• Aucun résultat trouvé

American put option in a model with discrete dividends

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "American put option in a model with discrete dividends"

Copied!
31
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

American put option in a model with discrete dividends

M. Jeunesse and B. Jourdain

Universit´e Paris-Est, CERMICS, Project team INRIA MathFi, 6 et 8 avenue Blaise Pascal, 77455 Marne La Vall´ee, Cedex 2, France, e-mails:jeunessm@cermics.enpc.frandjourdain@cermics.enpc.fr

April 18, 2012

(2)

Introduction

Reduction to simple problems without dividends Existence and continuity of the exercise boundary

Existence Continuity

Smooth-fit

Equivalent near the dividend date Conclusion

(3)
(4)

Put option contract with maturity (or life-time)T and strikeK on an underlyingS :

I European type : at the end of the life-time of the option, the buyer gets (K −ST)+.

I American type : during all the life-time of the option, the buyer can ask to stop and gets (K −St)+

(5)

Fair value of the put option contract with maturity (or life-time)T and strikeK on an underlying S :

I European type : the fair value is E h

e−rT(K −ST)+ i

.

I American type : the fair value is supτ∈[0,T]E

e−rτ(K −Sτ)+ .

(6)

Figure: A trajectory of the stock price process

(7)

I Between dividend dates, dynamics of the stock price processS is the standard Black Scholes dynamics (parameters r andσ) i.e : dSt =rStdt+σStdBt

I At a dividend date, tdi,Sti

d =Sti

d−Di

Sti

d

whereDi is a deterministic function satisfying the following assumptions

∀i ∈ {1, . . . ,I}:

((a)Di is ↑and non-negative,

(b) ρi :x7→x−Di(x) is ↑and non-negative.

(8)

Aim : Obtain the value of the American Put option with strikeK and maturityT on an underlying paying discrete dividends. Since we are in a Markovian framework, the price can be characterized in terms of a value function depending of the timet and the stock price at timet.

(9)

Ast 7→(K −St)+ is upper semi-continuous, general optimal stopping time theory is valid (cf [EK81]) :

I u(t,x) = supτ∈[t,T]E

e−r(τ−t)(K −Sτ)+

St=x ,

I τ? = inf{v≥t|u(v,Sv)≤(K −Sv)+} ∧T is optimal.

(10)

Introduction

Reduction to simple problems without dividends Existence and continuity of the exercise boundary

Existence Continuity

Smooth-fit

Equivalent near the dividend date Conclusion

(11)

Let (θdi =tdi −tdi+1)0≤i≤I−1 with the conventiontd0 =T denote the durations between the dividend dates. For non-negative values ofθ andx, we define by induction

I value function : u0(θ,x) = supτ∈[0,θ]E h

e−rτ K −S¯τx+i

I exercise boundary : c0(θ),

{x :u(0,x)>(K x)+}= (c0(θ),+∞),

I ¯c(θ) exercise boundary associated toK = 1.

I c0(θ) = sup{x|u0(θ,x) = (K x)+}=K¯c(θ).

I ∀i ∈ {1, . . . ,I},

ui(θ,x) = sup

τ∈[0,θ]E

"

e−rτ K −S¯τx+

1{τ <θ}

+e−rθui−1id−1,S¯θx −Di(¯Sθx))1{τ=θ}

# .

Note thatui(0,x) =ui−1di−1,x−Di(x)).

(12)

Proposition Suppose that

t<tdi <tdi−1 <· · ·<td1 <T and setθ=tdi −t,

θd0 =T −td1, and for

j = 1. . .i−1,θdj =tdj −tdj+1, then the value at time t when the spot price of the stock is equal to x of the American put option with strike K and maturity T is given by ui(θ,x).

(13)

Introduction

Reduction to simple problems without dividends Existence and continuity of the exercise boundary

Existence Continuity

Smooth-fit

Equivalent near the dividend date Conclusion

(14)

Here are Lemmas from [JV11].

Lemma

For eachθ≥0, the mapping x 7→ui(θ,x) is non-increasing and x7→x+ui(θ,x) is non-decreasing.

Corollary (Exercise boundary)

For anyθ≥0, it exists ci(θ)∈[0,K) such that : ui(θ,x)>(K −x)+⇔x >ci(θ)

ci(θ) = sup{x≥0|ui(θ,x) = (K −x)+} Lemma

The mapping(θ,x)7→ui(θ,x) is continuous on R+×R+

(15)

I Upper semi-continuity of the exercise boundary is a direct consequence of the global continuity of the value function.

