• Aucun résultat trouvé

The East African monetary union: ready or not?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "The East African monetary union: ready or not?"

Copied!
69
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

21

st

Intergovernmental Committee of Experts Transformative Growth in Eastern Africa:

Catalysts and Constraints

Venue: Moroni, Union of Comoros Dates: 7-9

th

November 2017.

The East African Monetary Union:

Ready or Not?

Draft Report

October 2017

(2)

Executive summary

EAC Partner States are in the implementation process of the protocol on the Establishment of the East African Community Monetary Union (EAMU) signed in November 2013, which will lead to the use of a common currency by 2024. However, the use of a common currency has benefits and costs. The main benefits of monetary union derive from the elimination of the transaction costs of exchanging currencies and the elimination of exchange-rate volatility while the main costs of monetary union are those attributable to the inability of monetary authorities of the individual countries to use country-specific monetary policies and the exchange rate as an instrument of macroeconomic adjustment in response to shocks. The benefits and costs arising from the establishment of monetary union depend on the structural characterizes of the economies concerned. While endogenous theory suggests that a common currency can promote trade and growth and that countries could become more similar in a currency union than before joining currency union, many recent studies show a much smaller trade impact of monetary union, particularly in developing countries. This reinforces the importance of meeting optimum currency criteria (OCA) as prerequisite for forming a currency union. The basic point of the OCA theory is that countries or regions exposed to symmetric shocks, or possessing mechanisms for the absorption of asymmetric shocks, may find it optimal to adopt a common currency.

The main objective of this paper was to investigate the readiness of East African Community countries for a monetary union by extending the period of study used by other researchers, to cover recent periods when progress was made in policy coordination and implementation of common market protocols.

The general conclusion is that despite some similarities in the structures of EAC economies, country-specific shocks have been prevalent, with economies in the EAC remaining susceptible to asymmetric shocks. Empirical analysis points to a partial convergence among different macro-economic variables used to assess the readiness of EAC countries for a monetary union. It may be advisable for the region, to fast track the full implementation of common market and customers union protocol, harmonize policies and increase inter regional trade before adopting a common currency. Adopting a common currency before reaching a good level of convergence may be more damaging to EAC countries. Partial convergence in inflation and exchange rates implies that the EAC countries need to align their monetary policies and allow a period of monetary policy coordination.

While drawing from experiences of other currency unions, it will be important that going forward, the EAC continues to direct efforts to designing and putting in place adequate mechanisms that can help member countries to adjust to future shocks once the common currency is adopted. This includes the usual measures to mitigate costs of common monetary policies such as labor and capital mobility, price, and wage flexibility, as well as various risk-sharing mechanisms, including fiscal policy.

This will require that EAC countries agree to explicit and binding convergence commitments as prerequisites and ongoing commitments for the viability of EAMU. To achieve this, there is need for the establishment of an institution or a strong mechanism for enforcement and ensuring compliance by all countries. Firm commitment, discipline

(3)

among members and reduction of the risk of bad policies are results of a more rule- based framework. These measures should be agreed among member countries before the introduction of the single currency, to reduce risks and signal early commitment to macroeconomic stability.

Despite the relatively large volume of trade among the EAC countries, significant challenges to monetary integration remain, including the following: (i) low per capita income levels, resulting in internal markets of limited sizes; (ii) the concentration on primary-commodity exports for most countries; (iii) limited transportation facilities and large distances between population centers; and, (iv) relatively-high shares of informal trade because of permeable borders.

In the process of enhancing regional integration through the increase of inter-regional trade, it is important to fully implement the common market and customers union protocols.

As policy recommendation, to achieve greater intra-regional trade and structural similarity thus shock synchronization, barriers to trade within EAC need to be eliminated while common policies toward the outside of the EAC should be adopted. The region’s trade agenda therefore has a wider scope than reducing intraregional tariff barriers. Its current primary focus is on removing structural – mostly non-trade – barriers to competitiveness and trade. Besides the traditional objectives of removing quotas and tariffs, EAC’s trade policy now strives to strengthen the members’ “soft” and “hard” infrastructure so as to enable them to leverage their relative comparative advantages. The focus on relative comparative advantages would also help diversify the EAC product mix and could enhance the scope for intraregional trade along the value chains.

. The measurement of convergence criteria is another important issue to be considered. This is because the criteria have to have a legal force, and should be used as a basis for admission to the monetary union or sanctioning member countries that fail to meet the criteria. A strong emphasis has to be placed on the quality and cross-country comparability of the statistics used to compile the indicators. Therefore, statistical standards aligned with international statistical reporting requirements are necessary and statistics must be transparent and suitable for a wide range of analyses and public purposes.

Statistical programs must therefore be strong and the infrastructure must be in place, well before a proposed monetary union is formally established. There is a strong need for the early development of statistical systems in the monetary union-building process.

The experience of EMU show that members manage a high degree of periodicity and timeliness for their statistics which enables rapid policy responses, and a degree of certainty among policymakers since they have a good understanding of current economic conditions. During the period of financial turmoil, when economic conditions are changing rapidly and there is wide uncertainty about the management of the economy and of the financial sector in particular, the availability of accurate, timely, and reliable economic data becomes critical.

(4)

I.

Background

The formation of different monetary union blocs in Africa is explained by different factors including, the possibility of creating more solidarity among African countries (Cobham and Robson, 1994, p. 286; Masson and Pattillo, 2004, p. 10); the experience of the European monetary union that is perceived to have been successful in bringing benefits to its members (Masson and Pattillo, 2005, p. 34; Jefferis, 2007, p. 83); monetary union viewed as a way of achieving an efficient single market (Kenen and Meade, 2008, p. 4); and as a way to improve structures of the economies, to increase trade-integration and business-cycle correlation, and enhancing the credibility of macroeconomic policies (Frankel and Rose, 1998; Rose, 2000).

Studies on the readiness of countries to form monetary unions have been guided by the theory of optimum currency areas (OCA) which was developed by Mundell (1961), McKinnon (1963), and Kenen (1969) and became popular for analysis of the costs and benefits of monetary integration.

