Thesis Supervisor

Accepted by ...

nis Frenchman

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE Chair, MCP Committee

OF TECHNOLOGY

Department of Urban Studies and Planning

JUL 0

2 2002

(2)

To my best

friend

(3)

DOES INCOME DISTRIBUTION AFFECT INNOVATION? by

Apiwat Ratanawaraha

Submitted to the Department of Urban Studies and Planning on May 16, 2002 in partial fulfillment of the requirements

for the Degree of Master in City Planning

ABSTRACT

In this study I specify econometric models that test the hypothesis that income distribution affects innovation. The econometric results suggest that countries with more equal income distribution spend more on innovative activity, produce more innovative outputs, and are more productive in producing innovations than those with less equal income distribution. Other significant determinants of innovation include income level, the size of economic activity, and population density.

However, my findings indicate that the effects of income distribution on innovation are limited to developing countries. Income distribution, the size of economic activity, and population density significantly affect innovation expenditures only in developing countries. Income level affects R&D expenditures in both developed and developing countries. Regarding the determinants of innovation output level, income distribution affects only developing countries, whereas the size of economic activity affects both developed and developing countries. Income level is not a significant factor in determining the level of innovation output. As for innovation productivity, income level is significant for both developed and developed countries, while income distribution and population density affect only developing countries. The size of economic activity is not a significant determinant of innovation productivity.

Income distribution has an effect only on developing countries, because knowledge and information, the essence of innovation, have the properties of increasing returns to scale due to externalities, and increasing marginal productivity. Income distribution affects innovation expenditure, innovation output, and innovation productivity by affecting the aggregate demand composition and human-capital accumulation. Because the market size and the stock of human capital are relatively small in developing countries, income distribution has significant effects on the size of market, the stock of human capital, and therefore innovation.

Thesis Supervisor: Alice H. Amsden Title: Professor of Political Economy

Reader: Karen R. Polenske

(4)

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This thesis would have ended up being only a term paper, if Professor Alice H. Amsden, my thesis advisor, had not encouraged me to develop the ideas further. I am sincerely grateful to Professor Karen R. Polenske, my faculty advisor and thesis reader, who has been supportive of me since my first day at MIT.

I am also grateful to my friends in DUSP, who have supported me through thick and thin. I am particularly grateful to Esther, Erica, and Chong Yean.

(5)

TABLE OF CONTENTS ABSTRACT--- 2 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS 4 TABLE OF CONTENTS 5 LIST OF TABLES 6 CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION 7

CHAPTER 2: THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK 10

I. Income Distribution 10

II. Innovation 15

III. Income Distribution and Innovation 20

CHAPTER 3: EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS 35

I. Descriptive Statistics---. 35

II. Hypothesis and Estimation Approach 38

III. Income Distribution and Innovation Investment 39

IV. Innovation Output and Productivity 50

V. Capital/Credit Markets and Innovation 53

VI. Inputs and Outputs of Innovation .--- 56

VII. Results Summary --- 57

CHAPTER 4: CONCLUSION 59

BIBLIOGRAPHY 63

APPENDIX I: LIST OF COUNTRIES IN THE SAMPLE 71

(6)

LIST OF TABLES

TABLE PAGE

3.1: Summary Statistics for Income Distribution and Innovation Measures --- 35 3.2: Summary Statistics by Regions._____________________________--- - 36

3.3: Sources of Funds for Research and Development by Region, 1999.____________--- 37

3.4: Summary of Variables---.44

3.5: Summary of Key Estimation Results____ ___ __... _56...

Al: Estimation Results for Regressions on GERD, Full Sample________ ...---- 72 A2: Estimation Results for Regressions on GERD, Sub-Samples 73 A3: Estimation Results for Regressions on GERD with Alternative Measures

of Income Distribution, Full Sample... 74 A4: Estimation Results for Regressions on PERD, Full Sample _______________---- 75 A5: Estimation Results for Regressions on PERD, Sub-Samples________________----76 A6: Estimation Results for Regressions on GERD with Alternative Measures

of Income Distribution, Full Sample.---..77

A7: Estimation Results for Regressions on PTENT, Full Sample___ ______________- 78 A8: Estimation Results for Regressions on PTENT, Sub-Samples_ ...----______ 79 A9: Estimation Results for Regressions on PTENTCAP, Full Sample_ ...----_____ 80 A10: Estimation Results for Regressions on PTENTCAP, Sub-Samples_ ...--_____ 81 Al 1: Estimation Results for Regressions on GERD with Financial-Sector

Development M easures ________ ____________________ _ 82

A12: Estimation Results for Regressions on GERD with Credit-Market

Imperfections Measures ___________________________--- 83

A13: Estimation Results for Regressions on Log of PTENT_ ...----________ 84

(7)

CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION

Income distribution and technological innovations are two of the most important issues in the field of economic development. Many analysts have proposed economic theories and conducted empirical studies on both issues, particularly with regard to their relationships with economic growth. Income distribution plays a crucial role in many of the development models, from those of earlier economists, such as Kuznets (1955) and Kaldor (1957), to the more recent ones, such as Galor and Zeira (1993) and Alesina and Rodrik (1994). It is now widely accepted that income distribution affects economic development through various channels, such as imperfect capital and credit markets and redistributive policy.

Technological innovations, on the other hand, have long been considered as the engine of economic development. Although the reference to technological progress is implicit in the writings of earlier economists, such as Adam Smith and Karl Marx, it was Schumpeter (1934) who first explicitly regarded innovation as the key determinant of economic growth. Since then, many economists have incorporated technological innovation into their analyses of economic growth, particularly in the recent literature of endogenous-growth models (e.g., Arrow 1962; Romer 1986; Grossman and Helpman 1991).

