• Aucun résultat trouvé

Collective action and allocation of decision rights in pesticide safety risk management: the case of tomato producer organizations in France

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "Collective action and allocation of decision rights in pesticide safety risk management: the case of tomato producer organizations in France"

Copied!
17
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

HAL Id: hal-02748504

https://hal.inrae.fr/hal-02748504

Submitted on 3 Jun 2020

HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access

archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci-entific research documents, whether they are pub-lished or not. The documents may come from teaching and research institutions in France or abroad, or from public or private research centers.

L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires publics ou privés.

Collective action and allocation of decision rights in

pesticide safety risk management: the case of tomato

producer organizations in France

Jean Marie Codron, Zouhair Bouhsina, Laure Bonnaud

To cite this version:

Jean Marie Codron, Zouhair Bouhsina, Laure Bonnaud. Collective action and allocation of decision rights in pesticide safety risk management: the case of tomato producer organizations in France. 7. Journées de Recherches en Sciences Sociales, Société Française d’Economie Rurale (SFER). Paris, FRA.; Center for Organization Studies (CORS). Sao Paulo, BRA.; European Association of Agricul-tural Economists (EAAE). INT., Dec 2013, Angers, France. 15 p. �hal-02748504�

(2)

Collective action and allocation of decision rights in pesticide safety risk

management: the case of tomato producer organizations in France

Jean Marie Codron1, Zouhair Bouhsina1, and Laure Bonnaud2 1INRA, UMR1110 MOISA, F-34000 Montpellier, France

2INRA, UR Ritme, F-75 Ivry sur Seine, France

Abstract  

Pesticide safety management at the production/shipping level is a costly transaction between a farmer and a buyer. Within the safety-demanding global market, a frequent solution adopted to comply with end customer requirements is to allocate monitoring and decision rights to the shipper. Our paper aims to explain how and why farmers who are members of Producer Organizations (POs) allocate monitoring and decision rights to their managers to manage pesticide safety risks. It also distinguishes the two types of control rights (over the product and over the production process) which define a safety management strategy. Drawing on the scant empirical literature on the transfer of property rights within incomplete contracts (Arrunada et al, 2001; Hu and Hendrikse, 2009), it tests for the predictions of the theory, putting forward as main independent variables group size, reputation, customer safety demands and asset specificity. To this end, twenty POs accounting for more than 95% of French tomato production with market organization have been surveyed. Our results confirm most of the predictions, namely that the allocation of control rights increases with commercial reputation, customer safety demands and IPM technical assistance (asset specificity). Moreover, we show that the two types of control are substitutes and complementary. On the one hand, POs focus either on product control or process control while on the other hand, both controls are necessary for POs with a good reputation and demanding customers.

JEL:    

incomplete   contracts,   property   rights,   allocation   of   property   rights,   safety,   product   control,  process  control,  tomato,  Producer  Organizations  or  marketing  groups,  France  

(3)

Collective action and allocation of decision rights in pesticide safety risk

management: the case of tomato producer organizations in France

     

1.  Introduction  

The stringent demands of customers in terms of pesticide safety lead suppliers to intervene more decisively in managing the safety risk at the production level. Nowadays, such involvement is not only required by European regulations which make in-house control obligatory at every level of the chain, is also highly motivated by the commercial risk of failing to comply with buyers' individual requirements (Bignebat and Codron, 2006).

A crucial level of managing the safety risk is at the production/shipping level. While the former level is broadly documented in empirical literature, the latter remains an emerging issue (Aubert et al, 2013). Empirically, buyers facing stringent safety requirements do not limit their control to the product itself (pesticide residue analysis at the platform level) but are also involved in controlling the production process (monitoring and often taking decisions with regard to certain production practices). While buyers' management practices usually combine both kinds of control, there is no easy hierarchy that may be established between buyers who prefer to focus control over the product and those who prefer to focus control over the production process (Bouhsina et al, 2009; Bonnaud et al, 2012a, b).

The aim of this paper is to offer an insight into how buyers manage safety with their suppliers and how buyers' characteristics may influence this organization. We maintain that buyers may choose to focus their control more on the product or more on the production process. To explain such a strategic choice of control, we will draw on the transactional and "contract design" literature and focus on the main variables usually identified as a major factor of influence on vertical integration, namely asset specificity, the level of customer safety requirements and – since our buyer is a marketing group – the size of the group and the collective commercial reputation at stake. As we are dealing with the management or governance of the safety risk, vertical integration will be approximated by the nature and the intensity of buyer control.

