• Aucun résultat trouvé

The benefits of improvements in coastal water quality : the contingent approach as applied to Brest natural harbour

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "The benefits of improvements in coastal water quality : the contingent approach as applied to Brest natural harbour"

Copied!
17
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

HAL Id: hal-02282304

https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-02282304

Submitted on 7 Jun 2020

HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- entific research documents, whether they are pub- lished or not. The documents may come from teaching and research institutions in France or abroad, or from public or private research centers.

L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires publics ou privés.

Distributed under a Creative Commons Attribution - NonCommercial - NoDerivatives| 4.0 International License

the contingent approach as applied to Brest natural harbour

Philippe Le Goffe

To cite this version:

Philippe Le Goffe. The benefits of improvements in coastal water quality : the contingent approach as

applied to Brest natural harbour. 5. Annual meeting, Jun 1994, Dublin, Ireland. 16 p. �hal-02282304�

(2)

The European Association of Environmental and Resou rce Economisfs

***

Fifth Annuat Meeting - Dublin - June 22-24, 1994

TNC BENEFITS OF IMPROVEMENTS IN COASTAL WATER QUALITY : TNE COruTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BNCST NATURAL HARBOUR.

Ph. Le Goffe

. N. S. A. R.- Eçonomie, Gestion et Sciences Sociales 65, Rue de Saint-Brieuc - 35042 Rennes cedex (France)

SUMMARY

Brest natural harbour was chosen by the European Community as a pilot site in respect to improvements in coastal water quality. The depollution program will be financed

by the Community, the French Government and the regional authorities. There are two problems to be resolved in priority : microbe contamination from urban sources and over enrichment in nutrients from agricultural sources. This paper deals with the non-market value which local people give to water quality in the harbour. Our objectives are to improve

the knowledge about the demand for natural assets in France, and simultaneously to prepare a cost-benefit analysis which will help decision-making concerning the restoration of the harbour. ln an on site survey carried out in summer 1993, we realised a contingent valuation for two goods : 1) improved water salubrity, and 2) preservation of the ecosystem against eutrophication (under uncertainty). The corresponding WTP's were explained using Tobit models. Whatever the good, the WTP was seen to rise with revenue. However, whilst the WTP "salubrity" was affected by environmental sensibility and the awareness of local pollution, it is above all education which affected the WTP "ecosystem". On whole, the residents accepted the exercise of contingent valuation and were willing to give important amounts (FF 215 and FF 160 on average per household per year respectively for goods 1 and 2). The behavioural differences between both goods and the significance of the WTP's thus obtained are discussed.

OOCUillEI'ITATON ÉCONOr\]llE RURALE REI'IttËS

€Asl -êsC

/îce *t" l,

2 5 t{Af;$ 199+

- trEruefË$

T

illll.lïlllllllll llll l!il lll llll

(3)

1. INTRODUCTION

ln a synthesis on water pollution control policies, Freeman (1990) insisted on the interest society has in making àn economic choice for depollution objectives. The first point,

and this is true whatever the eventual goals may be, is to select the means to be implemented with the idea of minimising depollution costs e.g. use of economic instruments such as taxes, negotiable permits. Secondly, objectives should be fixed with the aim of making the benefits from depollution superior to the corresponding costs. An examination of the arising costs and benefits is therefore an integral part of the construction of a pollution control policy and ensures an efficient allocation of resources. ln this same study, Freeman tried to evaluate the nationwide benefits in 1985 accruing from the application of the Federal Water Pollution Act Amendments 1972 . The benefits from the rise in water quality can be classified into four categories according to the different functions of water: drinking water, production, recreation and ecology (Amigues et al, 1993). For Freeman, the benefits associated with the recreational and ecological functions of water i.e. recreational use + passive use represent over 60% of total benefits. lt is precisely these non-market benefits which are examined in this Paper.

The litterature concerning the non-market benefits of improvements in water quality mainly deals with continental waters. Most papers measure the on site recreational use values of water to the exclusion of any measurement of the passive use values of water (synthesis from Walsh et al 1992, Navrud and Strand, 1992.) These daily values for

recreational use represent the total surplus per day of leisure resulting from the enjoyment of a ressource of a given quality. With the background of a policy of pollution control, more rare studies have estimated the variation in consumers'surplus induced by a variation in surface water quality (Mitchell and Carson, 1981 and 1984 ; Smith and Desvousges, 1986). When measured ex ante by the contingent valuation method (CVM), these non-market benefits represent the total economic value, including values for active and passive uses. Studies on marine water falling into this second category are very limited. Bockstael et al (1989) and Magnussen (1992) studied the benefits associated with a reduction in nutrients in coastal waters :Chesapeake Bay and the North Sea respectively, using two different approaches.