If income distribution indeed affects the economic development process, and innovation plays a crucial role in economic development, then a causal relationship is possible between income distribution and technological innovation. Given the substantial amount of interest in both issues, it is surprising that few analysts have proposed theoretical models that explain the causal relationships between income distribution and innovation, let alone conducted an

(8)

empirical study to test their relationships. Even among the more recent analysts, most tend to focus on the impact of technological innovation on income distribution (e.g., Lawrence and Slaughter 1993). To the best of my knowledge, there is no empirical study that investigates the issue of how income distribution affects technological innovations.

In light of the foregoing observation, I test empirically the causal relationship between income distribution and technological innovation (hereafter innovation). Specifically, I examine whether income distribution affects the amount of investment on innovative activities, innovation outputs, and innovative productivity. I also examine whether the effects are the same between developed and developing countries.

My main hypothesis is that countries with more equal income distribution are more

innovative than those countries with unequal income distribution. More specifically, I hypothesize that countries with more equal income distribution spend more on innovative activities, produce more innovative outputs, and are more productive in producing innovations than those with less equal income distribution.

Income distribution can affect innovation through several mechanisms. First, income distribution affects the aggregate demand and production composition, thus affecting the investment incentives of the entrepreneurs. Second, in the presence of credit-market imperfections, income distribution affects entrepreneurs' access to credits for investment, financial-sector development, occupational choices, relative profit margins, and human-capital accumulation. The third mechanism is one of redistributive policy, which affects firm size and market structure. Due to data availability, in this study, I test only two mechanisms through which income distribution may affect innovation: namely, financial-sector development, and credit-markets imperfection.

(9)

The thesis is organized as follows. In Chapter 2, I establish the theoretical framework for the empirical analysis of the impact of income distribution on innovation. First, I briefly review the concepts and characteristics of income distribution and innovation, focusing on the impact of income distribution on economic indicators that may determine the rates and directions of innovation. I then propose the possible mechanisms through which income distribution may affect innovation.

Within the conceptual framework, I describe and explain in Chapter 3 the methodology, variables, and data that I use for the regression analysis. I also discuss other possible determinants of innovations, which are used as the control variables. I then present the estimated results. In the concluding chapter, I examine some of the broader lessons and limitations that emerge from the analysis.

(10)

CHAPTER 2

THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

In this chapter, I establish the theoretical framework for the empirical analysis of the impact of income distribution on innovation. In the first section, I briefly review the concepts of income distribution and innovation, focusing on the impact of income distribution on economic indicators that may determine the rate and directions of innovation. In the second section, I review the theoretical models that investigate the impact of income distribution on innovation. Based on these reviews, I then propose the possible mechanisms through which income distribution may affect innovation.

I. INCOME DISTRIBUTION

In this section, I review the basic concepts of income distribution and the mechanisms through which income distribution affects economic development.

1. Basic concepts of income distribution

Philosophers have debated the definition of equality for centuries. At the metaphysical level, the notions of equality can be categorized into two distinct groups of meanings. In the first, equality signifies justice or fair treatment. In the second, equality indicates sameness or homogeneity. Equality as justice is a normative statement regarding the relations between persons, whereas equality as sameness is a positive statement of fact, postulating the common characteristics among people. The concept of equality stretches far beyond the realm of economics to include other related notions such as lifetimes, basic capability, and political freedoms (See Sen 1999 for detailed discussions).

(11)

At the level of economics, the concept of equality and distribution concerns the material choices the individual has, as compared with other individuals. Depending on the context, distribution may refer to the distribution of the asset stocks or the distribution of the income flows. It may refer to the distribution from a short-term perspective, e.g., income distribution at any one point in time, or from a long-term perspective, e.g., distribution of lifetime income.

Furthermore, there is a distinction between functional and personal income distribution. Functional income distribution is the distribution of the returns to different factors of production, namely labor and capital. Personal income distribution, on the other hand, refers to the returns that are funneled to households. The knowledge of how income is earned by households tells us about the relationship between income distribution and other features of development, such as innovation and growth. In this study, I limit the analysis within the realm of economics, focusing on the personal distribution of income at one point in time.

2. Income distribution and economic development

The issue of income distribution has been of great interest to economists for many years. The vast literature on income distribution and development can be categorized into two groups, according to the two possible types of causalities: i.e., one that focuses on the effect of economic growth on income distribution, and the other on the effect of distribution on growth.

The recent interest in the effects of income distribution on economic development started with a classic paper by Kuznets (1955). In the paper, Kuznets argues that income distribution is more equal at low levels of income in the early stages of development, then becomes more unequal as development proceeds, and eventually becomes equal again as countries approach the income level of the developed countries. The Kuznets hypothesis of this U-shaped curve has

(12)

since been a major topic for debate among economists. Many analysts have investigated the Kuznets inverted U-shape curve, relating the levels of income per capita to income distribution. Although some economists have found supporting evidence for the Kuznets hypothesis (e.g., Paukert 1973), the consensus seems to be developing in recent years that the parabolic relationship between income inequality and income level is weak (e.g., Anand and Kanpur 1993; Bourguignon 1995; Deininger and Squire 1998).

My interest in the effect of income distribution on innovation fits into the other group of

literature, which examines how income distribution affects growth. I categorize the substantial literature on the issue into two broad approaches. The two approaches are distinguished by their conflicting predictions and their differing explanations of the mechanisms through which distribution affects growth. One is the classical approach, which argues that inequality stimulates capital accumulation, and thus promotes economic growth. The other is the modem approach, which argues, in contrast, that equality can stimulate investment in human capital, and hence economic growth. The modem approach focuses on two key issues, namely, capital-market imperfections, and the political economy of inequality.

3. Income distribution and savings

The classical approach to explaining the effects of income distribution on economic growth was originated by Adam Smith (1776) and was further developed by Keynes (1920), Lewis (1954), and more recently Bourguignon (1981). The basis for this approach is the observation that saving rates of the rich are higher than those of the poor. Because of inequality, limited resources are channeled towards those whose marginal propensity to save is higher. This process increases aggregate savings, capital accumulation, and investment. As suggested by the Harrod-Domar and Solow growth models, the rate of savings affects the long-run level of per

(13)

capita income, and, in some cases, the rate of economic growth. Recently, Smith (2001) finds the empirical evidence that income distribution affects the private saving rate in both industrialized and developing countries.