Our paper is organized as follows. Section 2 develops our theoretical framework, based mainly on a Transaction Cost approach to contract design and the allocation of property rights. Section 3 sets the stage, describes the groups and their main characteristics and presents both our methodology and the data collected while throwing light on the choice of variables allowing both types of control to be represented together with their contribution to the management of safety risk. Section 4 tests for the hypotheses based on the theory that allows both types of control and their interaction to be explained and comments on the findings. Section 5 concludes by emphasizing how both types of control are influenced by the factors put forward in the literature (reputation, safety objectives, asset specificity and group size) and how they combine to determine a strategy for managing the safety risk.

(4)

2.  Analytical  framework  

2.1  The  grower-­‐PO  relationship  and  the  nature  of  transaction  costs  

Transaction costs are central to the choice of control strategy. They basically derive from an agency issue where the goals of the farmer (maximizing yield and quality) may conflict with the goals of the buyer (compliance with the safety rules) and where deviant behavior is difficult to detect given the strong exogenous hazards. Farmers   may   thus   be   reluctant   to   reveal   information   or   to   produce   information   that   may   be   useful   to   the   buyer   with   regard   to   safety   management.   For   instance,   a   farmer   may   prefer   to   use   a   forbidden   pesticide  which  is  cheaper  and  may  have  a  stronger  impact  on  the  pest  but  which  is  not   accepted   by   the   buyer   for   regulatory   or   customer-­‐related   reasons.   To   reduce   such   agency  costs,  buyers  may  choose  to  focus  their  control  on  the  product  or  the  production   process.

Controlling the product generates measurement costs which may prove prohibitive if applied to all products delivered by the growers. This leads buyers to use sampling and penalties to enforce compliance with safety requirements. However, given the complex production function and the high level of environmental uncertainty, it is difficult to distinguish between a grower's effort and hazard and thus to draft a complete contract and determine the optimal sanction which could lead a grower to make the “utmost effort” required by the buyer (Soubeyran et al.). Consequently, most buyers are encouraged to draft incomplete contracts and to monitor growers’ efforts in the production process.

Control over the production process means high transaction costs due mainly to uncertainty and asset specificity. Uncertainty derives from the complexity of the production function and the difficulty in evaluating the right decision (Codron et al, 2013) for some key pest and disease management activities. Decisions  concerning  activities  such  as  chemical  spreading   or  the  introduction  of  biological  auxiliaries  are  so  complex  and  contingent  on  fluctuating   parameters  which  have  to  be  measured  at  the  last  moment,  that  they  cannot  be  defined   ex-­‐ante   and   have   to   be   taken   at   short   notice.   Such uncertainty is also observed in the literature as ease of measurement (Williamson, 1991), difficulty of measurement (Barzel, 1982), non-separability (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972) or task programmability (Eisenhardt, 1985). Allocation of monitoring and decision rights to the party best informed (Barzel, 1989) allows such uncertainty to be reduced but, at the same time, creates new transaction costs, referred to by Barzel (2005) as “errors of measurement” and related to the possible manipulation of information by the party which has been allocated control and decision rights.

Asset specificity is mainly embodied by the human resources that the buyer invests to perform his control over the production process. Most buyers recruit technicians with some knowledge of IPM to recommend or impose actions to be taken by the grower. Given the exogenous uncertainty and the difficulty in monitoring the grower, there is potential for grower opportunism and a risk of poor efficiency of the technician. Drawing on the literature on the allocation of property rights (Barzel, 1989; Arrunada et al, 2003) and asset specificity (Williamson, 1991), the risk of maladaptation or abusive appropriation of the quasi-organizational rent created in the grower-buyer transaction increases with uncertainty or measuring difficulty, asset specificity and the level of safety that is targeted by the buyer.

(5)

A third class of transaction costs exists in our case study. They derive from the nature of the buyers who are marketing groups of growers who delegate authority to managers (Bijman, 2007; Ménard, 2012). The transfer of decision rights is primarily concerned with product commercialization but may extend to the production process in order to improve product commercialization and help build a group reputation or a collective brand. In this paper, we limit the scope of our analysis to the governance mechanisms and their application for safety purposes. First, although marketing groups may differ considerably in their governance structure (Sykuta and Cook, 2001; Chaddad and Iliopoulos, 2013), we consider that, with regard to safety management, differences in governance mechanisms are much greater than differences in governance structures. A major reason behind this is that most of the groups1 are of the cooperative type (17/20), were created to benefit from EU subsidies and demonstrate few differences in decision-making processes concerning internal safety rules; however they differ considerably in the content or intensity of their control over the product or the production process.