Eutrophication resulting from the over enrichment of water in nitrate and phosphate is one of the major problems of pollution in Brest natural harbour. Brest natural harbour is situated at the point of Brittany in western France. The nitrate concentration in the harbour's estuaries has doubled over the past fifteen years. ln Brittany the principal sources of nutrients are, in decreasing order of importance : animal faeces, fertilisers and domestic and industrial waste water. High concentrations of nutrients in coastal waters can provoke

THE BENEF|TS oF tMpRovEMENTs tN CoASTAL WATER euALtw : THE coNTtNcENT APPRoACH As APPLIED To BREST NATURAL HARBoUR

Ph. Le Goffe

(4)

blooming in seaweed or phytoplancton (coloured waters). The ultimate result of this is the asphyxiation of deep water letding to the disappearance of fish and other forms.of marine life. Until now, the harbour was protected from eutrophication by the strong currents which are to be found there but the estuaries and the internal bays are potentially threatened.

Another important problem is microbe contamination from domestic sewage which effectively by-passes the water treatment plants which serve the coastal communities. The harbour water is mostly of medium quality or momentaneously bad quality for bathing. lt is not advised to eat wild shellfish fished on shore due to possible health hazards such as gastro enteritis or viral hepatitis. Lastly, other contaminating agents whose effects are not fully known are equally present. These contaminants range from pesticides to heavy metals and tributyl tin i.e. TBT, an antifouling agent.

1992 saw the signing of a bay contract for Brest harbour, linking the European Community, the French Government and all the local and regional governments, as well as the main economic actors of the region. The bay contract, whose head of works is the City of Brest, aims to improve water quality and to safeguard and restore marine life in the bay area. The urban pollution control measures plan, amongst other things, to restructure the existing purification networks and to construct new water treatment plants. ln order to reduce agricultural pollution, current methods of crop cultivation and animal rearing will have

to be modified. One means of reducing polluting inputs i.e. pesticides and fertilisers would be to tax these inputs (Vermersch et a|,1991). Another solution which could be applied to the case of Brest would be to negotiate with the farmers themselves and eventually subsidise agricultural techniques respectful of the environment.

ln this paper, we have tried to evaluate the non-market value which is accorded by residents to an improved water quality and to the preservation of the marine ecosystem in Brest natural harbour. On the scientific front this study is aimed at increasing the knowledge of the value of such natural assets (there are only two such studies available for France

:

Bonnieux et al, 1992) and the determinants of their demand. On the practical side, the study aims to evaluate to what point the non-market services provided by the harbour area generate benefits which would socially justify the costs of depolluting the harbour area. We were also concerned with making our results transferable for other comparable situations which are numerous in France. To determine the residents' demand function for good water quality in the bay area, the CVM was chosen (Mitchell and Carson, 1989 ; Cummings et al, 1986 ). Although this study was not centered on the methodology of non-market benefit measurement, it does allow for the drawing of some lessons on the conditions surrounding the use of the CVM.

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMENTS IN coASTAL wATER oUALITY : THE coNTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATURAL HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

(5)

2. SURVEY METHODOLOGY AND CONTINGENT VALUATION

Onsite surueys

The contingent valuations were gathered from direct interviews onsite on the banks of the harbour bay, principally in Brest, between June and September 1993.607 interviews were conducted on five different locations with approximately 120 interviews conducted per site. Four locations were chosen to cover the different recreational activities which are practised along the bay area: beach , sandbank at low tide in periods of spring tide, sailing

harbour, coastalwalk. The fifth recreational site : Brest Botanical Gardens, was purposefully chosen outside of the immediate area in order to include some non users. The goods under

focus are of a local nature. Some problems of bias may come into play with foreign consumers : part-whole bias since the good may be mentally included in a wider context, strategic bias because they do not pay local taxes. Therefore only local inhabitants were interviewed. This is quite logical since this area is more of a local attraction due to its

morphology and the lack of beaches. Out of the 607 people interviewed, 7oo/o live in Brest itself and 95% live less than 15 km from the bay area. The interviews were conducted by 12 people, students in Geography at the university in Brest. They had all received one day's preliminary training during the course of which the objectives, the content and the underlying scientific basis were presented to them. For practical reasons, it was not possible to prevent certain interviewers from intervening more than others at certain sites and at certain times.

On average two people had to be approached in order to obtain one interview (50%

participation). The average time for an interview was twenty minutes.

Contingent markets

The interview questionnaire underwent a preliminary test. lt was centred on the measurement of the non-market beneflts from an improvement in the water quality in Brest natural harbour. Two contingent markets were proposed successively to the interviewees.