The benefits are directly related to the elimination of transaction costs due to exchanging currencies and exchange rate volatilities.Costs in countries’ bilateral trade while costs are related to the inability of the central bank in individual countries to use country specific monetary and exchange rate policy as an instrument of macro-economic adjustment. Thus, the benefits and costs arising from the establishment of monetary union depend on the structural characteristics of the economies concerned. The basic point of the OCA theory is that countries or regions exposed to symmetric shocks, or possessing mechanisms for the absorption of asymmetric shocks, may find it optimal to adopt a common currency.

Thus, OCA theory focuses more on asymmetric disturbances to output, trade linkages and the mobility of labor and considers that countries with intensive trade relations are likely to gain relatively more from the monetary integration. However, Frankel and Rose (1998) suggest that a common currency can promote trade and growth and that countries, could become more similar in a currency union than prior to the union. .This suggests that it may not be crucial for members to meet OCA criteria before forming a currency union. However, recent studies show a much smaller trade impact of monetary union, particularly in developing countries. This reinforces the importance of meeting optimum currency criteria as prerequisite for forming a currency union.

(5)

East African Community member states signed the Protocol on the Establishment of the East African Community Monetary Union (EAMU) in November 2013 as the third stage of integration in the region, aiming at launching a single currency by 2024. Indeed, the treaty for the establishment of the East African Community (EAC) signed by the Heads of State of Kenya, Tanzania, and Uganda in November 1999, and entered into force in July 2000, defines four different stages of integration. These include a Customs Union, a Common Market, a Monetary Union, and a Political Federation. Burundi and Rwanda acceded to the EAC Treaty in June 2007, while South Sudan gained accession in April 2016. The key objective of the EAC is to broaden and deepen cooperation among Partner States in a wide range of areas, including economic, social, political, security, and judicial affairs.

The first stage entailed a Customs Union and came into effect in 2005. This enables Partner States to operate as a free trade area by reducing or eliminating taxes on goods traded within the community, while having a common tariff on goods imported from other countries. The EAC Common Market which entered into force on July 2010, is the second stage of integration. It provides free movement of goods, services, labour, and capital. Founding members of EAC (Uganda, Kenya and Tanzania) set common external tariffs (CET) in 2005, which were adopted by Rwanda and Burundi after joining the community. The purpose of CET was to protect industries of significance to those countries by allowing firms to take advantage of economies of scale in production, selling to a wider market and encourage foreign direct investment (FDI) in the region by allowing international firms free access to a larger market than that of the individual member countries.

Different tariff rates were set: 0% for raw material; 10% for intermediate inputs or semi-finished goods and 25% for finished goods. However, this classification (0-10-25) poses some challenges in its implementation. A number of goods that are subject to the 25% tariff line are classified as raw materials or intermediate inputs according to the UN Board Economic Categories (BEC) classification (TMEA, 2015), which is likely to harm some countries like Rwanda and Burundi, by placing high 25% tariffs on the input for their manufacturing.

(6)

In addition, sensitive items (SI) under CET that have tariff rates in excess of 25% have been constraining. Individual countries have repeatedly applied for exemptions in line with SOAs, which are exemptions1 that individual EAC countries can request from the EAC council of ministers. If exemptions are agreed, the country will apply different rates for a period of one year.

East African Monetary Union (EAMU)

The stated objective of the EAMU is to “promote and maintain monetary and financial stability aimed at facilitating economic integration to attain sustainable growth and development of the community.” As pre-requisites for the EAMU, EAC countries ought to. (i)harmonize and coordinate fiscal, monetary and exchange rate policies; (ii) adopt common principles and rules for payments and settlements; (iii), harmonize policies and standards on statistical information; (iv) introduce bands and gradually fix their bilateral exchange rates; and (v) integrate their financial systems and adopt common principles and rules for the regulation and supervision of the financial system. Moreover, Partner States ought to phase out any outstanding national central bank lending to its government and public entities, while attaining and maintaining the pre-defined macroeconomic convergence criteria for at least three consecutive years before 2024.

Inherent to monetary union is the conduct of a single monetary and exchange rate policy in the interest of the single currency area as a whole. A system of central banks was adopted with a single regional central bank (The East African Central Banks, EACB) to replace the existing National Central Banks (NCBs), which could become its local arms. The primary objective of the monetary policy shall be to achieve and maintain price stability. Without prejudice to the primary objective, the monetary policy shall contribute to financial stability and economic growth and development.

In addition, to equip the EACB to conduct its exchange rate policy and to give the EACB control over the use of foreign currency a system of pooled reserves was adopted. In that framework which consists of centralizing the holding and management of foreign reserves, the NCBs would transfer foreign reserve assets in addition to subscribing to and paying up the capital of the EACB.

1 Many of these items are food staples. Increase in their prices as result of high tariffs affect poor households.

(7)

The monetary affairs committee (MAC) of EAC Central Bank Governors was created to harmonize monetary and exchange rate policy formulation and implementation as well as the regulatory frameworks of financial sectors in the region to ensure their stability and development.

In their effort of coordinating and harmonizing monetary and exchange rate policies during the transition to the monetary union, EAC central banks’ governors decided to adopt price based monetary policy framework by 2018 as money demand functions have become unstable and thus limiting the effectiveness of monetary policies in the region. To achieve that objective, clear measures were adopted to develop the interbank markets in all countries and harmonize monetary policy instruments. For example, an agreement to harmonize reserve requirement regimes in EAC countries by setting the reserve requirement ratio at 5% and the maintenance period to two weeks was reached.

Currently, the reserve requirement ratio is 5.25% in Kenya, 8% in Tanzania, 10% in Uganda, 5%

in Rwanda and 3% in Burundi. Central banks also agreed to design and implement a Common exchange rate mechanism, continually assess exchange rate misalignments in the region, develop capacity in modeling and forecasting and adopt Forecasting and Policy Analysis System (FPAS) as well as a common monetary policy communication strategy. Governors meet twice a year to assess the progress done and take additional measures to accelerate the implementation of their decisions.

Important achievements are also recorded in payment system development and harmonization.

They include, the integration of payment systems in the EAC region; harmonization of payment system standards for clearing and settlement systems; promotion of interconnectivity of payment cards switches; harmonization of payment systems legal, regulatory and institutional frameworks as well as cross border mobile money initiatives. On the financial system stability and development side, focus was put on integration of financial systems and adoption of common principles and rules for the regulation and supervision of the financial system; development and harmonization of criteria of the Basel Core Principles (BCPs); review, consolidation and harmonization of the existing financial stability assessment frameworks and establishment of working group on macro prudential analysis and stress testing (MAST).