Second, we consider that the delegation of authority for safety purposes is representative of the general delegation of authority and captures most of the transaction costs linked to the marketing of the product on behalf of the growers. In particular, while commercial quality (size, taste, packaging, etc.) may be easily measured and rewarded at the platform level where growers deliver their products, it is more difficult to measure safety along the customer requirements, either on the product or in the process of production. Consequently, except for the penalties that may punish a safety-deviant grower, there is no other incentive that may reward safety performance. Products eligible to be sold to safety-demanding customers are not given a premium while products with residue excesses due to exogenous hazards are not punished and receive the same price as compliant products.

In addition to the control costs previously mentioned, safety-specific transaction costs generated by collective action within the marketing group include exclusion costs or costs to protect the collective good from free riding. In the case of a marketing group, the dominant collective good is the collective brand or the commercial reputation of the group. Of course, traceability helps identify the defaulting grower and alleviate the responsibility of the group. However, it does not totally exonerate the group which is deemed responsible for grower control, must justify such a flaw and may suffer damage to its commercial reputation. Consequently, we can expect that the delegation of authority, which helps reduce transaction costs, will increase with the size of the group and the commercial reputation. This is in line with the emerging literature on contract design focusing on the allocation of control/decision rights (Arrunada et al, 2003; Hu and Hendrikse, 2009; Aubert et al, 2013).

2.2  Contractual  design  and  governance  mechanisms  

When transactions feature high uncertainty and contractual hazards, incomplete contracts with delegation of authority for some strategic decision rights are a frequent solution. As highlighted by Baker et al (2006) who build on the Property Right framework (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972; Grossman and Hart; 1986), this contractual transfer of decision rights                                                                                                                

1  Let us note, however, a significant difference in governance structure which exists for groups having entered a

superstructure to benefit from economies of scale, in particular regarding marketing, commercialisation and technical services. While the existence of such a superstructure tends to rule and homogeneize the decision-making processes of the elementary marketing groups and thus the elementary governance structures, there are still significant differences in the safety control mechanisms. This is particularly true of the production process which is mostly regulated by the elementary marketing groups, even though the superstructure offers some technical strategic orientation.  

(6)

concerning assets does not require ownership over these assets. Authority over the subset of decision rights that have been transferred by contract is based on mutual consent, differs from the hierarchical relationship within a firm and maintains symmetry between partners (Menard, 2012). Barzel (1989) predicts that decision rights should be transferred to the party with more information or expertise. In our case, it is the buyer who has better information than the producer concerning customer safety requirements and who hires skilled technicians who are usually more effective than the grower or his technical manager.

Incomplete contracts between buyers and sellers consist of contractible and non-contractible clauses. The former are legally binding while the latter have to be enforced by private ordering. Delegation of authority is a type of private ordering and may be included in what we call “non-contractible clauses”. While contractible clauses are defined ex-ante and may be written with precision, delegation of authority only specifies the seller’s obligations and grants buyers the right to monitor the seller and to decide the actions to be taken by the seller in the future.

Drawing on Arrunada et al (2001) and Hu and Hendrikse (2009), we focus on the details of the control/decision rights that have been transferred to one of the parties in order to measure and explain the degree of delegation of authority. Different classes of Property Rights have been distinguished by these scholars. Arrunada et al, make a distinction between monitoring, completion and termination rights while Hu and Hendrikse differentiate input control, in-process control, after-in-process control, monitoring rights and termination rights. In our safety context, the major actions pursued by firms to manage pesticide safety are product control and process control while termination rights are very scarce in Producer Organizations due to their cooperative status.

Product control is achieved by deciding how many multi-residue analyses are to be performed during the campaign, the sampling protocol and the system of punishment in the event of deviant behavior. The sampling protocol includes the sampling methods (at random or targeting suspicious growers), the frequency of analysis per producer (yearly or less often) and the participation of the technician in charge of monitoring the growers’ safety practices (whether or not the technician is informed about the analysis results and/or involved in control planning). The system of punishment is often informal and applies to producers who have been caught with excess residues (above the Maximum Residue Limit) or with traces of forbidden molecules and have been acknowledged as fully responsible for such results. While some POs never use penalties, most of them downgrade the product into a lower commercial category and apply the sanction until a new analysis, which may or may not be paid for by the grower, proves compliance with the rules again. In a few cases, financial penalties that are formally decided, add to the previous ones. The system of penalties may be strengthened by giving an advantage or not to growers revealing ex-ante an incorrect chemical spreading behavior or by organizing collective information about individual deviant behavior.