The corresponding goods were constructed from the two major pollution problems, short and long term, facing the bay area : pollution from microbes and nutrients. Care was taken to

select problems which were scientifically recognised and familiar to users (origins,

consequences on the environment and the various means of combatting the problems ), as well as being ecologically important. That is why potentially worrying problems such as pesticide contamination or TBT pollution have not been treated. The first scenario evokes the microbian quality of the harbour waters in 1992. lt presents the risks to man from

bathing and the consumption of wild shellfish in such unhealthy waters. The second scenario

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMENTS IN CoASTAL WATER QUALITY : THE CONTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATURAL HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

(6)

evokes the high concentrations of nutrients in the waters and their consequences on the marine ecosystem. This is done using photographs : especially of coloured waters. ln each case, the nature of the pollutùn and the solutions proposed to reduce or to remedy the problem are made explicit. The plausability of the scenarios was reinforced by two

unexpected events which took place during the course of the survey. Firstly, the fishing of wild shellfish in the harbour bay area was the subject of a government ban during two months beginning the end of may 1993 because of health concerns. Secondly, august witnessed a sudden development of coloured waters in one estuary and in the northern sector of the bay area. This was important enough to provoke fears about the possible asphyxiation of the shellfish reared in the sector.

The phenomonon of eutrophisation and its ultimate result i.e. the asphyxiation of the marine depths demand special treatment, due to the uncertainty surrounding them. lt is in practice difficult to fortell the growth rate in nutrients. Research is however being carried out in an attempt to determine thresholds for nutrient concentrations which would be succeptible to trigger acute eutrophication in the harbour bay area. Edwards (1988), in a paper on nitrate contamination of underground waters, introduced uncertainty on supply (contamination risk)

and on demand : the probability of being present at the moment of any eventual contamination. Here we limited ourselves to supply uncertainty. Three versions of the questionnaire were distributed equally amongst the twelve inquirers and the five sites. They differed only in respect to the risks of coloured water developing and the risks of asphyxiation of the water in the harbour bay : weak, noteworthy or very high.

After a reading of the two scenarios, valuation questions were asked. The interviewees were asked to allocate between the two pollution problems, the value accorded by them for a clean harbour bay . This precaution was destined to avoid any part-whole bias arising from the separation of the two goods. This separation was necessary in order to account for the characteristics and the mode of acquisition specific to each good. The interviewees were first asked about their willingness to pay (WTP) to be able , without risk,

to bathe and to consume wild shellfish in the harbour bay area. This defines the good

"salubrity". Next it was asked what would be the annual WTP to prevent the asphyxiation of

the harbour waters due to high concentrations of nutrients. This defines the good

"ecosystem". The method of payment used for the first good was the water bill. Here it was necessary to take into account the fact that the inhabitants of Brest had just seen a recent increase in their water bills - an increase designed to provide this very good (construction of a new water treatment plant, restructuring of the purification network). We needed to guard

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMENTS IN coAsTAL WATER QUALITY : THE CoNTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATURAL HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

(7)

against the bias of budgetary constraint. The payment vehicle for the second good was modified immediately after the return of the first interviews because of a proportion of nul responses which was too high.Ïhe local housing tax which was initially chosen is a local tax serving to finance the municipal budget. lt is judged to be too high by most inhabitants of Brest. The high level of the tax seems to be due to overequipment in the public sector. The

tax was replaced by participation in a special fund exclusively consecrated to the

preservation of the harbour bay area. For both goods the open valuation question was asked using the same payment card comporting amounts from FF 0 to FF 2000.

Descriptive resulfs

All of the 607 people interviewed accepted to reply to valuation questions. This being said however, the proportion of positive WTP's was more important for the good "salubrity"

than for the good "ecosystem" '.75o/o against 49% respectively (table 1). Amongst the nul responses we tried to distinguish between real zero values and protest bids by asking the interviewees the reason for their nul response. Real zero responses corresponded to reasons such as "haven't got the means to pay" or "indifferent to the problem" (no variation in the utility function). The reasons given which permitted us to recognise protest bids are

:

refusal to pay, refusal of the payment vehicle, a fear of paying for others, insufficient information or non-replies. These reasons represent 8, 3, 4, 3 and 1o/o of interviewees respectively for the good "salubrity" and 11, 10,5, 2 and 15o/o of interviewees for the good

"ecosystem". ln all the good "salubrity" generated less protest bids than the good

"ecosystem" : 20Vo against 45o/o. 4.4o/o of interviewees valued "salubrity" at more than FF 500, two of whom valued it at FF 2000. These categories represented respectively 1.6% of interviewees and one person for the good "ecosystem ". The arithmetic mean of the WTP was FF 218for "salubrity" and FF 173for "ecosystem".

Table 1. Descriptive statistics of willingness to pay (n=607) (1)

1 r household per year (2) Protest bids excluded.