I Right continuity(limθ0↓θci0) =ci(θ)) comes from a comparaison with respect to the case without dividends.

ui(θ+t,x) =E h

e−rτ

1{τ <t} K −S¯τx+

+1{τ=t}ui(θ,S¯tx) i

≤E h

e−rτ

1{τ <t} K −S¯τx+

+1{τ=t} K −

ci(θ)∧S¯tx+i

≤E

e−rτ K −h

ci(θ) + (K −ci(θ))(1−e−r(t−τ))∧S¯τxi+

=(K−ci(θ))e−rt+E h

e−rτ(ci(θ)+(K−ci(θ))(1−e−r(t−τ))−¯Sτx)+i

≤(K−ci(θ))e−rt+E h

e−rτ(ci(θ)+(K−ci(θ))(1−e−rt)−S¯τx)+i

≤(K−ci(θ))e−rt+(ci(θ)+(K−ci(θ))(1−e−rt))v

t, x

ci(θ)+(K−ci(θ))(1−e−rt)

«

(16)

ui(θ+t,x)≤(K−ci(θ))e−rt+(ci(θ)+(K−ci(θ))(1−e−rt))v

t, x

ci(θ)+(K−ci(θ))(1−e−rt)

«

I The previous equation gives us exactly

ci(θ+t)≥(ci(θ) + (K −ci(θ))(1−e−rt)) ¯c(t).

By [KS91], it gives us right-continuity.

I Tools to get right-continuity :

I continuity of the value function (u.s.c)

I exponential model.

(17)

I Left-continuity is a consequence of : Proposition

Under(A), the property

(Pi): For any θ >0 and x ≥0one has x >ci(θ)⇐⇒1 +∂xui(θ,x)>0 holds for any i∈ {0,· · · ,I}.

(18)

Figure: Proof of left continuity

(19)

Introduction

Reduction to simple problems without dividends Existence and continuity of the exercise boundary

Existence Continuity

Smooth-fit

Equivalent near the dividend date Conclusion

(20)

Proposition (Smooth-fit) For allθ >0, ui(θ,•) isC1.

(21)

It relies on the two following Lemmas : Lemma

(θ,x)7→u(θ,x) is a viscosity supersolution of

min(∂θui(θ,x)− Aui(θ,•)(x),ui(θ,x)−(K −x)+) = 0 with ui(0,x) =ui−1i−1d , ρi(x))

Lemma

For any i ≥0,θ >0 and x≥0one has for some constant C lim sup

θ0→θ

ui0,x)−ui(θ,x) θ0−θ

≤(1 +x)

C + σ

√ 2πθ

Moreover∂xui(θ,x) admits a right-hand limit at ci(θ) denoted by

xui(θ,ci(θ)+) and∂xui(θ,ci(θ)+)∈[−1,0].

(22)

Standard viscosity argument

Φ(θ+t,x) = e−βt

K −ci(θ) +p(x−ci(θ)) +1 (x−ci(θ))2

minV ui −Φ = ui −Φ|(θ,c

i(θ))= 0

viscosity super-solution property implies :

−∂tΦ +AΦ|(θ,c

i(θ)) ≤0

−(β+r) (K −ci(θ)) +rpci(θ) +σ2 2

ci(θ)2

ε ≤0

(23)

Introduction

Reduction to simple problems without dividends Existence and continuity of the exercise boundary

Existence Continuity

Smooth-fit

Equivalent near the dividend date Conclusion

(24)

Lemma

Assume that ci(0)>0,lim infx↓ci(0)x−cDi(x)

i(0) >0then

ci(θ)−ci(0)∼θ↓0−σci(0)p θ|lnθ|.

This result generalizes the following result from [JV11]

Lemma

Assume that Di is concave and ci(0) = 0, then if Dx

i(x) admits a finite right-hand limit at x= 0, ci(θ)∼θ→0+ rKθlimx→0+ x

Di(x).

Conclusion

(25)

Proposition

Assume that ci(0)<ci−1di−1), that Di is the difference of two convex functions, and that the positive part of the Jordan-Hahn decomposition of the measure Di00 is absolutely continuous with respect to the Lebesgue measure.