Process control first includes gathering relevant information on growers’ IPM practices to better manage safety at the PO level, either when controlling the product or when upgrading IPM practices. As a result, POs collect grower crop sheets which may only contain the minimum standard information about chemical spreading or additional information about other IPM practices. PO control over such information is not automatic or may be restricted to checking compliance with public safety regulations. In a few cases, it contributes to better management of pests and disease. In some POs, such information may be entered in a computer network under PO supervision allowing information to be centralized providing the

(7)

PO staff in charge of managing safety at the PO level (director, quality manager, IPM technician) with easy access. Process control also includes formal and informal procedures that facilitate a better flow of information between the quality manager and the IPM technician regarding residue management and prevention. Finally, process control includes the field visits of the quality manager which help him to better anticipate the output, in particular with regard to safety.

 

It is worth distinguishing product control and process control from a contractual point of view. While globally, most of the important safety decisions are not contractible due to their complexity and measurement difficulties, there are significant differences between the two types of control, control over the product displaying less delegation of authority. As a matter of fact, most actions concerning control over the product (number of residue analysis, sampling protocols or penalties for defaulting growers) can be formally written in the contract as they may be decided ex-ante. However, due to uncertainty and contractual hazards, a number of these actions have to be adjusted ex-post (such as increasing the number of residue analyses to check some ambiguous results or to comply with a last-minute customer demand) and enforced through costly interpretation procedures (to decide whether or not a grower defaulted intentionally or due to exogenous hazards). Buyers and sellers are thus led to leave blanks in the contract and room for the delegation of authority. In the case of a control over the process of production, some actions may be decided ex-ante like the use of resistant varieties or Good Agricultural Practice certificates but the bulk of the crucial actions have to be implemented at short notice taking account of a host of parameters and thus decided by the party with more expertise, as predicted in theory.

Another significant difference between the two types of control is the level of embeddedness or path-dependency: while the actions supporting control over the product may be implemented rapidly, easily modified according to the context and enforced through a system of penalties, the actions facilitating control over the production process must be part of a sustainable and long-term process of IPM education and training of the farmers in which pedagogy and assistance are much more effective tools than monetary penalties. Consequently, we can expect PO’s with a high quality and safety strategy to use a higher proportion of control over the production process.

2.3  Hypothesis  

Within this framework, we can predict that the delegation of safety control in the marketing group will increase with the level of safety targeted by the group (Raynaud et al, 2009), commercial reputation, asset specificity and group size (Hu and Hendrikse, 2009). We therefore expect PO managers to be allocated more rights to decide and monitor the behavior of farmers in larger groups, in groups with a high commercial reputation, in groups targeting safety-demanding customers and in groups with high safety-specific investments. The four variables impacting the transfer of property rights are highly concerned with safety management and are the result of strategic choices made by the group. Our empirical work aims to explain the two observed types of control implemented by the groups as a consequence of these strategic choices.

We consider that our prediction is true whatever the type of control (over the product or over the production process) and whatever the tools implemented to organize the control over the product (pressure of analysis, sampling methods and sanctions). However, it remains unclear what exactly determines the trade-off between the two controls. We will test for

(8)

complementarity and substitutability of the two controls, echoing Arrunada et al (2003). In line with the theoretical predictions, we have identified and documented, for each PO, the following proxies for each of the four categories of explanatory variables: group size, group reputation, safety demand and asset specificity. Group size is measured by the number of tomato growers in the PO while the reputation of the group is approximated by three variables: the existence of an association of POs with a collective brand, the average value per kilo obtained by a PO during the year (total value/total production), and the level of segmentation measured by the percentage of “non-standard” tomatoes (small tomatoes, old varieties). Quality/safety targeted by the group is approximated by three variables: the existence of customers in the UK, market share of the fast food industry and the existence of specific safety requirements in terms of pesticide residues. Two proxies were finally selected to represent asset specificity: the quality manager's profile and the IPM technician’s profile: the former was defined by the level of professional education and the number of years’ experience in this activity while the latter was characterized by his level of IPM implication: strong involvement for technicians hired by the PO and fully dedicated to IPM, medium involvement for technicians hired by the PO and sharing their time between IPM and general technical assistance, low involvement when no technician has been hired.