4. Income distribution and credit-market imperfections

Credit market imperfection is another approach to understanding the impact of income distribution on economic development. Galor and Zeira (1993) argue that in the presence of credit markets imperfection, and a fixed up-front investment required for human capital accumulation, the initial income distribution of wealth affects aggregate output and investment, and thus economic development. This statement is based on the observation that an individual's collateral, i.e., her existing wealth, determines the degree to which she can have access to the credit market. In an unequal society in which many people do not have access to credit markets, poor people cannot accumulate enough wealth to cover the fixed cost of human capital.

5. Income distribution and political economy

Another approach to the effect of income distribution on growth includes the studies that relate income inequality to political pressure for redistributive policies. Persson and Tabellini (1994) show both theoretically and empirically that there is a significant relationship between inequality and economic growth. Their explanation is that inequality leads to policies that do not guarantee property rights and do not allow full private appropriation of returns from investment.

Alesina and Rodrik (1994) also find that the greater the inequality of wealth and income, the higher the rate of taxation, and the lower the rate of growth. Their basic argument is that in a

society where a large section of the population does not have access to productive resources, there is a strong pressure for redistribution. Instead of redistributing the existing stock of wealth,

(14)

many governments resort to taxing the increments to the stock of wealth. This type of taxation tends to reduce the rate of investment and therefore the rate of economic growth. Similarly, Alesina and Perotti (1996) examine the relationship between income inequality, socio-political instability, and investment. They also conclude that inequality affects investment and economic

growth.

6. A unified view

It is clear that the classical and modem approaches lead to conflicting predictions as to how income distribution affects economic growth. Some economists attempt to reconcile both approaches by re-defining the process of economic development. Galor and Moav (1999) propose an alternative approach to the issue. They argue that the replacement of physical capital accumulation by human capital accumulation as a prime engine of growth has changed the qualitative effect of income distribution on the process of development. A unified approach, as Galor (2000) puts it, holds that both classical and modem explanations could be true, depending on the stages of development. Inequality may have a positive effect on the process of development in early stages of development when physical accumulation is the engine of economic growth. In contrast, when human capital accumulation becomes crucial to economic development, equality has a positive impact on economic growth.

(15)

II. INNOVATION

In this section, I review the literature on the definition, the properties, and the determinants of innovation.

1. Definition of innovation

Although the word "innovation" has been used for some time, the use of the word in economics was relatively recent. According to the Oxford English Dictionary, Joseph Schumpeter was the first person who used the word to refer positively to the creative introduction of useful improvement. His concept of innovation includes "(1) the introduction of a

new good ... (2) the introduction of the new method of production ... (3) the opening of a new market ... (4) the opening of a new source of supply ... (5) the carrying out of the new

organization of any industry, like the creation of a monopoly position" (Schumpeter 1934, p. 66). Clearly, his concept of innovation includes both technological and organizational considerations. In this study, however, I focus only on technological innovation.

Innovation can be categorized as process innovation and product innovation. Process innovation is aimed at reducing the cost of producing existing goods. In other words, it is the deliberate effort to change the relationship between factor input proportions used by a firn to produce a given type and/or level of output. On the other hand, product innovation is aimed at inventing completely new commodities. Furthermore, according to the relationship of the newly invented products to the existing ones, innovative products are vertically related when they have similar functions to the existing goods but have better quality. On the other hand, new products are horizontally related when they have new functions, thereby expanding the variety in consumption or specialization in production.

(16)

2. Properties of Innovations

Innovations, like technology in its broad definition, are essentially information- and knowledge-based assets. Information and knowledge have some unique properties as an economic commodity, which may explain the determinants and effects of innovations in economic processes. As first argued by Arrow (1962) and later refined by Romer (1990), information has the property of a quasi-public good; that is, it is rival and partially non-excludable. It is non-rival, in that when one person uses certain information and knowledge to produce a good, this action does not preclude others from doing so, even simultaneously. It is partially non-excludable, in that the owners of the information sometimes find it difficult to prevent others from using it without compensation, even with legal protection of their intellectual property rights. The degree of excludability varies upon the policy choices of each society, which determines the duration and scope of protection, as well as the enforcement of the related laws. The difficulty arises precisely because information and knowledge are intangible, and thus are harder to secure.

The partial excludability of knowledge creates the possibility of technological spillovers generated by industrial R&D. According to Grossman and Helpman (1991), technological spillovers occur when (1) firms can acquire information created by others without compensating for it through market transaction, and (2) the creators or owners of the information have no effective recourse, if other firms utilize the information so acquired. Technological spillovers as a type of externalities may stimulate further innovation. This process is self-perpetuating, since investment in creating new knowledge stimulates further knowledge spillovers, which in turn create still more knowledge.

(17)

The property of partial excludability leads to another unique characteristic of knowledge and innovation. When new knowledge is used as a factor of production, the production of goods from the increased knowledge exhibits increasing returns to scale. In other words, knowledge demonstrates increasing marginal productivity. However, as shown by Romer (1990) in his endogenous growth model, when new knowledge itself is the objective of an R&D investment, the "knowledge production" exhibits diminishing returns. That is, a doubling of innovative investment will not produce double knowledge.

High initial costs in creating an innovation also lead to increasing returns to scale. In industries such as computer software, biotechnology and pharmaceutical industries, frmns spend a large proportion of their expenditure on research and development before they can actually sell a product innovation. Once the innovation is sold in the market, the marginal costs of producing an additional unit of innovation is very low. With the protection of intellectual property rights through patents, innovators can take advantage of the temporary monopoly by charging a price that exceeds it marginal costs of production.

These unique properties of information, knowledge, and innovation are important in understanding the determinants of innovation. They are also crucial to my attempting to establish the causal relationship between income distribution and innovation in the following chapter.