The questionnaire also allowed the interviewees to be categorised in order to explain variations in the WTP. Only those variables retained for the construction of models are

THE BENEF|TS oF tMpRovEMENTs tN CoASTAL WATER euALrw : THE CoNTTNGENT AppRoAcH AS APPLTED To BREsr NATUML HARBoUR

Ph. Le Goffe

Amount (2) - (FF) Maximum

Standard deviation Good Mean

Proportion (%) Realzero

values

Protest WTP> O bids

231 210 5

6

20 45

218 173

2000 2000 Salubrity

Ecosystem

75

49

(8)

presented in table 2. Classic socio-economic characteristics such as sex, age, education i.e.

post primary school, revenue (1Qo/o of interviewees refused to reply) and profession turned out to be quite useful. The inte?viewees were asked to indicate their income group out of a possible seventeen ; the data in table 2 were calculated using the central point of these brackets. Our sample contained 6.10/o executives and higher level intellectual professions,

12.7o/o intermediate professions (teachers, technichians) and 5.6% blue collar workers. The importance attached to the preservation of the harbour bay area for leisure activities is one of the criteria used in the survey to measure environmental sensitivity. As far as quality is concerned, those individuals who have already observed the appearance of coloured waters in the bay area (23% of interviewees), are probably more conscient than the others of the problem of water pollution. The practice of recreational activity and the frequenting of the bay area (on average 58 times per year) give an objective view of the use of the good in a global context. 73o/o of those interviewed frequent one or more seaside substitutes. Finally, the risks of asphyxiation of the depths and the payment vehicle (modified during the course of the survey) were incorporated into those models relating to the good "ecosystem".

Table 2. Descriptive statistics of individual characteristics used in demand models

(1) Using midpoints of brackets

THE BENEFITS oF rMpRovEMENTs rN CoASTAL WATER ouALtw : THE CoNTTNGENT AppRoAcH As AppLrED To BREsr NATUML HARBoUR

Ph. Le Goffe

Variable Mean Minimum Maximum Standard

deviation Sex (1=women ; O=men)

Age (years) lncome (FF) (1) Education (years)

Higher professions (1=yes ; O=no) lntermediate professions(1 =yes ; O=no) Blue collarWorkers (1=yes; O=no)

Brest natural harbour preservation (1=very important;

O=somewhat, not very, or not at all important) Observation of coloured waters (1=yes ; O=no)

Brest natural harbour frequenting (times a year) Sailers (1=yes ; O=no)

Divers (1=yes ; O=no)

Seaside substitute (1=yes; 0=no)

Risk of asphyxiation (1=very high ; O=noteworthy or slight) Special fund/housing tax (1 = SF, 0 = HT)

0,493 44,4 10 701

11,1

0,061 0,127 0,056 0,819 0,231 58 0,114 0,048 0,728 0,341 0,727

20 650

6

0

84 50 000

18

365

16,5 7217

3,8

77

(9)

3. THE SCOPE OF THE DEMAND ANALYSIS

The determination of a functional relationship between the WTP and individual characteristics may be useful in enabling the results to be widened to the whole population benefitting from the goods to be valued. lt is desirable to obtain the demand functions from

the utility maximisation. ln the case of a closed question with a yes-no type answer, Hanemann (1984) showed that the probability of accepting a payment was a function of the differences in the utility values (Logit model). This modelisation allows the Logit coefficients to be interpreted using the specification chosen for the utility function. ln the case of an open question with payment card, Bonnieux and Vermersch (1993) developped a dual approach version of the preceeding model by formalising the WTP by a difference in restrained expenditure functions; the WTP is then explained by a Tobit model. This proceedure seemed to be applicable to the goods "salubrity" and "ecosystem".

We note however that for the good "salubrity", the WTP corresponds to a

compensatory variation in well-being i.e. the reduction in revenue agreed to in order to benefit from an increase in the "salubrity" of the water without any modification in utility. On

the other hand, the WTP for the good "ecosystem" measures an equivalent variation in welfare i.e. the payment accepted in order to avoid the deterioration in the ecosystem. This would lead to the same reduction in utility as that provoked by the deterioration in the

ecosystem with constant earnings. The measurement of these hicksian surplusses

necessitates the distinction to be made between those individuals who refuse to place a

monetary value on the goods (protest bids), and those who accept to participate in the exercise of contingent valuation. The latter can equally be divided into two separate categories according to whether they wish or do not wish to see that part of their budget consecrated to the depollution of the harbour bay area rise.

Let Z be the individual expenditure necessary for the provision of water of a given

quality z,z1is the initial level and z2the final level after improvement. We can see that for the first category of individuals there is a positive WTP which expresses an increase in the demand for better water quality (tZ = Z2-Zp0). For the others, the observed WTP is nul.

This corresponds probably to a desire to see that part of their budget consecrated to the depollution of the harbour bay area reduce '. LZ<O. A simple Tobit model then allows us to include this particular category

:

WTPi= 62' if ÂZ;>0

0 otherwise and LZi= x; b + ui

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMENTS IN CoASTAL WATER QUALITY : THE CoNTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATURAL HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

(10)

where xi is the vector of characteristics and ui a random variable.