3.  Data  and  methodology    

Twenty POs (out of twenty two POs existing in France in 2010) were surveyed, accounting for more than 95% of tomato production with market organization and more than 70% of total French production (not including production for self consumption). Data were collected through closed questionnaires and qualitative face-to-face interviews. The questionnaires considered three series of PO items : i) structures and marketing; ii) pesticide residue controls and penalties in case of non-compliance with PO rules; and iii) grower production practices and how the latter are managed/monitored by the PO. Face-to-face interviews were conducted with the PO Director, the Quality Manager and the IPM Technician, if existing.

Table  1:  Structures  and  marketing  characteristics  of  Tomato  Producer  Organizations  (2010)  

Minimum Maximum Average

Producers 1 94 21,5

Tomato Surface Area (ha) 2 191 38,3

Tomato Production (tons) 186 72000 14180

Tomato Turnover (103 €) 340 124000 16700

Export (%) 0 20 3

Source:  our  survey  

A data base of 113 variables (90 from the closed questionnaire and 23 from the face-to-face interviews) was established. 22 variables out of the 113 were considered of potential interest for the analysis. After testing for non-dependency/correlation, 19 variables (9 independent variables and 10 dependent variables) were finally retained for analysis. From table 1, we can see that an  average  profile  of  the  POs  under  scrutiny  at  the  time  of  our  survey  could  be   characterized  as  follows:  21  farmers  with  a  total  greenhouse  area  of  38  ha  (that  is  more   or  less  2  ha  per  grower)  and  producing  14,200  tons  of  tomatoes.  The  figures  in  table  1   also  show  a  wide  dispersion  of  those  characteristics.  For  instance  the  ratio  between  the   size  of  the  smallest  PO  and  the  biggest  is  1  to  94  for  the  number  of  producers,  1  to  100   for  the  greenhouse  area  and  1  to  360  for  tomato  production,  while  the  marketing  ratios   range  from  70%  to  100%  for  tomato  diversification  (cherries  and  cocktail  tomatoes,  old  

(9)

varieties),   from   0   %   to   20   %   for   the   share   of   total   volume   exported   and   from   0%   to   about  25  %  for  the  share  of  total  volume  sold  to  the  fast  food  industry.

 

Table  2:  Statistics  concerning  the  independent  variables   Group Size Number of tomato producers within the group

Min: 1 Max: 94 Mean: 21.5 Level of customer safety requirements Existence of customer specific requirements Yes: 6 POs No: 14 POs Export to UK customers Yes: 4 POs No: 16 POs Share of the fast food industry (%) Min: 0 Max: 23 Mean: 2 Commercial Reputation Membership in a commercial superstructure with collective brand Yes: 11 POs No: 9 POs Level of tomato valuation (€/kg) Min: 0.70 Max: 2.32 Mean: 1.47 Tomato segmentation (% of cherries, cocktail tomatoes and old varieties in total volume) Min: 0 Max: 68 Mean: 13 Specific Assets Type of technician: contractual status and degree of concern for IPM Independent with grower contract: 3

Independent with PO contract: 2

Employee with partial IPM dedication: 8

Employee with full IPM dedication: 7

Type of quality manager (QM): specialized education background and experience No employee with full dedication to quality management: 4

Low skills: no specialized education and low experience: 4

High skills: specialized education and/or high experience: 12 Table  3:  Statistics  of  the  dependent  variables   Control over the product Pressure of analysis (tons/analysis) Min: 141 Max: 5,500 Mean: 842 Sanctions Type of penalty No sanction: 1

(a) Cost of additional analysis paid by the grower: 1

(b) Downgrading or no commercialization under PO brand: 11

(c) = (a) + (b) : 4

(d) = (c) + payment of a fine: 3

Incentives for grower transparency concerning deviant practices (lower penalty) No: 15 Yes: 5

Communication of individual residues analysis results at the collective level No: 7

Yes: 13

Control procedures Grower sampling for residue analysis At random: 3

Targeting suspicious ones: 17

At least one analysis per grower per year Yes: 12

No: 8

Information on the results of the residue analysis and/or association of the IPM technician to control planning adjustments No information: 11

Information: 5

Information and association: 4

Control over the practices Crop sheets management (*) Type of control No control: 1

Control to verify adequation of pesticide use to the rules: 9

Control with the additional aim of improving IPM practices: 3

Control with the additional aim of improving IPM practices based on observation sheets data: 7

Centralization at the PO level Yes: 10 No: 10

Consultation between the Quality Manager and the IPM Technician over residue management and prevention Yes: 16 No: 4

High frequency of greenhouses visits (more than once a month) by the Quality Manager Yes: 12

No: 8 (*)  In  the  analysis,  “Crop sheets management” is a combination of the variables “Crop sheets type of control” and “Centralization of crop sheets at the PO level”  with  the  respective  weightings  (4  and  1).    