3. Determinants of Innovations

The literature is vast on the determinants of innovation. The foci and approaches vary greatly, from fin-level and industry-level studies to individual-country and cross-country studies. This study is primarily concerned with the determinants of innovation at the national level, so that I adopt a cross-country comparison as the methodology. Nevertheless, it is

(18)

important to understand the determinants of innovation at the firm level, because it is at the firm level where innovations are actually produced.

The variables investigated at the firm and industry levels range from firm characteristics, such as firm size, corporate governance system, and investment strategies (e.g., Cockburn and Henderson 1996; Morck and Yeung 2001), to market characteristics and types of industries (e.g., Schumpeter 1942; Scherer 1982). The debate revolves around the issue of optimum firm sizes for innovation and monopoly power in the industry. I discuss this issue later in detail in the section where I explore the effect of income distribution on redistributive policy, which, in turn, affects firm size and market structure.

At the macro-level, variables include institutional variables, such as property-right systems; policy variables, such as industrial and technology policies; and even non-economic variables, such as national cultures and religions (e.g., Rosenberg 1994). Furthermore, urban and regional economists have recognized the role of agglomeration economies in promoting innovation, because of knowledge spillovers between firms (e.g., Romer 1986; Porter 1990) or the existence of a pool of skilled labor (Henderson 1986). Some analysts have studied the effect of the agglomeration on economic growth (e.g., Glaeser et al. 1992; Gray and Markusen 1996).

There is a long debate in the innovation literature about the relative importance of "market pull" versus "technology push" in determining the rate and direction of innovation. Early analysts on the sources of technological change considered scientific discoveries as the primary source behind innovation. Scientific advances were regarded as the outcomes of

intellectual pursuits of scientists, whose motivation was purely the passion for novel knowledge, not the possible business profits. This scientific basis for innovation therefore removed innovative activities from the realm of economic analysis. Usher (1954) represented this school

(19)

of thought, considering "invention" as a result of an "act of insight" going beyond the practice of normal skills.

Some economists, however, take a different view. Joseph Schumpeter (1939) distinguishes his concept of innovation from that of invention, saying that "innovation is possible without anything we should identify as invention, and invention does not necessarily induce innovation." (p. 84) He believes that innovations are driven by the "businessman's hunt for profits." (Schumpeter 1942, p. 110) Schumpeter's argument is in line with the hypothesis that profit maximization is the most important motive for fmns.

Although the argument seems plausible, quantitative evidence has been scarce on the robustness of the connection between profits and expenditure on research and development (R&D). One empirical study that confmns Schumpeter's argument is that of Schmookler (1966). In his extensive study of important inventions in petroleum refining, paper making, railroading, and farming, Schmookler shows that the stimulus for innovation is the need to solve costly problems in production processes, or the desire to seize potentially profitable opportunities. In his view, it is the expected profitability of inventive activity that determines the pace and direction of industrial innovation.

Similarly, a recent study by Scherer (2001) confirms the linkage between profitability and R&D spending at the firm and industry levels in the pharmaceutical sector. According to Scherer, profitability and investments in R&D are linked in three distinct ways. First, successful research and development leads, with some time lags, to new products. Depending on the reception of the market, the new products could add to firm profits. Second, the profits earned by a company serve as a source of funding for R&D. Third, the expectation of managers for future profit opportunities can exert a demand-pull influence on R&D investment.

(20)

Other analysts have reconciled the arguments regarding the sources of innovation. According to Mowery and Rosenberg (1989), scientific discovery plays a great role in the process of technological innovation, but it takes considerable time before new scientific knowledge can become innovations. New discoveries that come out of pure research need additional applied research before they could become the economically useful knowledge. Similarly, Dosi (1988) contends that industrial innovations are the results of the interactions between technological opportunities created by scientific discoveries, inducements for applied research that emerge from market opportunities, and private appropriability of the benefits of innovation.

According to Dosi, many market-related factors could induce and determine the rate and direction of innovation. These factors are, for instance, the levels and changes of demand (market size and growth, and income elasticities of the various products), and the levels and changes in relative prices, particularly the relative price of labor to that of machines and the price of energy.

In this study, I limit the analysis within the realm of economics. I consider profits as the key stimulus to, and source of funding for, research and development, which, in turn, leads to innovative products and processes. It is profits that lure entrepreneurs to invest in innovative activity. This is the conceptual basis for the empirical analyses in the following chapter.

III. INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INNOVATION

The literature I have reviewed suggests that income distribution can affect savings, investment, risk bearing, and the composition of demand and production. In this section, I extend what I have learned from the literature and propose the possible mechanisms through which

(21)

income distribution may affect investment on innovation, innovative output, and its productivity. Three broad categories of mechanisms are possible. The first mechanism affects the demand and production composition, thus affecting the investment incentives of the entrepreneurs. Second, in the presence of credit-market imperfections, income distribution affects entrepreneurs' access to credits for investment, financial-sector development, occupational choices, relative profit margins, and human-capital accumulation. The third mechanism is one of redistributive policy,

which affects firm size and market structure.

1. Demand Composition, Market Size, and Profits

Income determines not only the level of consumption, but also its composition or pattern. According to Engel's Law, the different categories of consumption do not increase proportionally to income. When income rises, the share of basic items in total consumption tends to fall. For instance, at low levels of income, basic needs for food and clothing determine the consumption patterns. Once people become richer, these basic needs are saturated, and demand shifts to other categories of consumption. People demand goods of higher quality and sophistication. In other words, the systems of demand are not homothetic but hierarchical.

Demand composition is one of the channels through which income distribution affects innovation. If the individual's demand pattern depends on her income, the patterns of market demand for different products should vary with the income distribution in a society as well. A unique pattern of income distribution in a society means its overall pattern of expenditure and demand is different from that of other societies. Furthermore, because the different products demanded by consumers have to be produced and supplied, different demand patterns suggest that different products are sold in the market. In short, different patterns of income distribution lead to different demand compositions, thus different types of products supplied in the markets.