(8)

However, the absence of any agreed rules and enforcement mechanism poses challenges to the implementation of decisions by the monetary affairs committee of EAC central banks’ governors as well as decisions by other EAC committees.. Indeed, policy coordination and harmonization become problematic in the absence of a rule-based framework that creates discipline among members and reduces the risk of bad policies (Currie, Holtham, and Hughes, 1989). The recent euro zone debt crisis is a good example of weak enforced rules and inadequate policy coordination.

In the case of EAC, the implementation of some decisions of EAC central banks’ governors has delayed or decisions changed because they are not binding. For example, the decision of governors to set the reserve requirement ratio at 5% by 2018 was modified in 2017 because one central bank failed to manage liquidity in the banking sector and decided to maintain its reserve requirement ratio at high level for a period of four years. Some countries have also postponed the adoption of price based monetary policy to 2021 instead of 2018 initially agreed by EAC central banks’

governors. The lack of firm commitment to implement decisions taken by different regional committees to fast-track the implementation of EAMU protocol due to more focus on relative national gains and sovereignty is one of big challenges in the journey towards full regional integration.

To ensure good preparation on the establishment of EAMU, Partner States agreed to create the East African Monetary Institute (EAMI), responsible for the preparatory work for the monetary union. It was also agreed to create the following institutions to support the monetary union: an institution responsible for financial services; an institution responsible for surveillance, compliance and enforcement and an institution responsible for statistics.

A few number of studies assessing the readiness of EAC countries to adopt a monetary union exists. Two main conclusions emerge from those studies. First, exchange rates in EAC countries mostly absorb real asymmetric shocks with the exception of Burundi, exchange rate shock being a source of disturbances to inflation and not to GDP (Paulo Drummond, at al. 2015). Second, there is not a clear evidence about synchronization of business cycles and macro-economic convergence, suggesting that there could be substantial costs for the member countries from a fast-tracked process (Buigut, 2011; Rusuhuzwa & Masson, 2012; Davoodi et al., 2013; Mafusire & Brixiova, 2013; Lepetit et al., 2014; Asongu, 2014bc; Buigui & Valev, 2005 ; Falagiarda, 2010; Kishor &

Ssozi, 2011; Sheik et al., 2011).

(9)

The overall objective of this research is to re-assess the readiness of East African Community countries for a monetary union by extending the sample of study to cover the recent period when progress was made in policy coordination and implementation of common market protocol. In addition, this paper is a contribution to the existing literature on the assessment of the feasibility of different monetary blocks in Africa, using the case study of EAC.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In the section 2, we present a summary of literature review. In the section 3 we analyze how EAC countries have been achieving convergence criteria.

In section 4, we evaluate additional indicators linked to OCA theory. In section 5, we conduct empirical analysis about the readiness of EAC countries to form a monetary union, and in the last section, we conclude the paper and propose policy recommendations.

II. Literature review

Theoretical literature review

Most of empirical studies on monetary unions have focused on the capacity of the countries concerned to satisfy optimum-currency-area (OCA) criteria considering that economies subjected to similar terms-of-trade shocks are more-suitable candidates for a monetary union. The reason is that exchange-rate adjustment between those economies will not be needed and this will permit the implementation of a common monetary policy (e.g. Mundell, McKinnon, 1963). The elimination of the transaction costs due to exchanging currencies and exchange-rate volatility are the two main benefits of monetary union (Robson, 1987, p. 140; Tavlas, 1993). Contrary, the main costs of monetary union are those attributable to the inability of monetary authorities of the individual countries to use country-specific monetary policies and the exchange rate as an instrument of macroeconomic adjustment in response to shocks.

This explains why the analysis of the gains and losses arising from the establishment of monetary union focuses on the structural characteristics of the candidates for a monetary union such as (1) analysis of the nature of shocks affecting the economies considered; (2) assessment of the degree

(10)

of correlations of movements of real exchange rates and/or the terms-of-trade among the economies; and, (3) analysis of co-movements in cyclical real growth rates among the economies.

While earlier work on OCA focused on identifying the characteristics that an economy should satisfy prior to joining a monetary union (i.e., ex ante), the endogenous theory of OCA has focused on changes in economic structure and performance that may result from participation in a monetary union. In other words, the adoption of a common currency can improve the structural characteristics of the economies concerned, increasing trade-integration and business-cycle correlation, and enhancing the credibility of macroeconomic policies (Frankel and Rose, 1998;

Rose, 2000). This implies that the participation in a currency area becomes more favorable after a country joins a currency union than before. Thus, the creation of a monetary union can itself create conditions that are favorable for the well-functioning of the union (De Grauwe, 2007, p.

27).

Endogenous OCA theory posits that a common currency can promote trade and growth. In addition to removing the costs of currency conversion, a single currency and a common monetary policy increases price transparency, facilitate foreign direct and portfolio investment and the building of long-term relationships. These outcomes would, promote reciprocal trade as a result, economic and financial integration, and the accumulation of knowledge. Countries could then become more similar in a currency union than before joining the union (Rose at.al, 2001; Mongelli, 2002).

Empirical literature review

Empirical research on feasibility of monetary union differ in terms of used empirical methodologies, countries considered and sample periods which makes the results from all these studies incomparable. Various methodologies were applied, including (i) analysis of correlations of real growth rates; exchange rates / terms-of trade ; (ii) correlations of shocks identified using statistical transformation of data or a Structural Vector Autogression SVAR) models analysis and, (iii) a cointegration approach. Studies that report correlations of real per capita growth rates aim to provide information on underlying shocks, the idea being that, apart from the impact of trend, movements in output are driven mainly by shocks, considering that cyclical movements in output are the primary result of the shocks.

(11)

(12)

Karras (2007) calculated correlations of de-trended output growth of nine SADC countries using real GDP based on purchasing-power-parity real exchange rates. He applied the following three methods to estimate the cyclical component of output: (1) first differencing, (2) the Hodrick- Prescott (HP) filter, and (3) the Band-pass (BP) filter to remove the trend from output growth.

Using the same approach, Bayoumi and Ostry (2007) calculated bilateral output correlations among country pairs contrary to Karras who estimated correlations of each country’s cyclical output component against the SADC total.