For each good, this model was estimated on the population not including those individuals having given protest bids. The implicit values of these non-replies are then reconstituted by the model and a mean WTP for the entire population can then be calculated. After unfruitful attempts to carry out a logarithmic transformation or box-cox, we chose the brut WTP as the dependent variable and used a linear equation. ln the case of revenue, the use of a variable equal to the rank of the wage group gave better results than

the use of the midpoints of the brackets in FF, or its logarithm, Amongst the independent variables, age, education, profession and the recreational activity show relationships. ln order to avoid any problems of multicolinearity, these variables are separated into three distinct models. We limited ourselves to retaining only the most significant modalities of profession and recreational activity.

At first it seemed useful to characterise briefly those respondants not having placed a

value on the goods. This was done in an attempt to analyse the interviewees' perception of the contingent valuation scenario. The probability of giving a protest bid was estimated by a Logit model. ln this case the dependent variable is dichotomic. Bonnieux and Vermersch (1993) point out that a generalized Tobit model (Gourieroux, 1989) might allow the simultaneous treatment of protest bids, real nulWTP's and positive WTP's.

4. ESTIMATION RESULTS

Logit models

The prediction of replys and the significance of the coefficients of the Logit model values are on the whole better for the good "ecosystem" (table 3). The probability of making

a protest bid increases with age and revenue, but more rapidly for the good "ecosystem"

than for the good "salubrity". Whatever the good, the probability of a false zero value is weaker amongst women and seems to diminish with education and the frequentation of the

area. Unfortunately the statistical significance of these variables is weak. Environmental sensitivity and substitutes have no significant role and have an opposed sign according to the good considered. Finally the probability of giving a protest bid for the good "ecosystem"

is less strong when the risk of asphyxiation is very high and where the payment vehicle used

is the special fund rather than the local governmenl lax (42o/o against 51% false zeros respectively).

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMENTS IN CoASTAL WATER QUALITY : THE CoNTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATURAL HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

(11)

Table 3. Probability to give protest bids for water quality improvement or preservation : Logit models

Good

Variable Salubrity Ecosystem

Sex Age lncome (1) Education

Brest natural harbour preservation Brest natural harbour frequenting Seaside substitutè

Risk of asphyxiation Spécialfund

-0,205 (-0,e) 0,007 (0,9) 0,030

(0,9) -0,031

(-0,8) -0,030

(-0,1) -0,002 (-1,0) -0,275

(-1 ,1 )

-0,141 (-0,8) 0,021

(3,1) 0,055

(2,1) -0,014

(-0,5) 0,1 95 (0,8) -0,001

(-0,6) 0,229

(1,1) -0,372

(-1,9) -0,312

(-1,6)

Concordant prediction (% 57,3 64,6

(1) Using 17 brackets

Tobit models

Amongst those variables explaining the WTP for the good "salubrity" (table 4), the most significant and the most robust when you pass from one model to another are

:

environmental sensitivity, revenue, the sight of coloured waters and sex. lndividuals for whom the preservation of the harbor bay area is very important accept paying FF 92 to FF 100 more than the others to be able to benefit from the good "salubrity". ln accordance with micro-economic theory, the WTP rises along with revenue : FF 7 to FF 9 per bracket. Having already seen coloured water noticeably increases the WTP "salubrity" : FF 60 to FF 67.

However, this information was gathered during the scenario presented to define the good

"ecosystem". Women, who as we have seen tend to more strongly express their preferences, have a WTP which is inferior to that of men by FF 50 to FF 60.

Age and education are two variables which are negatively linked in our study. They have an opposed but unsignificant effect on the WTP "salubrity". Contrary to what one might have expected, those interviewees who frequent a substitute for the Brest harbour bay are willing to pay FF 56 to FF 68 more than the others. Here we are dealing with a population which is on average younger, better educated and richer, to such a point that we may ask if these variables were sufficiently taken into account by the model. lt is also possible that the relations between the harbour bay area and coastal sites should be analysed more in terms

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMENTS IN CoASTAL WATER QUALIW : THE CoNTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATURAL HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

(12)

of complements than in terms of substitutes. The WTP is also a function of the intensity and of the type of recreational use qrade of the bay area. The WTP rises with regular frequenting (FF 0.16 to FF O.22per day) and is higherforthose who dive or sail : approximately FF 70 more per day than those practising other recreational activities. Lastly it must be said that there is a large calendar effect independant from the others : the WTP is reduced by FF 130 between June and September. This factor has not been taken into account since it is difficult to interprete : is it due to the interviewer, the site, or a real calendar effect linked for example to the events which took place at the time of the survey?

Table 4. wTP for water salubrity improvement : Tobit models (1)

(1) Per per year - (2) Using 17 brackets - population ng reconstituted values.