(22)

How does income distribution affect innovation through demand composition? As Baldwin (1956) and North (1959) have pointed out, extreme concentration of wealth among the rich results in the demand for handmade and imported luxury goods rather than for domestic manufactures. In other words, unequal income distribution means that there are not many rich and middle-class people who can afford innovative goods. Baland and Ray (1991) show a situation in which unequal assets distribution results in a high demand for luxury goods by the rich, as compared with basic goods.

As reviewed earlier, innovations require high front-end investment, which needs large markets to break even. Income distribution affects the level of demand and the market size for innovations. Here, I interpret unequal income distribution to mean that there are a great number of poor people and few rich people. This makes innovations less profitable, because the size of the market is smaller in the early stage of production. Lower profit margins then reduce entrepreneurs' incentives to invest in innovative activity.

A few analysts theoretically examine demand composition as the channel through which

income distribution becomes a determinant of innovation. Falkinger (1994) presents an Engelian growth model in which income distribution affects product development, when consumers have hierarchic preferences. Although his model considers the effects of income distribution on product demand, it does not regard horizontal product differentiation as innovation. Horizontal product differentiation here refers to product innovation that leads only to new brands of essentially the same goods. In the Falkinger model, product innovation leads to new products based on vertical product differentiation, where in each category of demand the existing products are substituted by new ones of better quality. In addition, he also considers a more fundamental type of innovation, i.e., the development of new categories of demand.

(23)

Similarly, Zweimuller (2000) develops an innovation-driven growth model that captures the effect of income distribution on innovation, with the assumption of hierarchic preferences. In

this model, income distribution affects the incentives to innovate by affecting not only the level, but also the growth, of demand for innovator's products. The model suggests that societies that

are more equal and have higher economic growth will be more innovative.

In both the Falinger and Zweimuller models, income distribution affects the demand but does not impact the prices of new goods. Other analysts have developed models that take into account the prices of new products. For example, Glass (1999) shows that when consumers' valuation of quality improvement varies, depending upon their income levels, income inequality can affect the willingness to pay for quality. Income distribution affects the equilibrium price structure among goods of different qualities, which, in turn, affects the profit incentives to innovate. His model suggests that in an unequal society, there are few rich consumers who value new products of high quality, and the profit incentives for quality improvement, i.e., innovation, are low. As a result, the rate of innovation is lower than when income distribution is more equal.

How is this related to the investment and production of innovation? In a society in which income inequality is low, there is a large middle-class population who are the natural consumers of manufacturers. This implies a strong market for each of the products demanded. On the other hand, in a society where income distribution is very unequal, the demand for manufactures is low. The poor demand and can afford only basic products, while the rich demand luxury items. In this case, although the range of goods demanded is wide, the quantity demanded for each individual good is limited.

Income distribution affects innovation in a similar way to how it affects industrialization. Murphy et al. (1989) show that the adoption of efficient production methods, i.e., process

(24)

innovation, requires large markets. In addition to a large population, homogeneous tastes, and concentrated population, income distribution also affects industrialization, as it affects the composition of demand and market sizes for manufactures.

In short, when income is highly concentrated among the rich, the initial market for a new product is small. When a high proportion of consumers are poor, it takes a long time for the market size for the new product to enlarge. This reduces the expected profitability of the product, thereby reducing the entrepreneurs' incentives to invest in innovative activity.

The issue of an open economy

The assumption of a closed economy underlies the discussion of the demand effects of income distribution. Most countries, however, are open to some international trade. A question then arises as to whether the demand composition effects of the domestic income distribution are still relevant. I contend that the hypothesis is still valid, as domestic demand composition has an impact on the pattern of trade, thus the domestic production of goods.

According to the Linder hypothesis, named after Burenstam Linder (1961), foreign trade is the extension of domestic production and consumption. The set of exports of an economy must be a subset of goods domestically demanded. In other words, the necessary condition for any manufactured good to be an export is that it be demanded for domestic consumption. According to Chenery et al. (1987), the domestic markets for developing countries account for 80-90 percent of their manufacturing outputs.

The reason lies in the need on the producer's part for knowledge about demand and consumer preferences. According to Linder, domestic entrepreneurs base their production decisions on proximate profit opportunities. They need the knowledge about the needs and

(25)

preferences of consumers, which are harder to acquire in the case of exports to foreign consumers. This hypothesis applies to the discussion of income distribution and entrepreneurs' incentives to innovate. The assumption that domestic manufacturers first consider the domestic markets in their investment decisions is applicable to the case of innovation.

2. Imperfections of Capital and Credit Markets

There are several ways in which income distribution may affect innovation through imperfect capital and credit markets: namely (1) lack of collateral for investment; (2) development of financial markets; (3) occupational choices; (4) relative profit margins; and (5) human capital accumulation.

2.1 Lack of collateral for investment

As reviewed earlier, a common mechanism through which income distribution affects macroeconomic variables is imperfect credit markets. Under extreme inequality, many people are prevented from borrowing against their future income, because a minimum level of income or collateral is required of all borrowers. In such a case, the initial income distribution affects the pattern of investment in human capital, subsequent aggregate output, and hence economic growth. As an extension of this argument, I contend that credit-markets imperfection is also a mechanism through which income inequality affects innovation.

In an unequal society, many potential entrepreneurs do not have access to credits that they could use to invest in innovative activity. Only the rich have access to them. When capital markets are imperfect and there are fixed up-front costs required for the production of innovation, investors in innovative activities are limited to those people who have enough existing wealth. The rich entrepreneurs could either use their existing wealth or borrow from

(26)

banks to fund innovative projects. In contrast, potential entrepreneurs with limited asset stocks can neither fund the innovative projects by themselves nor borrow from the credit markets because they lack collateral. As a result, the overall investment in innovative activity and the rate of innovation are low.