Masson and Pattillo (2005) estimated correlations of per cent changes in the terms of trade for 14 SADC countries; Wang et al. (2006) calculated correlations of per cent changes in the terms of trade for Botswana and the four CMA economies; Jefferis (2007) calculated correlations of movements of bilateral nominal exchange rates of twelve SADC countries against the South African rand.

A limitation of this approach is that the techniques do not make a distinction between disturbances to output growth and the policy responses to the disturbances. In addition, the approach does not account for the situation where an identical shock may affect individual countries differently due to differences in key factors such as wage and price flexibility, tax structure, and trade responsiveness (Mélitz, 1991, p. 321; Tobin, 1993).

In order to deal with these limitations, some authors use econometric methods in order to extract the underlying disturbances from real output. Bayoumi and Ostry (1997), Yehoue (2005), and Wang et al.(2006) employed a three-step autoregressive estimation procedure. The growth of per capita GDP (measured as change in the logarithm of real GDP per capita) was regressed upon its own first and second lags. The residuals from this regression (or a measure of the residuals, such as the standard deviation of the residuals) were considered as underlying real output disturbances, and correlations among disturbances were calculated. While autoregressive approach helps separate the underlying shocks from the data, it does not separate demand and supply shocks.

To address this problem, different studies have used the Vector Auto regression (VAR) technique.

Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1992) were among the first to identify the underlying structural shocks using the Vector Auto regression (VAR) technique developed by Blanchard and Quah (1989) and measured the incidence of asymmetric demand and supply shocks across members of the former European Community (EC) and compared them with the ones prevailing in the United States.

(13)

The idea is that asymmetric supply shocks are likely to continue after monetary unification while asymmetric demand shocks are likely to diminish (since they are partly policy induced). Thus, Countries that are confronted with relatively-large asymmetric supply shocks are not likely to be good candidates for monetary union.

Since then, a large literature including on optimum currency area, has applied this methodology or a related approach to different compositions of country groups in Europe (Bayoumi and Taylor 1995, Ramaswamy and Slok, 1998, Kouparitsas ,1999; Fidrmuc and Korhonen, 2001 and Frenkel and Nickel, 2002) and in East Asia (e.g. Yuen and Ling, 2001 and Zhang et al, 2004).

It is important to mention that the Blanchard-Quah technique involves limitations such as restraining any relationship among variables to be a linear and considering that there are only two kinds of shocks in the economy: a supply shock that is assumed to be permanent and a demand shock that is assumed to be temporary.

Grandes (2003) and Khamfula and Huizinga (2004) used cointegration approach for Botswana and the four CMA countries and tested for cointegration among bilateral real exchange rates, using the rand as the base currency. If the relationships were stationary, the author inferred that the real exchange rates exhibited common trends and that the countries had been subjected to symmetric shocks.

Multivariate cointegration analysis has been applied by a number of authors to test convergence especially for the European Monetary Union (EMU). Haug et al. (2000) used cointegration techniques to analyze which of the European Union (EU) countries would form a successful monetary union based on the nominal convergence criteria defined in the Maastricht treaty. Brada and Kutan (2002) compared the convergence of monetary policy of the Balkan and Mediterranean candidates for EU membership with those of Germany as a proxy for the European Central Bank (ECB).

(14)

Khamfula and Huizinga (2004) used a GARCH model to estimate correlations of unanticipated components of bilateral real exchange rates of nine SADC countries against the South African rand, using both monthly and quarterly data over the period 1980-96. The methodology is based on the following three steps.

(1) Calculate bilateral real rates against the rand and seasonally adjust the change in each bilateral rate using seasonal dummies. Calculate two sets of residuals: one for the monthly data and the other for the quarterly data, used as estimates of unanticipated residuals;

(2) Regress each of the residuals on its own lags (up to seven lags);

(3) Squares of unanticipated residuals are used as measures of underlying shocks. In this approach, monthly and quarterly residuals characterize short-run and long-run shocks respectively.

Although there are a number of economic blocks considering monetary union in Africa like the two CFA regions: the West African Economic and Monetary Union (UEMOA) and the region of the Central Bank of central Africa (BEAC), the Southern African Development Community (SADC), and the East Africa Community ( EAC), application of this methodology in Africa has been limited.

Fielding and Shields (2001) used the same methodology to compare economic shocks to different members of the two CFA monetary unions. Khamfula and Huizinga (2004) investigated the desirability of a monetary union among the SADC countries using Generalized Auto-Regressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity (GARCH) model to assess the share of the variation in real exchange rates vis-à-vis South Africa that can be explained by the divergence in monetary and fiscal policies.

Dutu and Sparks (2004) assessed the degree of convergence among fourteen SADC countries over the period 1995-98. The variables considered by those authors included annual bilateral exchange- rate changes against the South African rand, inflation rates, external debt-to-GDP ratios, and openness.

(15)

There is a few number of empirical studies on the feasibility of monetary union in EAC. Mkenda (2001) employs a Generalized Purchasing Power Parity (GPPP) model developed by Enders and Hurn (1994), this approach uses cointegration methods to find if the prospective countries’

macroeconomic variables exhibit long-run relationships. Economies suitable for a monetary union experience symmetric shocks to their macroeconomic variables and thus on average ‘move’

together. GPPP postulates then that the real exchange rates between countries comprising an optimal currency area should be cointegrated. However, this approach does not distinguish disturbances from responses because movements in macroeconomic variables reflect the combined effects of shocks and responses (Angeloni and Dedola, 1999).

Buigut and Valev (2006) used a VAR analysis, adopting the identification scheme due to Blanchard and Quah (1989) to achieve this distinction in EAC. The study by Kigabo Rusuhuzwa and Paul Mason (2012) used different methodologies and data covering the period 1995-2013.

First, the paper examined if EAC countries face correlated trend and cyclical components of their macroeconomic indicators such as GDP using Hodrick Prescott (1997) filter. The paper used a VAR to identify supply shocks, and furthermore, a cointegration approach to test if real effective exchange rates are cointegrated.

Buigut S (2011) applied multivariate cointegration to the case of EAC countries using quarterly data covering the period 1997Q4-2009Q1, considering several criteria (nominal exchange rates, real exchange rates, and inflation rates, monetary base and real output). The monetary base is included as an indicator of monetary policy convergence in absence of consistent long term interest rate data. The monetary aggregate is preferred over other broader aggregates because it is less diluted by intervention by other agents in the financial system, and better able to capture the central bank’s policy stance.