When comparing the WTP models for the goods "salubrity" and "ecosystem" similar tendencies can be seen especially in relation to the signs of the coefficients of the explanatory variables. This being said, the WTP "ecosystem" is above all influenced by revenue (+FF 10 to FF 13 per bracket) and education (+f,p 11 per school year), with coeff1cients higher than those observed for "salubrity" (table 5). The difference between

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMENTS IN coAsTAL WATER QUALITY : THE CONTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATUML HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

model3 model2

model 1

Variable

-16,6 (-0,3) -55,5 (-2,4)

6,83 (2,2) 4,22 (1,4)

94,3 (3,1) 65,5 (2,4\

0,205 (1,3)

57,2 (2,1)

24,1 (0,7) -0,2 (0,0) 91,6 (3,1) 59,5 (2,2',) 0,1 55 (1,0) 70,5 (1,9) 71,9 (1,3) 58,3 -34,4 14,0 (0,3) -48,7 (-2,0)

7,50 (2,4)

(-0,7) 53,6

(1,0) -61,0 (-2,6) -0,838

(-1,1) 7,96 (2,6)

100,4 (3,3) 66,7 (2,5) 0,220

(1,4)

56,1 (2,1) Constant

Sex Age lncome (2) Education

Higher professions lntermediate professions Blue collar Workers

Brest natural harbour preservation Observation of coloured waters Brest naturel harbour frequenting Sailers

Divers

Seaside substitute

-2 903,0 -2 903,8

-2 899,8 Log likelihood

215 85 215

78 214

80 Mean WTP (FF) (3)

o (FF)

(13)

these two goods is particularly great on education. These revenue and education effects are

to be found at least partially_ at the professional level. ln relation to other categories, executives and intermediate professions agree to a suppliment of FF 100 and FF 58 respectively whilst blue collar workers have a WTP FF 144 less.

In comparison with the WTP "salubrity", the WTP "ecosystem" depends less significantly and with a weaker coefficient, on sex (FF 40 to FF 50), feeling about preservation of the bay area (FF 38 to FF 61), the sight of coloured waters (FF 32 to FF 36)

and on the frequenting of a substitute (FF 28 to FF 38). lt is now independant of the frequentation of the bay area. On the other hand the effects linked to sailing and diving remain. The risk of asphyxiation which reduced the probability of recording a protest bid, has litge or no influence on the WTP. Finally the differences between the payment vehicle (not given in table 5) disappear when the effect of the date is taken into account.

Table 5. WTP for ecosystem preservation against eutrophication : Tobit models (l)

(1) Per household per year - - (3) Whole ng reconstituted values

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMÊNTS IN CoASTAL WATER QUALIw : THE CONTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATURAL HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

Variable model 1 model2 model3

Constant Sex Age lncome (2) Education

Higher professions lntermediate professions Blue collar Workers

Brest natural harbour preservation Observation of coloured waters Brest natural harbour frequenting Sailers

Divers

Seaside substitute Risk of asphyxiation

-1,3 (0,0) -50,9 (-2,2) -0,629

(-0,9) 12,8 (4,3)

61,4 (2,1) 32,4 (1,2) 0,040

(0,2)

38,0 (1,4) 18,8 (0,8)

-138,6 (-2,7) -39,9 (-1,8)

12,3 (4,2) 10,9 (3,8)

47,0 (1,6) 36,1 (1,4) 0,091 (0,6)

25,5 (1,0) 20,9

-5,7 (0,0) 40,4 (-1,7)

10,4 (3,4)

100,5 (2,2) 58,2 (1,8) -143,6

(-2,4) 38,0 (1,3) 35,3 (1,3) -0,011

(0,0) 80,9 (2,4) 66,2 (1,4) 30,3 (1,2) 15,4

Log likelihood -1 841,6 -1840,4 -1 837,4

Mean WTP (FF) (3) o (FF)

162

71

160 81

158

B9

(14)

5. DTSCUSSION - CONCLUSION

Brest natural harbour is an integral part of the resident's environment. They are quite well informed on the problems bf pollution. This explains the relatively good acception of this contingent valuation exercise from the bay area dwellers. We can nevertheless ask ourselves why there exists such a difference in behaviour towards the goods "salubrity" and

"ecosystem". Amongst possible reasons we have to distinguish those treating the measurement methodology, and those which express differences in the utility functions.

The good "ecosystem" provoked more protest bids, especially amongst the elderly.