(10)

Selecting  and  aggregating  the  dependent  and  independent  variables  

 

The   variables   highlighted   by   the   theory   as   having   an   influence   on   the   allocation   of   monitoring/decision  rights  for  safety  management  purposes  have  been  documented  by   our   survey   and   validated   by   experts.   After   eliminating   the   items   with   no   variation   or   very   low   occurrence   and   testing   for   dependence/correlation   between   the   remaining   variables,   we   were   left   with   1   variable   for   group   size,   3   variables   for   customer   safety   requirements,  3  variables  for  commercial  reputation  and  2  variables  for  asset  specificity.      

The   same   procedure   was   conducted   for   the   dependent   variables.   The   two   types   of   control  (over  the  product  and  over  the  process)  were  assessed  using  a  list  of  relevant   data   collected   during   the   survey.   Twelve   items   were   likely   to   be   representative   of   a   strategy   of   control.   After   eliminating   the   items   with   no   variation   and   testing   for   dependence/correlation  between  the  remaining  variables,  we  were  left  with  7  variables   for  product  control  and  3  variables  for  process  control.    

 

The  following  OLS  regressions  were  then  run  for  each  of  the  10  variables  of  control  over   the  9  independent  variables  (see  table  in  appendix).    

 

Decision/monitoring  right  allocation  i=1  à  10    =  β0  +  β1  Size  +  β2-­‐4  Quality  targeted2-­‐4   +  β5-­‐7    Reputation5-­‐7    +  β8  QM8    +  β9  Technician9    +  εi  

 

Theoretical  and  empirical  considerations  led  us  to  identify  four  categories  for  the  rights   that   are   transferred   to   the   marketing   group   for   safety   management   purposes:   control   over  grower  practices,  pressure  of  analysis,  level  of  sanctions  and  procedures  of  control,   the   last   three   latter   relating   to   control   over   the   product.   After   testing   the   influence   of   each  of  the  9  independent  variables  on  the  10  dependent  variables,  we  tried  to  give  a   more  synthetic  view  by  using  the  aggregated  variables  previously  identified.  Given  the   differences  in  nature  of  the  variables,  we  used  a  series  of  combinatorial  tests  to  assign  a   weight   to   each   elementary   variable   within   a   given   category   of   dependent   or   independent  variables.  All  elementary  variables  had  previously  been  normalized  at  10   as  a  maximum.  Resulting  weightings  (tables  4  and  5)  were  validated  by  experts.  Every   major  variable  is  thus  represented  by  the  weighted  sum  of  its  basic  variables.  

   

Table  4:  Weighting  of  the  independent  variables  

Aggregated variable Elementary variable coefficient Group Size Number of tomato producers within the group No aggregation Level of customer

safety requirements

Existence of customer specific requirements 20

Export to UK customers 1

Share of the fast food industry (%) 20

Commercial Reputation

Membership in a commercial superstructure with collective brand 4

Level of tomato valuation (€/kg) 4

Tomato segmentation (% of cherries, cocktail tomatoes and old varieties in

total volume) 1

Specific Assets

Type of technician: contractual status and degree of concern for IPM No aggregation Type of quality manager (QM): specialized education background and

experience No aggregation

       

(11)

Table  5:  Weighting  of  the  dependent  variables  

Aggregated variable Elementary variable Coefficient Pressure of Analysis Number of tons per residue analysis No aggregation Sanctions

Type of penalty 5

Incentives for grower transparency 2

Communication of individual results at the collective level 1 Control procedures

Grower sampling for residue analysis 1

At least one analysis per grower per year 1 Information/Association of the IPM technician 2 Control over practices

Crop sheets management 4

Consultation between the QM and the IPM Technician 2 Frequency of greenhouse visits by the QM 1  

For  each  main  dependent  variable,  we  thus  run  the  following  OLS  regressions:  

Pressure   of   analysis   =   β0   +   β1Size   +   β2Quality   targeted   +   β3Reputation   +   β4QM   +  

β5Technician  +  ε  

Level   of   Sanction   =   β0   +   β1Size   +   β2Quality   targeted   +   β3Reputation   +   β4QM   +  

β5Technician  +  ε  

Control   procedure   =   β0   +   β1Size   +   β2Quality   targeted   +   β3Reputation   +   β4QM   +  