Paulo Drummond, at.al (2015) uses different methodologies to identify the degree of susceptibility of the EAC economies to asymmetric shocks; assesses the value of the exchange rate as a shock absorber for these countries; and reviews adjustment mechanisms that would help ensure a successful experience under the monetary union.

(16)

The study concluded that despite some similarities in the structures of their economies, country- specific shocks have been prevalent in the last two decades, with EAC economies remaining susceptible to asymmetric shocks. While declining dispersion of growth rates across countries suggests gradual move toward economic convergence in the last decade, cluster analysis indicates that dissimilarities remain large.

III. Convergence criteria

Convergence criteria are rooted in the optimum currency theory stipulating that more convergent economies have greater benefits in being members of currency union. In general, convergence criteria have been defined either, in terms of countries having similar economic behavior, such closed rates of inflation and economic growth, or in absolute terms, such as all countries candidates for or members of a monetary union to achieving an agreed low rate of inflation.

Convergence is seen as necessary to form monetary unions and various monetary blocs have adopted similar convergence criteria to those in the European Monetary Union (EMU), setting different targets on used macro-economic variables. Based on EMU experience, convergence criteria are obligatory for all countries seeking to join a monetary union or that are already members. In addition, economic conditions in all union member countries have to be similar so that a single monetary or exchange rate policy be effective.

As mentioned, the experience of the EMU has been perceived as successful in bringing benefits to its members. This explains why planned monetary unions have adopted convergence criteria similar to those in Europe and formally intend to converge like in Europe. However, in the case of Africa,, the ability of small, poor countries to meet strict criteria may be limited and one can expect to see planned monetary unions in Africa taking a bit longer to be established.

(17)

There is however real danger resulting from political pressures to pursue currency unions in Africa, before convergence criteria are met due to high expectations about the benefits of monetary union such as lower financial transactions costs, more stable monetary conditions, greater exchange rate stability, better price signals, financial market integration, and the objective of creating more solidarity among African countries. This is a challenge because monetary unions require strong signals of convergence resulting from efficient policies, institutions and regional infrastructures to facilitate trade among countries forming a monetary union.

It is therefore critical to examine how countries are converging, before forming a monetary union or at least examine whether there is a clear evidence of structural similarities among monetary union members, free movement of labor, a high degree of economic openness, enabling business environment and diversification in the structure of the economies.

One key issue in proposed unions, is asymmetries in the size and strength of individual union members, the nature of shocks affecting those economies as well as the nature of policies used to deal with those shocks. In the case countries agree to establish a monetary union with limited convergence, the success may depend on the extent that the largest members may be willing to support smaller or weaker members until greater convergence can be achieved. About the nature of shocks, the literature distinguishes two shocks hitting the countries on path to become members of a monetary union namely symmetric and asymmetric shocks. Symmetric shocks affect all union member countries in similar ways. An example could be a sharp hike in food prices that affects all EAC countries. In the case of presence of symmetric shocks, a single monetary policy for the entire union is more likely to be successful. On the other side, asymmetric shocks hit union member countries distinctively. An example would be a hike in international oil prices that may differently affect economies of union countries that produce oil to those which are net importer of oil products. In that case, countries within unions cannot rely on traditional monetary policy and exchange rate, and therefore must rely on other policies available to them (such as taxation, public expenditure, market development, etc.) to deal with the shocks.

(18)

3.1. EAMU convergence criteria

In EAC, partners States agreed to monitor the following indicative convergence criteria (i.e. early warning indicators):

a. Core inflation ceiling of 5 percent;

b. Fiscal deficit (excluding grants) ceiling of 6 percent of gross domestic product (GDP); and c. Tax-to-GDP ratio of 25 percent.

However, macroeconomic convergence will be assessed on the following performance convergence criteria:

a. Headline inflation ceiling of 8 percent;

b. Fiscal deficit (including grants) ceiling of 3 percent of GDP;

c. Gross public debt ceiling of 50 percent of GDP in net present value terms; and d. Reserve cover of 4.5 months of imports.

In this section, we analyze recent trends in the indicators pertaining to performance convergence criteria before we analyze other relevant factors as per the Optimum Currency Area (OCA) theory, such as economic structure, trade interdependence and business cycles.

An inspection of the EAC member countries’ performance since 2000, relative to the convergence criteria, reveals disparities among countries despite some similarities in the structures of their economies. Each country’s outcomes with respect to performance convergence criteria are reported in Table 1. In general, Partner States are on track of achieving the criteria on inflation.

However, challenges remain in attaining the criteria on fiscal deficit and adequate level of foreign reserves.

3.2. Criteria on inflation: Headline inflation ceiling of 8 percent

Movements in prices in countries may be one of the indicators of convergence or divergence that can be easily assessed. One issue merits consideration. In different prospect monetary unions, countries set a maximum acceptable level of inflation, such as 8 percent in EAC. However, a lower level of inflation in any country could be an indicator of economic problem so that a deflationary bias in many countries would be a serious structural problem for a monetary union.

(19)

Two approaches have been used to assess how countries comply with the criteria on inflation. In addition to comparing countries’ inflation rates to the convergence criteria, the standard deviation can be used to measure the dispersion between inflation rates. Increased integration between the member countries is likely to result in a reduction in the standard deviation over time. On the other side, widening of the spread can indicate that the real exchange rates of the economies are diverging and affecting the competitiveness of the economies.

In this section, we adopt two approaches to examine how inflation rates in EAC countries have been converging for the last seventeen years. In addition, some research on macroeconomic convergence use unit root tests on inflation differentials to establish whether two (or more) variables are in the process of converging, with large part of the gap between them depending on initial conditions. Stationarity tests, on the other hand, are the most appropriate tool to verify whether the series have converged, meaning that the difference between them tends to remain stable. For inflation differentials, the main interest is to test the hypothesis of absolute convergence; this means, testing whether or not inflation differentials were converging to zero (Fabio Busetti, 2006).

The assessment of the implication of inflation differential on monetary union depends on whether the expansionary effects associated with a real interest rate reduction or the contractionary ones induced by real exchange rate appreciation dominate. The answer to that question will depend on the magnitude of inflation differentials and on their persistence.