The corresponding WTP depends essentially on two factors : revenue and education

These results might suggest that there were difficulties surrounding the comprehension of

the scenarios and a good insufficiently familiar to interviewees. Over the past ten years however, the local media have been informing the population about the overenrichment of freshwater in nutrients and occasional accidents with anoxia and deaths of fish. The extension of these phenomonon to saltwaters was quite evident, especially since accidents have already taken place at other points of the Brittany coastline. On the other hand the initial payment vehicle clearly had a negative effect on the revelation of preferences, and we experienced difficulties in redefining a payment vehicle as natural as the water bill for the

first good. We note however that the WTP was unaffected by this change. Another methodological problem arises from the fact that here we have chosen to study two goods simultaneously even though the traditional CVM approach treated goods individually. The part-whole bias which is under question here was studied for goods whose level of agregation was decreasing (Magnussen 1992). lt has been studied little for goods of the same level of aggregation as in our study. Did not the fact that the good "ecosystem" came second after the good "salubrity" perturb the very valuation of the good "ecosystem"?

ln a study on the alternative strategies for the management of a dam on the river Seine, Desaigues and Lesgards (1992) had already sought to disassociate the recreational and the ecological functions of water by estimating two categories of benefits : 1) the benefits drawn from an improvement in the attributes of the ecosystem, 2) the benefits to be drawn from an improvement in possible recreational uses. Moreover, these authors had assimilated the ecological benefits to an existence value and the recreational benefits to a

use value. Without going as far as that, is is probable that our good "ecosystem" is proportionally more valued for motives of existence than the good "salubrity". lt is worth noting that the WTP "ecosystem" is independant of the frequentation of the bay area .

THE BENEFTTS oF tMpRovEMENTs tN coAsrAL WATER euALrw : THE CoNTTNGENT AppRoAcH AS APPLTED To BREsr NATURAL HARBoUR

Ph. Le Goffe

(15)

Everything happens as if the good "ecosystem" were a luxury which only those disposing of sufficient means and a good level of education could offer themselves. Finally, the uncertain

character of the supply of ùe good "ecosystem" has weighed on the revelation of preferences which improve whilst the risk of the harbour waters asphyxiating rises. On the other hand and contrary to Edwards (1989), the option price does not depend on the risk of asphyxiation.

Other approaches or methods have been used to evaluate the non-market damage resulting from the eutrophication of coastal waters. Magnussen (1992) also used the CVM model to estimate the value of a 50% reduction in the output of nutrients : nitrogen and phosphor into the north sea. To do this, she distributed cards to interviewees showing the evolution of overall water quality and the corresponding uses, before and after reductions in outputs of these nutrients. ln addition to metric bias which is always possible, the risk here is

of using figures for water quality which are too global and do not take into account the specifïcity of the eutrophication phenonomon e.g. threshold effects. Bockstael et al (1989) used the travel cost method indexing the demand to the total production of nitrogen and of phosphor. They then calculated the variation in surplus corresponding to a 20o/o drop in nutrient production. This approach does not take into account threshold effects. Moreover it gives an equal importance to nitrogen and phosphor, although it would seem that marine eutrophication is more dependant on nitrogen. This approach could not be used in the case of Brest, notably because of the abscence of spacial or temporal time series data indicating

a sufficient variation in transport costs, visits and water quality. This is why we retained a

scenario of eutrophication sufficiently extreme so as to seriously affect the services provided by the bay area whilst still remaining within the realms of the probable. When compared to previous studies, one of the inconveniences of our approach is that the scientific knowledge concerning the bay area is to this day insufficient to establish any relationship between the outputs of nutrients and the acute phenonomons of eutrophication, and therefore between the polluting outputs and the damage. One of the scientific programmes planned under the bay contract aims to establish this physical relationship.

The onsite enquiry technique used in this study lead to the selection of a population of recreational space users. This population is not necessarily representative of the total population susceptible to benefit from the goods to be valued. Contingent valuations made by telephone surveys, postal surveys or house to house surveys where the sample is drawn

at random would allow us to reduce this sample bias. However, due to the only recent beginnings of contingent valuation in France, there are no data on their acceptance by the

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMENTS IN CoASTAL WATER QUALITY : THE CoNTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATURAL HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

(16)

french public. lt therefore seemed more sure to begin by gathering data directly from the recreational sites themselves. This choice will make it more difficult to agregate the benefits to the entire population. Nevertheless redressment procedures may be used, especially from previous data surrounding the practice of recreational activities in Brest according to socioprofessional brackets.

ln all, individuals accepted paying quite substiantial amounts to see better water quality in the bay. The average reconstructed WTP was FF 215 and FF 160 respectively for the goods "salubrity" and "ecosystem". The WTP "salubrity" represents 10o/o of the annual

water bill. These amounts are less than those obtained by Bockstael et al (1989) for Chesapeake bay (here the WTP for swimmable water corresponded to FF 350 in 1987) and especially than those obtained by Magnussen (1992) for a national good (FF 1000 in 1991

for a 50% reduction in nutrients). But our flgures are two to three times higher than the WTP's estimated by Desaigues and Lesgards (1992) for goods which are admittedly different, but within the French context. We may ask ourselves if our values haven't been circumstantially increased by the events which took place just before the start of our survey.

ln a context of benefit aggregation it might be reasonable to reduce their importance so as to smooth this accidentaleffect.