β5Technician  +  ε  

Control  over  the  practices  =  β0  +  β1Size  +  β2Quality  targeted  +  β3Reputation  +  β4QM  +  

β5Technician  +  ε  

4.  Results  

 

In   this   section,   we   comment   on   the   tests   relating   to   the   theoretical   predictions   concerning   the   allocation   of   rights,   distinguishing   between   rights   to   control   over   the   grower  practices  and  rights  to  control  over  the  product.  The  latter  include  the  intensity   of  control  (number  of  residue  analyses  per  ton),  the  level  of  sanctions  and  the  control   procedures.  We  then  go  on  to  study  the  interactions  between  the  two  types  of  control.    

Most  factors  demonstrate  a  significant  impact  on  control  variables  with  the  exception  of   the   procedures   of   control   over   the   product   (Fisher   test   non   validated).   Despite   a   high   level   of   significance,   our   hypothesis   are   only   partially   confirmed   (table   6).   The   theoretical   predictions   are   fully   verified   regarding   the   role   of   reputation   and   the   IPM   technician   (first   asset   specificity),   while   those   regarding   the   quality   manager   (second   asset   specificity)   run   the   other   way   (reverse   impact   on   control)   and   the   predictions   regarding   group   size   and   customer   safety   demand   have   an   ambiguous   impact   on   control.  Let  us  comment  on  these  findings  

 

Table  6:  Marketing  group  discretion  

Independent Variables Type of

control Dependent Variables Group Size Customer safety demand

Commercial

Reputation Technician IPM Manager Quality Intercept R2 Prob > F Process control Process control 0.113 -0.055** 0.413*** 1.896** -1.117 (10.9%) 36.362*** 0.635 0.008 Product Control Analysis Pressure -0.451*** 0.010*** 0.061*** 0.100 -0.457*** 4.234*** 0.840 0.000 Sanctions -3.477** -0.014 0.513*** 3.012*** 3.677*** - 55.218*** 0.699 0.002 Procedures -0.465 0.001 0.087 1.364* -0.597 11.953 0.251 0.487 Significant  at  1%  (***),  5%  (**);  10%  (*)      

(12)

 

Commercial  reputation  

From  an  empirical  point  of  view,  the  positive  influence  of  commercial  reputation  is  easy   to   understand.   The   level   of   control   increases   with   the   level   of   commercial   reputation   that  is  under  exposure  and  this  is  true  whatever  the  type  of  control.  The  stronger  the   brand  or  the  commercial  reputation,  the  higher  the  pressure  of  analysis  and  the  level  of   sanctions  and  the  more  intensive  the  control  over  grower  practices.    

 

Customer  safety  demand  

More   ambiguous   is   the   influence   of   customer   safety   demands,   which   is   positive   regarding  product  control  but  negative  regarding  process  control.  While  the  first  result   is  in  line  with  the  theoretical  prediction  (more  control  rights  over  the  product  will  be   allocated   to   the   marketing   group   with   an   increase   in   customer   safety   demands),   the   second   result   is   more   surprising   and   leads   us   to   review   the   elementary   variables   that   were  used  to  define  customer  safety  demands.  Actually,  by  far  the  strongest  component   of  such  demands  is  the  existence  of  customer-­‐specific  requirements.  Thirty  per  cent  of   POs   claimed   to   respond   to   specific   requirements   relative   to   pesticide   residues.   Global   GAP  (Good  Agricultural  Practices)  which  applies  to  grower  practices,  is  not  considered  a   specific   requirement   since   it   tends   to   be   a   standard   requirement   when   exporting   to   Northern   Europe.   This   is   not   the   case   of   the   private   standards   relative   to   pesticide   residues   imposed   by   some   European   supermarkets.   Those   standards   are   much   more   stringent  than  the  public  standards  on  pesticide  residues  implemented  by  the  European   Union.  They  place  a  true  burden  on  the  marketing  groups  working  with  such  customers.   To   comply   with   such   safety   demands,   strict   control   over   the   product   is   unavoidable   while  long-­‐term  actions  taken  to  improve  grower  IPM  practices  are  less  useful.    