Persistent differences in inflation among members of a monetary union may lead to disparities in real interest rates, given that the common monetary policy leads to same nominal interest rates. A country where economic activity is relatively subdued is likely to experience a relatively high real interest rate, because inflationary pressures are less. This situation in turn could add further to the divergence of inflation in the union. However, in the case of absence of exchange rate flexibility, inflation differentials can serve as adjustment mechanism, for countries with higher productivity or lower wage growth than others. Those countries would experience a depreciation of the real exchange rate and thus a gain in trade competitiveness.

(20)

As shown in table 1, average inflation rate in each EAC country during the period 2010–16 was below double digits, however with disparities, varying from 4.1% in Rwanda to 8.7% in Tanzania.

All countries complied with inflation criteria of keeping headline inflation not exceeding 8%

between 2010 and 2016, except for some years. In the period under review, Burundi and Tanzania missed the target twice, Uganda and Kenya once. In addition, inflation was less volatile in Rwanda, with standard deviation (SD) of 1.7. It was more volatile in Burundi (SD=4.5), followed by Uganda (SD=4.3), Tanzania (SD=4.1) and Kenya (SD=3). The volatility in inflation rates is mainly due to supply shocks, particularly changes in food prices and also volatility in regional currencies’

exchange rates due to external shocks and structure of economies (the split between the shares in GDP of the traded and non- traded sectors). Understanding the nature of shocks hitting EAC countries is important because of observed difference in volatility in inflation and the important role played by exchange rates as source of disturbances to inflation.

The graph below shows that inflation rates in EAC countries, except in Rwanda were higher in 2011 and 2012 due to high increase in food prices, but declined and remained lower than the target since 2013.

Figure 1: Inflation development in EAC

The cross-country standard deviation of EAC countries’ inflation rates increased since 2010, reaching its maximum (4.8) in the 2012 before slowing down to 0.4 in 2016, indicating

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20

2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

Bdi TZ UG KYA RDA Target

(21)

convergence in inflation rates during the recent period. High standard deviation in 2010- 2012 is an indication of how the five countries were differently affected by food prices shocks and external shocks.

Figure 2: Inflation development in standard deviation of inflation rates

3.3 Reserve cover of 4.5 months of imports.

To be protected against external shocks, EAC countries decided to hold foreign-exchange reserves covering at least 4.5 months of imports. Countries with adequate reserves generally avoided large drops in output and consumption in case of external shocks such as trade shocks, volatile aid, foreign direct investment, and a decline remittance flows.. Foreign reserves in conjunction with sound policies and economic fundamentals can bring significant benefits for countries by reducing the likelihood of balance of payments problems and ensuring economic and financial stability.

That is why a regular forward-looking discussion on reserve adequacy is important as it ensures that anticipated changes in baseline external vulnerabilities are taken into account.

According to the IMF definition, reserves are fundamentally an external liquidity buffer and external assets for a country, that are readily available to and controlled by monetary authorities for meeting balance of payments financing needs, for intervention in exchange markets to affect the currency exchange rate, and for other related purposes such as maintaining confidence in the currency and the economy, and serving as a basis for foreign borrowing (IMF, 2011).

0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 5.0 6.0

2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

(22)

The figure below shows that in the period 2010 and 2016, only Uganda complies with the criteria with foreign reserves covering exactly 4.5 months of import on average since 2012. The average level of coverage was 4.1 months of import in Rwanda and Kenya and 3.9 and 3.4 months in Tanzania and Burundi respectively.

Figure 3: International reserves-months of import

Literature on the need of keeping foreign reserves shows that lower levels of reserves are only needed in countries with good institutions and policies (IMF, 2011).

Inability of keeping sufficient levels of foreign reserves is an indication of economic problems, including less diversified economic structure and balance of payments imbalances as well as how vulnerable are EAC countries to external shocks with negative impact on macroeconomic stability.

Thus, EAC countries need to not only develop and diversify their economies to generate more foreign reserves but also ensure that they implement efficient policies and create sound institutions for better management of reserves, by clearly identifying responsibility and ensure accountability in the way reserves are effectively and efficiently managed to meet country’s needs.

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

BDI TZ UG Kya Rda Target

(23)

3.3.Government borrowing: Fiscal deficit (including grants) ceiling of 3 percent of GDP and Gross public debt ceiling of 50 percent of GDP in net present value terms; and

Convergence in fiscal policies is very important for the viability of monetary union, because after adoption of a single monetary policy, national fiscal policy will remain the main tool at the disposal of individual countries to respond to national economic shocks. However, fiscal policy stance may differ considerably from a country to another and this has different implications on the monetary union. A country that runs a big budget deficit and borrows heavily from other member countries to cover the deficit could prevent funding from productive investments to the disadvantage of the monetary union as a whole.

In addition, if many members of a monetary union highly borrow, this would be an indication of structural problems in the union that could tighten investment in private sectors and possibly damage the long-term health of the union. Furthermore, a wide difference of government deficits could indicate that certain economies were drawing in investment capital to the possible detriment on other union members. In summary, in a monetary union, domestic fiscal policies can cause negative spillover effects on other members of the union.

The ratio of government debt to GDP, which is a function of the size of the fiscal deficit is commonly used as convergence criteria in monetary unions as it can provide information on the long-term sustainability of fiscal positions of countries. Stable or declining ratios are considered desirable. High deficits can potentially cause unsustainable growth in the debt ratios, and thus the deficit and debt ratios must be monitored together.

In EAC countries, overall fiscal and external deficits are sizeable, mostly reflecting large infrastructure spending and associated capital goods imports. All EAC countries complied with the criteria of gross public debt ceiling of 50 percent of GDP, except the recent case in Kenya where the ratio increased to 52.4% and 54.4% in 2015 and 2016 respectively. Furthermore, gross public debt as percentage of GDP has been increasing trend is observed in all EAC countries during recent years showing pressures on government budgets leading to more deficit.

(24)

Figure 4: Budget deficit as percentage of GDP

About the fiscal deficit, including grants not to exceed 3% of GDP, only Rwanda consistently complied with that criterion between 2010 and 2016. Considering the indicative convergence criteria about fiscal deficit (excluding grants) not to exceed 6 percent of gross domestic product some countries such as Rwanda, Tanzania and Burundi have consistently found it difficult.