2.2 Development offinancial sector

Income inequality may also affect the development of domestic financial markets, which, in turn, affects technological innovation. As shown empirically by Li et al. (1998), a developed financial market eases the access of the poor to credit, thereby reducing income inequality. However, little is known whether income distribution indeed affects the development of financial markets. Given the importance of income distribution and financial markets in the economic development discourse, it is surprising that there is very little literature on how income distribution affects financial market development.

Many economists have shown that a well-functioning financial market is crucial to innovation and economic growth. Schumpeter (1911) argues that "The banker authorizes people,

in the name of the society as it were, to ... [innovate]" (p. 74). In other words, the appropriate allocation of capital made possible by efficient and flexible financial markets is important for innovative activity. The services, such as mobilizing savings, evaluating projects, managing risks, and facilitating transactions, provided by financial intermediaries are essential for technological innovation. King and Levine (1993a) empirically test the argument and find that there is a strong relationship between a country's level of financial-sector development and indicators for economic performance, such as real per capita GDP growth, physical capital accumulation, and economic efficiency.

(27)

An explanation for why developed financial markets foster innovation is related to the issue of risk allocation. According to Arrow (1964), investors are willing to take more risks in a well-functioning financial market, as risks are spread across many investors. I extend this argument further to argue that an innovation investment is usually associated with risks, and that investors consider the level of risks when deciding whether to finance it. A well-developed financial market can spread both the actual risks and the risks perceived by investors, thus promoting innovative activities.

This view is well captured within the framework of endogenous technological change. King and Levine (1993b) construct an endogenous growth model in which financial systems evaluate prospective entrepreneurs, mobilize savings to finance the most promising productivity-improving activities, diversify the risks associated with these innovative activities, and reveal the expected profits from engaging in innovation rather than the production of existing goods using existing methods. They find that better financial systems improve the probability of successful innovation and thereby accelerate economic growth. On the other hand, financial-sector distortions reduce the rate of economic growth by reducing the rate of innovation.

2.3 Occupational choices

Income distribution may also affect the occupational structure of the economy and the organizational form of production. Banerjee and Newman (1993) develop a model in which the distribution of wealth affects the occupational choice and economic development. They argue that because of capital-market imperfections, poor people have no choice but to work for a wage rather than to be self-employed, while rich people can become entrepreneurs. These occupational decisions then determine the wage rate of the economy, which leads to a new distribution of wealth. The entire process then repeats itself. Simply put, the initial distribution of wealth

(28)

determines the number of people who become entrepreneurs, as well as the number of people who become hired workers or join the subsistence sector.

According to the model, in a society with highly unequal income distribution, there is a large supply of labor at any wage exceeding subsistence levels. These people are too poor to have access to credits and hence cannot become entrepreneurs. On the other hand, the demand for labor is low at any wage rate. The wage rate at equilibrium is thus at the minimum subsistence wage. In contrast, the profits are high for those who can become entrepreneurs.

On the other hand, if a society has an equal income distribution, relatively few people are barred from access to credit markets, and more people can become entrepreneurs. These people enter the labor market only when wages are high enough to lure them from becoming entrepreneurs.

The model shows that income distribution determines the number of entrepreneurs in a society. I extend the model to explain the effects of income distribution on innovation. Because these entrepreneurs are practically investors in innovative activity, I assume that innovation is the function of the number of entrepreneurs. In other words, the total number of entrepreneurs affects the level of innovation in a society. In a country with great income inequality, there are

fewer entrepreneurs than there would be with lower inequality. Fewer entrepreneurs therefore mean fewer innovations. Thus, income distribution affects the number of entrepreneurs, and hence innovation investment and the number of innovations.

2.4 Human capital accumulation

As innovation is essentially knowledge and information, the quality and quantity of human capital available in a country is undoubtedly another important determinant of innovation.

(29)

The general hypothesis is that the more and better human capital a country has, the more it can innovate. Among several economists who investigate the issue, Roy (1997) shows theoretically how the quality of human capital affects innovation and long-run economic growth. Nickell and Nicolitsas (1997) also show that human capital stock, as measured by number of personnel in

R&D and level of educational achievement, influences investments in fixed capital and R&D. Unequal income distribution also implies unequal access to knowledge. Because innovation is essentially knowledge and information, I hypothesize that income inequality affects the accumulation process of knowledge and human capital, the number of personnel in research and development, and thus the rate of innovation. I base this hypothesis on the assumptions of hierarchical demand composition and imperfect credit markets for education.

As discussed earlier, income distribution affects the composition of aggregate demand for good and services, as well as the demand for and the returns to labor of different skill levels. For example, under high inequality, there is a low demand for goods and services produced by medium-skilled labor. This presses down the returns to medium-skilled labor, while returns are skewed in favor of high-skilled labor. In most developing countries, where there are no credit markets for education. Poor people therefore do not have access to the education to equip them with higher-level skills. Furthermore, in the long run, the poor will not be able to fund the education for their children, as they will not be able to bequeath enough wealth for them.

This is another channel through which income distribution affects innovation, assuming that innovations require minimum levels of skills and knowledge and that the total number of personnel in R&D affects the rate of innovation. Under these assumptions, the higher the inequality in a society, the fewer people with skills and knowledge, thus the lower the rate of innovation.

(30)

A related issue is the concentration of employment in certain sectors that may produce

more innovations than others. Leamer et al. (1999) find that countries that have low Gini-coefficients tend to have more employment in manufacturing than those countries with high Gini-coefficients. This is particularly true for human-capital-intensive sectors such as chemicals, and printing and paper. I can extend their conclusion to fit into my hypothesis that income distribution affects innovation. Assuming that innovations are produced in the manufacturing

sector, large manufacturing sectors could lead to more innovations.

2.5 Relative profits margin across sectors

Income inequality, together with the differences in the rates of returns across sectors due to capital-market imperfections, lead to the concentration of investment in the sectors that are not

innovative.