Assume moreover that, if gi denotes the density of the absolutely continuous part of the measure Di00, it exists

ε∈(0,ci−1di−1)−ci(0))and C1 ∈[0,+∞) such that on(ci(0),ci(0) +ε],

and such that−rDi(x) +rxDi0(x) + σ2x2

2 gi(x)≤rK −ε,

∀x >ci(0) +ε, gi(x)≤C1xC1.

Then it exists a neighborhood of(0,ci(0)) in R+×R+ such that ui is non-increasing w.r.tθ in this neighborhood. Moreover the exercise boundary ci is non-decreasing in a neighborhood of0.

(26)

Proposition

Assume that ci(0)<ci−1di−1), that Di is the difference of two convex functions, and that thenegative part of the Jordan-Hahn decomposition of the measure Di00 is absolutely continuous with respect to the Lebesgue measure.

Assume moreover that, if gi denotes the density of the absolutely continuous part of the measure Di00, it exists

ε∈(0,ci−1di−1)−ci(0))and C1 ∈[0,+∞) such that on(ci(0),ci(0) +ε], Di is C2

and such that−rDi(x) +rxDi0(x) +σ2x2

2 gi(x)≥rK +ε,

∀x >ci(0) +ε, gi(x)≤ −C1xC1.

Then it exists a neighborhood of(0,ci(0)) in R+×R+ such that ui is non-decreasing w.r.tθin this neighborhood. Moreover the exercise boundary ci isnon-increasingin a neighborhood of 0.

(27)

Introduction

Reduction to simple problems without dividends Existence and continuity of the exercise boundary

Existence Continuity

Smooth-fit

Equivalent near the dividend date Conclusion

(28)

(a) D1(x) = min

1125 32 , 8

1125

`(x50)+´2«

(b)D1(x) = 0.05(x50)+

Figure: Exercise boundaries of an American put option of maturity 4 with one dividend time at 3.5 for different dividend functions. Strike is 100, diffusion parameters arer = 0.04 andσ= 0.3.

(29)

(a) Maturity is 2 with one div- idend time at 1.7; D1(x) = 1

5

`(x20)+(x30)+´

(b) Maturity is 0.1 with one div- idend time at 0.05; D1(x) = min

9 8,2

9

`(x20)+´2«

Figure: Exercise boundaries of an American put option with different maturities for different dividend functions. Strike is 100, diffusion parameters arer = 0.04 andσ= 0.3.

(30)

N. El Karoui.

Les aspects probabilistes du contrˆole stochastique.

InNinth Saint Flour Probability Summer School—1979 (Saint Flour, 1979), volume 876 of Lecture Notes in Math., pages 73–238. Springer, Berlin, 1981.

M. Jeunesse and B. Jourdain.

Regularity of the American put option in the Black Scholes model with general discrete dividends.

Stochastic Processes and their Applications, To appear.

B. Jourdain and M. Vellekoop.

Regularity of the Exercise Boundary for American Put Options on Assets with Discrete Dividends.

SIAM Journal on Mathematical Finance, 2:538–561, 2011.

I. Karatzas and S. E. Shreve.

Methods of mathematical finance.

Springer, 1991.

(31)

Thank you for your attention.

Questions ?

Slides based on [JJ]

Références

Documents relatifs

Unit´e de recherche INRIA Rennes, Irisa, Campus universitaire de Beaulieu, 35042 RENNES Cedex Unit´e de recherche INRIA Rh ˆone-Alpes, 655, avenue de l’Europe, 38330 MONTBONNOT

In particular, we prove that, in situations where the limit of the critical price is equal to the strike price, the rate of convergence to the limit is linear if and only if

We study the behavior of the critical price of an American put option near maturity in the jump diffusion model when the underlying stock pays dividends at a continuous rate and

[7] Lamberton D and Villeneuve S (2003), Critical price near maturity for an American option on a dividend paying stock (avec S. Villeneuve), Annals of Applied Probability 13,

The incorporation of a dividend yield in the classical option pricing model of Black- Scholes results in a minor modification of the Black-Scholes formula, since the lognormal

To test the efficiency of BIR and BBSR in pricing American options, a standard test is usually applied, based on the computation of the (absolute value of) the

gain from pocketing from the buyer the option price, that shall be noted C(xo&gt; x~, T) for a call option on a share of initial price xo starting at t = 0, of striking price xc

This exercise boundary was computed by a binomial tree method (see [22])... It is based on the stronger results that we will prove for the single dividend case in this section and