Combining the two criteria about fiscal deficit including or excluding grants, it becomes apparent that EAC countries’ capacity to generate their own revenue remains low compared to their financial demands. The high dependency on grants or aid for economic development is risky for any economy even more dangerous as nations ascend the union given that such donor support is not sustainable source of financing government expenditures.

Figure 4: Gross public debt (% of GDP)

As indicated, fiscal policy will be the main macroeconomic policy tool available to the countries after giving up independent national monetary policy. In addition, the above analysis has shown that fiscal convergence is an area where EAC countries still have considerable challenges.

0 10 20 30 40 50 60

2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

BDI TZ UGA KYA RDA Target

0 10 20 30 40 50 60

2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

BDI TZ UG KYA RDA Target

(25)

To achieve this objective going forward, there is a need for EAC countries to agree to explicit and binding fiscal convergence commitments as prerequisites and ongoing commitments for the viability of EAMU.

Complying with fiscal convergence criteria is challenging considering the macroeconomic context of EAC countries, with significant need for investment and development spending. In addition, the countries face significant macroeconomic shocks, such as terms-of-trade shocks from international commodity prices and agricultural productivity shocks from weather as well as international aid shock. Thus, sufficient discretion in national fiscal policy would better enable individual countries to respond to national economic shocks. This calls for not only agreements on fiscal convergence criteria and commitment for fiscal discipline but also the establishment of institution or strong mechanism for enforcement and ensuring compliance by all countries.

Indeed, once the EAC establishes fiscal convergence criteria that best suit the needs of its members, an immediate challenge will be preserving those commitments. Thus, EAC should have an independent institution to oversee issues of fiscal surveillance, decision and enforcement.

Independence involves the personnel selection process, the EAC enforcement agency’s budget, and the enforcement mechanism avoiding any political pressure. In addition to the establishment of EAMI, it is urgent to fast track the establishment of the institution responsible for surveillance, compliance and enforcement as indicated in EAMU protocol.

History demonstrates that several approaches have widely been used to try ensuring fiscal discipline in monetary unions. These include centralized enforcement (e.g., EMU and WAEMU since 1999), surveillance and persuasion (e.g., ECCU and CEMAC), and decentralized enforcement (e.g., USA).

These approaches attempt to address the imperfect incentives facing the governments when deciding about fiscal policies in each country. For example, elected officials tend to have short time horizons and are tempted to increase borrowing to implement different projects and meet expectations of their constituencies. However, because in a monetary union the costs of borrowing are shared with other member states, elected officials in a member country are constrained to postpone hard choices.

(26)

One method is to legally, denounce bailouts although it is difficult in practice. If a state member of a monetary union is about to deny its debt, its creditors may be spread throughout the monetary union. Greece and Ireland are a case in point. Despite the Maastricht Treaty’s “no-bailout” clause, 27 the two countries received bailouts because in a monetary union where countries are more integrated, costs of not bailing out a country may eventually exceed the costs of bailing out that country.

A second method is to create a firm and categorical rule banning deficits and debt beyond a certain level. To ban behavior, the sanctions applied to non-compliant countries must be prohibitive. This approach has advantages because violations are easy to identify and are uniformly punished.

However, during periods of economic hardship, these rules are also difficult to implement in a monetary union. They can unwisely prevent sound economic policies to limit negative impact of economic problems affecting the population of the concerned country. Thus, such rule is likely to face political resistance. In addition, in an integrated monetary union, the costs of not increasing budget deficits may spill over and affect other member states. As such, the rule is likely to face severe political resistance.

A third method might be enforcement with a more flexible, multifactor balancing test. This rule would allow the judge of excessive deficits to consider a country’s circumstances to determine the economic merits and demerits of a particular deficit. The big challenge related to this approach is that such rules rely heavily on the judge’s subjective opinions and this can lead to disagreement among countries. The former East African Currency Board, which was in place from 1960 to 1966 and composed by Uganda, Kenya and Tanzania is a good case about challenges associated to this approach. By 1964 both Tanzania and Uganda had reached their borrowing limits and wanted to raise the limits to borrow more but after Kenya’s approval. This situation contributed to dissolving the monetary union within six years of independence.

(27)

Table 1: EAC Macroeconomic convergence criteria

Country Indicator 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 Average SD

Burundi

Headline inflation 6.5 9.6 18.2 7.9 4.4 4.6 5.5 8.1 4.5 International Reserves

(months of imports) 4.1 3.2 3.4 3.4 3.5 4.2 1.9 3.4 0.8 Fiscal deficit, including

grants (in % of GDP) -3.6 -3.9 -3.7 -1.7 -3.4 -5.3 -6.2 Gross public debt (% of

GDP) 46.9 42.7 41.4 36.1 35.7 46 47.2

Tanzania

Headline inflation 7.2 12.7 16 7.9 6.1 5.6 5.2 8.7 4.1 International Reserves

(months of imports) 4.1 3.5 3.6 4 4.3 4 3.7 3.9 0.3

Fiscal deficit, including

grants (in % of GDP) -4.8 -3.6 -4.1 -3.9 -3 -3.3 -3.8 Gross public debt (% of

GDP) 27.5 28 29.2 31.4 33.2 36.9 39

Uganda

Headline inflation 3.7 15 12.7 4.9 3.1 5.4 5.5 7.2 4.3 International Reserves

(months of imports) 3.9 3.7 4.5 4.8 5.1 4.8 4.5 4.5 0.5 Fiscal deficit, including

grants (in % of GDP) -5.8 -2.6 -3 -3.9 -3.3 -2.7 -3.6 Gross public debt (% of

GDP) 23.6 23.3 24.6 27.4 30.1 33.2 36.9

Kenya

Headline inflation 4.3 14 9.4 5.7 6.9 6.6 6.3 7.6 3

International Reserves

(months of imports) 2.9 2.8 3.7 3.9 5.3 5.1 4.8 4.1 1.0 Fiscal deficit, including

grants (in % of GDP) -4.4 -4.1 -5 -5.7 -7.4 -8.2 -7.3 Gross public debt (% of

GDP) 44.4 43 40.8 42.2 48.6 52.4 54.4

Rwanda

Headline inflation 2.3 5.7 6.3 4.2 1.8 2.5 5.7 4.1 1.7 International Reserves

(months of imports) 5.2 6.5 5.6 4.8 3.9 3.5 4 4.8 1.1

Fiscal deficit, including

grants (in % of GDP) -0.7 -0.9 -2.5 -1.3 -4 -2.8 -2.4 Gross public debt (% of

GDP) 20 19.9 20 26.7 29.1 33.4 37.6

Source: MAC, August 2017

In addition to reviewing the union’s regular convergence indicators, various other measures could be monitored. They include real exchange rates, change in terms of trade, economic structures and intraregional trade. Some of these indicators will be analyzed in section four. Real exchange rates within a currency union influence competition and cross-border trade, while competitiveness of each country in a monetary union is a function both of the union exchange rate and the prices in each country.