In a standard neoclassical investment model with the premise of profit maximization, the investment decision is based on the comparison between the present values of all costs and revenues. Corporate executives invest only when the net present value of the project in question exceeds zero. When there is more than one project to compare, investors choose the project with the highest rate of return.

This simple principle also applies to the investment decision on innovative activity. Taking into account the opportunities and risks associated with the new investment, investors are faced with two investment options: either investing in the existing products and/or processes, or investing in innovative activity. If the rates of returns of the existing products are higher than those of the new products, i.e., innovations, entrepreneurs will not invest in innovative activity. They are already satisfied with the profits that they can earn from existing production. On the

(31)

other hand, if these entrepreneurs see potentially high profits from innovations, they will invest in research and development for product and process improvement.

Income distribution can affect innovation, precisely because it affects the perceived rates of returns for innovation relative to the existing products and/or processes. Under imperfect capital markets, the rates of returns to investment vary across sectors. With highly skewed income distribution, the variance is even greater. Wealth is concentrated in the hands of the few rich, who invest in the sectors that would give them the highest returns. In countries with high income inequality, businesses are not very diversified and capital is concentrated in only a few sectors. This phenomenon is particularly true when the rates of returns for investment in existing businesses are higher than the expected rates of returns from new businesses.

Learner et al. (1999) conduct a cross-sectional empirical analysis to demonstrate that natural-resource-intensive sectors, particularly agriculture, absorb capital that might otherwise flow to manufacturing. This depresses workers' incentive to accumulate skills and delays industrialization. In most Latin American countries, capital is concentrated in natural-resource sectors. With the extreme concentration of wealth and imperfect capital markets, capital owners-cum-entrepreneurs are likely to choose natural-resource sectors over manufacturing, because the expected rates of returns are higher in natural-resource sectors.

Differences in rates of returns across sectors, combined with skewed income distribution, therefore affect innovation. This argument seems plausible particularly when the existing industries are natural-resource intensive and the new industries are manufacturing. Given that innovations occur more in the manufacturing industries than in the natural-resource-based industries, less investment in manufacturing industries is likely to result in fewer innovations.

(32)

I can further develop this argument in terms of a Schumpeterian growth model, in which innovation plays a central role. Again, profits are considered as the attraction to motivate

innovative activity, as well as the vehicle by which successful innovators grow relative to other firms. Competition is a dynamic process in which fmns deliberately attempt to be leaders in technological innovations, so as to earn supra-normal profits from successful innovations. With the protection of intellectual property rights, innovators can gain high entrepreneurial rents.

However, in an unequal society, entrepreneurs already earn high profits, regardless of the innovative capability of the firms. In other words, firms can sell their products in the domestic markets by utilizing their existing market power, without innovating, and still earn high profits. Limited dynamic competition among fmns thus results in low rates of innovation in the overall economy.

3. Redistributive Policy and Firm Size

Income distribution may also have an effect on the sizes of domestic firms, which, in turn, affect the rate of innovation. In order to prove this argument as one mechanism for income distribution to affect innovation, I need to establish the relationships between innovation and firm size, and between income distribution and frmn size.

Many economists have studied firm size and market structure as the determinants of innovation. The debate dates back to 1942 when Schumpeter argued that large firms with a considerable degree of market power would be the best innovators, because they could use their profits to fund further innovative activity. Small competitive frmns, on the other hand, would not be able to generate as much profit as monopolistic firms; thus they are unable to invest in innovative activity.

(33)

Many contemporary economists have explored the validity and implications of the "Schumpeter hypothesis." Several analysts in later years support the view that large firms are better innovators, although with somewhat different explanations. Caves (1982), for instance, argues that innovators have to choose to operate on a large scale to maximize the potential profits that are generated from innovations. Because innovations are essentially knowledge and information, which have the unique properties of increasing returns to scale and quasi-public goods, innovators have to retain the ownership of the knowledge-based assets as long as possible. Such ownership, however, cannot be fully protected by the intellectual property rights legislation. Innovators, therefore, have to produce their products on a very large scale. A model of R&D cost spreading, developed by Cohen and Klepper (1996), shows that there is an advantage to large size in R&D.

Many analysts have empirically supported this hypothesis. For example, Scherer (1980) notes that scale economies in production may provide scope economies for R&D. Particularly in capital-intensive and advertising intensive industries, larger firms are more advantageous than smaller firms to exploit the profits gained from innovation. In a more recent study, Damanpour

(1992) finds that firm size is positively related to innovation, particularly in manufacturing firms.

There are other analysts who think and prove otherwise. Geroski (1994) shows in his study of British firms from 1945 to 1983 that monopolistic industries are less innovative than competitive ones. Also, in a recent study of Swiss manufacturing fins, Arvanitis (1997) finds no significant evidence for the existence of economies of scale in the innovation activity.

A unified and refined view seems more convincing that the effects of firm size depend on

the particular industry. Scherer (1992) later modified his previous argument, and admits that it is not clear whether there is an absolute advantage of large, monopolistic corporations in

(34)

innovation. Large monopolistic fmns may be more advantageous than small firms to carry out certain types of innovative activities, and vice versa.

On the other hand, the literature is still scarce on the relationship between income distribution and firm size. One possible mechanism is the redistributive policy. As argued by Amsden (2001), governments in countries with highly unequal income distribution are reluctant to promote the formation of large fmns due to political reasons. If large frmns are indeed more innovative than small firms, as argued by many analysts, then a redistributive policy that aims to correct income inequality by discouraging the formation of large firms, in effect, could lead to few innovations.

I have so far proposed the possible mechanisms through which income distribution may affect innovation. In the following chapter, I test empirically the causal relationship between income distribution and innovation. Due to data availability, I choose to test only two mechanisms through which income distribution may affect innovation: namely, fmancial-sector development, and credit-markets imperfection.