REFERENCES

AMIGUES J. P., BONNIEUX F., LE GOFFE Ph., POINT P., 1993. Bénéfices potentiels d'une amélioration de Ia qualité des eaux continentales. Rapport Ministère de l'Environnement, Direction de I'eau, 111 p.

BOCKSTAEL N.E., MCCONNEL K.E., STMND LE., 1989 Measuring the benefits of improvements in water quality:The Chesapeake bay. Marine Resource Economics

6: 1-18.

BONNIEUX F., DESAIGUES 8., VERMERSCH D., 1992.France. ln NAVRUD S. (ed.):

Pricing the european environmenf, Scandinavian University Press, Oslo : 45-64.

BONNIEUX F., VERMERSCH D., 1993. Bénéfices et coÛts de la protection de I'eau : application de I'approche contingente à la pêche sportive. Revue d'Economie Politique 103 : 131-152.

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMENTS IN ooASTAL WATER QUALITY : THE CoNTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATUML HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

(17)

CUMMINGS R. G., BROOKSHIRE D. S., SCHULZE W. D., (Eds), 1986. Valuing environmentat goods.' an assessment of the contingent valuation method. Rowman and Allanheld, Totowa, N. J.

DESAIGUES 8., LESGARDS V., 1992. L'évaluation contingente des actifs naturels: un exemple d'application. Revue d'Economie Politique 1Q2 : 99-122.

EDWARDS S. F., 1988. Option Prices for Groundwater Protection. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 15 : 47 5-487

.

FREEMAN A. M., 1990. Water pottution poticy.ln PORTNEY P. E. (Ed.) ; Public policies for environmental protecfion, Resources for the future, Washington : 97 -1 49.

GOURIEROUX C., 1989. Econométrie des variables qualitatives. Paris, Economica.

HANEMANN W.M., 1984. Welfare evaluation in contingent valuation experiments with discrete responses. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 66 : 332-341.

MAGNUSSEN, 1992. Valuing reduced water pollution using the contingent valuation method

- Testing for amenity misspecification. ln NAVRUD S.(ed.) : Pricing the european environmenf. Scandinavian University Press, Oslo :195-230.

MITCHELL R. C., CARSON R. T., 1981 . An experiment in determining willingness to pay for nationalwater quatity improvemenfs. Draft report to the US Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, D-C.

MITCHELL R. C., CARSON R. T., 1984. A contingent valuation estimate of national freshwater benefits. Technical report to the US Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, DC, Resources for the Future.

MITCHELL R. C., CARSON R. T., 1989. IJsing surueys to value public goods: the contingent valuation method. Resources for the future, Washington D.C., Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.

NAVRUD S., STRAND J., 1992. Norway. ln NAVRUD S. (ed.) : Pricing the european environmenf. Scandinavian University Press, Oslo : 108-135.

SMITH V. K., DESVOUSGES W. H., 1986. Measuring Water Quality Benefits. Kluwer-Nijhoff Publishing, Boston.

VERMERSCH D., BONNIEUX F., RAINELLI P., 1991 Can we expect abatement of agricultural pollution using economic incentives ? The case of intensive livestock

farming in France. Second Annual Meeting of the European Association of Environmental and Resource Economics, Stockholm, June 11-14,1991'

WALSH R. G., JOHNSON D. M., McKEAN J. R., 1992. Benefit transfer of outdoor recreation demand studies, 1968-1 988. Water Resources Research 28 :707-713.

THE BENEFITS oF IMPRoVEMENTS IN CoASTAL WATER QUALITY : THE CONTINGENT APPROACH AS APPLIED TO BREST NATUML HARBOUR

Ph. Le Goffe

Références

Documents relatifs

The questionnaire used in the survey included four sections: 1 source of drinking water for the household; 2 opinions about the domestic water supply and quality; 3 willingness to

In fact, the large majority of bids for improved quality come from rural households having access to river or collective taps, whereas only 14% of private tap users, mainly in

The speed of convergence to the Gaussian chaos in (ii) is studied by Peccati and Th¨ale [21] in case the limit is a Gamma distributed random variable.. 2.1.3

Evolutionary history of the weedy populations: multiple introduction events, dispersal and crop-weed gene flow The structure of genetic diversity within and between weedy

is the mass of water vapor per unit volume of gaseous phase, and vi. is the velo ity of

Figure 2.5 illustrates this in greater statistical significance as it displays the distribution of grain boundary misorientation angle for the sample. It then shows the

In what follows we will give only few details about the overall obstacle avoidance algorithm in order to focus the attention only around the proposed mechanisms of control which

Les résultats obtenus sont reportés dans le tableau IV.4 et en annexe 8, et présentés dans la figure IV.14 Les résultats montrent une grande variation de la solubilité du