(28)

A country with higher inflation relative to other union members will become externally less competitive as its real exchange rate rises. In a monetary union, changes in real exchange rates due to variations in prices may lead countries members to have large differences in their external trade patterns in terms of origins, destinations and composition of trade. This can create situations where the common monetary and exchange rate policies are inappropriate for some member countries.

Terms of trade shifts can affect competitiveness and current account positions between monetary union members and can create political conflicts between members because gains of one member come at a cost to other members.

The level of economic diversification is also important in a monetary union because the more diversified economies are; the more likely that those economies will be affected by similar shocks.

In addition, more diversified economies have greater flexibility to adjust to shocks and to buffer shifts in demand. Two opposite effects of entry in monetary union on industrial concentration have been hypothesized in the literature. First, monetary union will cause greater inter-industry specialization because firms exploit their comparative advantages within larger markets, which reduces trade diversification. Second, increased inter-industry specialization results as suppliers link up with industrial customers throughout the union, which will increase trade diversification.

3.4.Other convergence indicators Economic growth in EAC countries

Overall macroeconomic performance in EAC countries is mixed and economic structures are generally diverse in terms of economic growth and industrial structures. Kenya is the largest economy accounting for an average of 38.4% per cent of total EAC GDP between 2000 and 2016, followed by Tanzania (34.1%), Uganda (20.1%), Rwanda (4.8%) and Burundi (2.4%). Kenya is also relatively industrialized and diversified while most of the other economies are small and relying on a narrow range of commodity exports. Kenya is the regional trade hub and its private enterprises lead the intraregional investment. For example, Kenyan banks operate across the region, with subsidiaries in the rest of EAC countries.

(29)

The real economic growth rates were diverse, ranging from an average of 3.1% in Burundi and 7.9% in Rwanda between 2010 and 2016 (Table 2). During the last five years (2012-2016), real economic growth was not only low but very volatile in Burundi, averaging 2% with a standard deviation of 4.3. Average GDP growth rates remain higher in Rwanda (7.2%) followed by Tanzania (6.7%), Kenya (5.4%) and Uganda (4.1%). During that period, economic growth was less volatile in Kenya (SD=0.5) and Tanzania (SD=0.9).

Table 2: real GDP growth

Burundi Kenya Rwanda Tanzania Uganda

2000 1.8 0.3 8.4 4.9 3.9

2001 1.7 4.0 8.5 6.0 8.8

2002 2.4 0.5 13.2 6.9 7.1

2003 2.5 2.9 2.2 6.4 6.2

2004 3.8 4.6 7.5 7.2 5.8

2005 4.4 5.7 9.4 6.5 10.0

2006 5.4 5.9 9.2 4.7 7.0

2007 3.5 6.9 7.6 8.5 8.1

2008 4.9 0.2 11.2 5.6 10.4

2009 3.8 3.3 6.3 5.4 8.1

2010 5.1 8.4 7.3 6.4 7.7

2011 4.0 6.1 7.8 7.9 6.8

2012 4.4 4.6 8.8 5.1 3.2

2013 5.9 5.7 4.7 7.3 4.7

2014 4.5 5.3 7.6 7.0 4.6

2015 -4.0 5.7 8.9 7.0 5.7

2016 -1.0 5.8 5.9 7.0 2.3

Average 3.1 4.5 7.9 6.4 6.5

SD 2.5 2.3 2.4 1.1 2.3

AV5 2.0 5.4 7.2 6.7 4.1

SD5 4.3 0.5 1.8 0.9 1.3

(30)

Additionally, declining dispersion of growth rates across countries in the last years suggests only a gradual move toward economic convergence and indicates differences in real GDP growth.

Figure 4: Real GDP-Standard deviation development

Furhermore, the more similar the economic structures of the potential candidates for a monetary union are, so is the effects of the impact of sector-specific shocks on their economies, and less national monetary policies are needed. In all EAC countries, the ratio of the agricultural sector to GDP remains high but has been declining overtime in all the five countries as the share of services in GDP was increasing. That is an indication of progressive diversification in EAC economies.

The share of services in GDP increased from 28.5% to 38.3% between 1990/5 and 2012/6 in Burundi. It increased from 36.08% to 47.6; from 40.48% to 44% and from 35.88% to 50% in Rwanda, Tanzania and Uganda respectively in the same period; while remaining stable in Kenya slightly declining from 49.58% to 49.3%. However, the industry sector share in GDP remain low in all countries. This limits intra-regional trade of industrial products and increases the dependence of the region to the rest of the world in terms of trade.

0.0 2.0 4.0 6.0 8.0

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

SD

Références

Documents relatifs

In section 3 we define a new operator for action negation therefore give arise to a new dynamic logic.. In Section 4 we apply the new logic to the

pluralisme des ordres juridiques, Mélanges B. 21 - V.F.LATTY, Le droit transnational économique, Droit de l’économie internationale, éd a.. لولأا عرفلا : نوناق موهفم راجتلا

Keywords: Behavioural Science, Behavioural Economics, Health Promotion, Public Health, Nudge.. David McDaid is Senior Research Fellow at LSE Health and Social Care and at

Calibrating our model for the EAC using annual data for the period 2003 to 2010, for various proxies of our respective monetary, …nancial and …scal stability measures, we then

In order to explain the visual approach, we present the problem of retrieval in terms of a classification problem: classify the documents as relevant or non relevant.. (14) In fact,

“I think one of the problems is that on issues of language, race, culture, ethnicity, religion, white politicians in power particularly, silence themselves for fear of rebuke from

● Psychometric assessment that measures organizational readiness for implementing change. ● Commitment / ability to transition to BIBFRAME ( e.g. task demands, resource

The Dawn mission found that the dominant colour variation on the surface of dwarf planet Ceres is a change of the visible spectral slope, where fresh impact craters are surrounded