(35)

CHAPTER 3 EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

In this chapter, I explore empirically the relationship between income distribution and innovation. I first present some descriptive evidence on the relevant variables, including research and development (R&D) expenditures, then I conduct a formal, empirical analysis using econometric methods. I discuss the basic methodological framework, the testable hypotheses, the data and measurement of variables, and the econometric issues in the regression analysis. In the econometric analysis, I test the hypothesis that income distribution affects the level of expenditure on innovative activity, the level of innovative outputs, and the productivity of innovative outputs.

I. DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

The patterns of income distribution vary greatly in different countries. Table 3.1 shows the summary of descriptive statistics of the full-sample data. It is clear that there is a huge gap between the country with the highest GINI-coefficient, South Africa, and the one with lowest GINI, Czech Republic. The same is true for the other measure of income distribution, i.e., the aggregate income share of the 2"d, 3rd, and 4 th quintile of the population (MID60), as well as

other variables shown in the same table. There are wide gaps in terms of gross R&D expenditures (GERD) and private R&D expenditures (PERD), level of innovation (PTENT), and productivity of innovation (PTENTCAP). Particularly striking is the difference in the level and productivity of innovation. Using patent applications to measure the level of innovation, I find that the most innovative country, Japan, has more than 360,000 patent applications per year, while Zambia and many other countries excluded from the sample have none. In terms of

(36)

innovative productivity, measured by patent applications per million inhabitants, there are also huge differences among countries. Japan is the most productive in producing innovations, with more than 2,800 patent applications per million inhabitants, whereas the average productivity for the sample of 72 countries is only 250.

Table 3.1: Summary Statistics for Income Distribution and Innovation Measures

Standard Number of

Variable Mean Deviation Minimum Maximum Observations Income Distribution GINI 37.85 10.25 22.88 60.90 72 MID60 51.62 14.86 32.30 56.30 72 Innovation Spending GERD 1.07 0.89 0.07 3.76 64 PERD 0.57 0.64 0.00 2.37 57

Innovative Output/ Productivity

PTENT 12,031 46,830 1 360,364 72

PTENTCAP 250 493 0 2,853 72

Notes: i) See Table 3.4 for definition of variables.

ii) Numbers of observations vary according to data availability.

To show the differences, I present the statistics by region in Table 3.2. Industrialized countries, on average, have more equal income distribution and larger middle-class population than developing countries. Among developing countries in the sample, the average income distribution in Eastern Europe is the most equal, followed by Asia. In fact, Eastern European countries are, on average, more equal than industrialized countries, possibly because of the legacy from the era of socialism. As is well known, income distribution in Latin America is very skewed and is the most unequal of all regions. In terms of R&D expenditures, industrialized countries clearly spend much more than developing countries. Among developing countries, both the gross and private R&D expenditures in Asia are higher than in other regions. This is also true in terms of innovative output and productivity. The total number of patent applications, and the

(37)

number of patent applications per one million inhabitants are the greatest in industrialized countries, followed by the groups of countries in Asia and Eastern Europe.

Table 3.2: Summary Statistics by Region

Region Industrialized Asia Mean St. Dev. Mean St. Dev. Income Distribution GINI 32.30 4.80 38.93 6.67 MID60 55.18 10.24 58.76 23.71 Innovation Spending GERD 1.88 0.85 0.81 0.86 PERD 1.02 0.63 0.53 0.80 Innovative Output PTENT 32,198 81,162 86,15 17,019 PTENTCAP 539 586 373 718 Number of Countries in Sample 22 13

Note: See Table 3.4 for definition of variables.

Source: Statistical Yearbook 1999, United Nations Educational,

Developing Countries Latin America Eastern Europe

Mean St. Dev. Mean St. Dev.

50.73 6.16 29.27 3.65 43.33 16.83 51.49 3.19 0.42 0.29 0.75 0.36 0.09 0.09 0.29 0.24 313 527 2,527 5,413 13 23 65 42 15 16 Africa Mean St. Dev. 46.55 13.35 42.85 7.92 0.46 0.34 0.38 -130 200 3 3 6

Scientific, and Cultural Organization (UNESCO)

Regarding the sources of funding for research and development, developed countries clearly rely more on funding from the private sector (Table 3.3). On average, more than half of the gross R&D expenditures in developed countries comes from private enterprises. In contrast, developing countries rely on the public sector, with more than 50% of R&D expenditure from their respective governments. Among developing countries, there are clear differences among regions. Latin America relies heavily on public sources, while its R&D funding from the private sector is extremely low. Africa's reliance on overseas funding is also striking, with 35% coming from overseas. The only group of developing countries with spending patterns similar to developed countries is the newly industrializing countries (NICs) of Asia. On average, 40% of their R&D funding comes from business enterprises, a level not far below that of developed

Figure

TABLE  OF CONTENTS ABSTRACT-------------------------------------------------------  2 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS  4 TABLE  OF  CONTENTS  5 LIST  OF TABLES  6 CHAPTER  1:  INTRODUCTION  7
TABLE  PAGE
Table 3.1:  Summary Statistics for Income  Distribution and Innovation Measures
Table 3.2:  Summary Statistics by Region
+7

Références

Documents relatifs

Nev- ertheless, the main themes from the annual panels hold up: (i) there is no sta- tistically significant unconditional effect of democratic switches; (ii) the effect of

Les accidents du travail rapportés par ces salariés sont également plus fréquents, notam- ment pour ceux des sous-traitants de dernier rang : 11 % déclarent au moins un accident

Tables 1 and 2 show some descriptive statistics of important characteristics by income group: i) the percentage of workers with temporary contracts are higher among low income

L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, émanant des

weighted household post- government income, individual net income, corrected monthly household income, and household net income from wages) on subjective health were compared in

According to Proposition 3 the steady-state growth rate responds in an intuitive way to the considered parameter changes: an economy with more workers grows faster (the scale effect),

norm) and Model 2 (own funds norm), as compared to the evolution of the corresponding baseline solution, on the following variables: output (Y ), personal consumption (CP ), the

From insufficient growth to discontent: Similarity and variation across countries With the magnitude of growth rates experienced since the beginning of the 19th century in