• Aucun résultat trouvé

PART III PRICE AND NON-PRICE STRATEGIES III.4 ADVERTISING

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "PART III PRICE AND NON-PRICE STRATEGIES III.4 ADVERTISING"

Copied!
22
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

PART III PRICE AND NON-PRICE STRATEGIES

III.4 ADVERTISING

(2)

Examples

Pharmaceutical sector

- Similar expenses in marketing activities and in R&D - Necessary marketing expenses? Wasteful?

Soft drinks

- Price competition plays a secondary role wrt advertising competition

In this chapter

- Advertising is considered with a strategic perspective

(3)

III.4.1 INFORMATION, PERSUASION, SIGNALING

To analyze the possible effects of advertising, classify goods in 3 categories:

- Search goods (PC)

- Experience goods (restaurants) - Credence goods (medical services)

Classify advertising activities:

- Informative advertising (information about characteristics) - Persuasive advertising (to influence consumers’ preferences)

(4)

Links:

- Informative advertising mainly associated with search goods

- Empirical evidence: advertising/sales ratio is 3x higher for experience goods than it is for search goods

Social value of advertising?

- Is informative advertising the only one with social value?

- Look for efficiency arguments

(5)

Signaling

- Persuasive advertising can be considered as an indirect informative advertising for some experience goods

- Example: Ford, Diet Coke at launch

- At launch, we have very little information - We only know that advertising is expensive

(6)

Signaling

- Advertising expenditure can signal quality - Ingredients:

! dynamic perspective (does not work for one-period goods)

! Experience goods (no information about the quality, the characteristics) - Signaling theory:

! Averse selection

! Market failure

! Signaling

! Credibility, interpretation of signals

! Signals expensive enough, not too much

(7)

III.4.2 ADVERTISING INTENSITY

- To measure advertising intensity, compute a/R, where a are the advertising expenses and R is the revenue from sales.

- Examples:

! In the salt industry, a/R is of the order of 0% to 0.5%

! For breakfast cereals, it is between 8% and 13% (Sutton’s estimates)

- How do we explain such differences?

(8)

Factor 1: Demand elasticity w.r.t. advertising

- Consider the following demand: D(a, p)

- Define demand elasticity w.r.t. advertising as

η

=

D(a, p)

a

a D(a, p)

- Some markets are more sentitive/reactive to variations in advertising than others.

(9)

p   p  

q   q  

Low  η   High  η  

(10)

Factor 2: Demand elasticity w.r.t. price

- Consider the following demand: D(a, p) - Define demand elasticity w.r.t. price as

ε

=

D(a, p)

p

p D(a, p)

- Some markets are more sentitive/reactive to variations in prices than others.

- Advertising is more effective in markets with a low price elasticity of demand because prices are generally higher in such markets.

(11)

p   p  

q   q  

Low  ε   High  ε  

Also,  ads  can  decrease  the   price  elasticity  of  demand  

(12)

Formally

A monopoly:

Maxp,a Π =(pc)D(p,a)− a

FOC w.r.t. p implies the inverse elasticity rule

pc

p = 1

ε

FOC w.r.t. a implies

a

R = pc p

η

(13)

Combining both FOC, we obtain the Dorfman-Steiner formula:

a

R =

η ε

- Advertising intensity increases with η and decreases with ε.

- Empirical support

(14)

Factor 3: Market structure

Higher advertising intensity in concentrated markets or in more competitive markets?

How do ε and η vary with the number of firms, n?

(15)

- ε increases with the number of firms, n

! By decreasing its price, a firm not only increases total demand, but also its market share.

! The second effect is greater for smaller firms.

! Therefore, price elasticity of demand is higher in markets with many small firms.

! Advertising intensity is therefore lower in markets with many firms.

(16)

- How does η vary with the number of firms, n?

2 extreme cases

1. If advertising increase the demand for all firms equally

! Examples: milk, diamonds

! Advertising = public good

! The higher n, the more we share the benefits from advertising

! η decreases with the number of firms, n

! Less incentives to invest in advertising when n is high

! Example: Diamonds (distribution by DeBeers vs Russian producers)

(17)

2. The total demand is given, only market shares vary (Hotelling)

! Examples: pharmaceuticals

! Effect of ads: consumers switch from brand-name drugs to generics

! In a monopoly, η = 0

! In a duopoly, η > 0

! In a concentrated market, η increases with the number of firms, n

! More incentives to invest in advertising when n increases

(18)

To sum up, as n increases, we have 3 effects:

- markets shares are lower, ε is higher, a/R decrease

- Each firm captures a smaller share of the positive effect of advertising - Hotelling

" The total effect is ambiguous.

Empirically:

- For high initial n, advertising intensity decreases with n - For low initial n, advertising intensity increases with n

(19)

III.4.3 PRICE COMPETITION AND ADVERTISING

Interactions between the advertising strategies of competing firms.

- Prisonners dilemma for advertising expenses (as for price setting)

- If total demand is constant (Hotelling), each firm engages in advertising until profits are zero

- Idem Bertrand competition

- This result on advertising can be nuanced in the same way as the Bertrand results - Example: repeated interactions can decrease such wasteful advertising activities.

(20)

Collusion and advertising strategies

- Different timing between advertising strategies and price strategies:

! Decisions: frequent for prices, less frequent for advertising

! Effects: short-term for prices, long-term for advertising

! Time-discount factor likely to be lower for advertising activities

! A collusive agreement on advertising activities is more difficult to sustain than one on prices

(21)

Interaction between price competition and advertising competition

- Advertising can soften price competition

! Generally, persuasive advertising increases product differentiation

! Therefore, it softens price competition

! Not only is advertising wasteful, but it is also anti-competitive

! But, how do we compare total surplus with and without advertising if consumer preferences vary?

! Moreover, adbertising increases the quantities exchanges, which argues in favor of advertising, even persuasive

(22)

- Advertising can intensify price competition

! Informative advertising on prices decreases search costs

! Therefore, price competition intensifies

! But then, why would firm invest in such informative advertising?

! Prisonners dilemma again?

Références

Documents relatifs

À  s’attacher  plus  précisément  au  niveau  de  la  composition  des 

Lors de la création de la liste de choix, Access crée une relation entre la table ouverte et la table utilisée pour générer les valeurs de la liste de choix ; dans cet exemple

il y a beaucoup plus qui entre en jeu, je trouve maintenant, que dans la pub traditionnelle il y a 20-30 ans et c’est là pour moi, en termes d’image parfois ça peut être utile

An in-depth study of the 40 fish markets in France (LEN-Corrail 2007) complemented by both a phone survey of 6 auction managers in June 2007 and qualitative

For a price-linear demand function, the impact of higher temperature on price and adver- tising depends on the type (hot or cold) of

Publié avec l’aide du PRIN 2012 (Italie): «Tradurre, tradire, traman- dare: i padri greci nell’occidente latino e nell’oriente siriaco» et de la chaire «Kirchen-

Indeed, a clinical cure rate of 100% was obtained with amoxicillin and cefquinome in animals expressing clinical signs of infection and with bacterial loads exceed- ing 10 6

Figure 3 shows the evolution of the differential transient absorption signal D OD measured after excitation with 500 nm at the probe wavelength 5460 nm (1835 cm 1 ) corresponding to