 

Group  size  

Group   size   does   not   have   the   expected   impact   suggested   by   Olson’s   collective   action   theory   which   predicts   an   increase   in   group   control   over   potential   member   free-­‐riding   when  the  size  of  the  group  increases.  This  is  true  whatever  the  type  of  control.  On  the   one  hand,  the  non-­‐significance  of  the  influence  of  group  size  over  process  control  most   likely   highlights   the   double   and   contradictory   impact   of   the   size   of   a   group,   the   expansion  of  which  requires  more  severe  control  of  potential  member  free-­‐riding  but  at   the  same  time  allows  for  economies  of  scale,  in  particular  to  achieve  better  control  over   the  production  process.  On  the  other  hand,  the  impact  on  product  control  is  significant   but  contradictory:  it  increases  with  the  pressure  of  analysis  but  decreases  with  the  level   of  sanctions.  Consequently,  it  is  impossible  to  say  whether  the  incentives  not  to  free  ride   will  increase  or  decrease  with  group  size.  Indeed,  a  good  proxy  of  these  incentives  is  the   likelihood  of  a  sanction  which  can  be  assessed  by  multiplying  the  probability  of  a  grower   being  controlled  (the  pressure  of  analysis  per  grower)  by  the  level  of  sanctions  that  will   be  applied  in  the  event  of  fraudulent  deviation  (Soubeyran  et  al,  2009).    

 

What  can  be  hypothesized,  however,  is  the  impact  on  a  strategy  of  control.  Given  that   POs'   strategies   of   control   may   be   represented   as   a   trade-­‐off   between   control   over   the   product   and   control   over   the   process,   we   can   anticipate   that   the   impact   of   group   size   will   depend   on   the   level   of   control   over   the   product   relative   to   control   over   the   production  process.  Indeed,  when  the  ratio  is  in  favor  of  process  control,  there  is  more   transparency   with   regard   to   grower   practices,   higher   costs   for   fraudulent   grower   deviation  which  should  lead  to  less  free  riding  and  a  smaller  impact  of  group  size  on  the   level   of   control.   Conversely,   when   control   over   practices   is   low,   growers   have   more  

(13)

opportunity   to   deviate   from   the   safety   rules   imposed   by   the   group   and   those   opportunities   should   increase   with   the   size   of   the   group,   leading   to   an   increase   in   product  control  (pressure  of  analysis  and  sanctions).    

 

IPM  technician    

Investments   in   technical   assistance   for   IPM   monitoring   and   management   have,   on   the   one  hand  and  as  expected,  a  positive  influence  on  the  control  over  grower  practices.  In   particular,  the  higher  the  investments,  the  more  cooperation  there  will  be  between  the   technician  and  the  quality  manager  and  the  more  frequently  the  latter  will  make  field   visits  (see  table  in  the  appendix).  The  impact  of  such  investments  differs,  on  the  other   hand,   between   the   three   components   of   product   control.   While   no   impact   can   be   detected  on  the  pressure  of  analysis,  significant  influence  is  found  for  the  procedure  of   control   and   even   more   for   the   level   of   sanctions.   More   precisely,   the   items   most   impacted  by  such  asset  specificity  are,  on  the  one  hand,  the  information  of  the  technician   concerning  residue  analysis  and  his  contribution  together  with  the  quality  manager  to   adjusting   residue   control   planning   and,   on   the   other   hand,   the   incentives   given   to   growers  to  reveal  ex-­‐ante  possible  misconduct  in  using  pesticides.  

 

We  can  explain  such  a  contrast  first  by  pointing  out  that  the  IPM  technician  has  above  all   a   role   of   education   and   guidance   regarding   IPM.   Consequently,   his   participation   in   control   will   be   all   the   more   understood   and   accepted   by   growers   if   he   has   good   IPM   skills   and   his   conduct   is   transparent   and   consistent.   A   second   reason   for   his   participation   in   control   is   his   position   of   front-­‐line   observer,   which   gives   him   a   true   advantage  over  the  quality  manager  regarding  ex-­‐post  adjustments  of  product  control.   In  particular,  he  is  the  most  capable  of  differentiating  between  technical  or  economical   hazard  and  grower  opportunism  in  the  event  of  detected  deviation.  Since  penalties  may   have   a   high   impact   on   grower   incomes,   a   fair   evaluation   of   grower   responsibility   is   required.  The  application  of  a  sanction  will  be  all  the  easier  as  POs  have  made  consistent   investments  in  IPM  technical  assistance.  

Quality  manager    

The  significant  negative  coefficient  characterizing  the  influence  of  the  quality  manager   (QM)   on   product   control   (pressure   of   analysis   and   level   of   sanctions)   and,   to   a   lesser   extent,   on   process   control   is   intriguing.   We   had   expected   a   positive   relationship   assuming   that   the   quality   manager   might   be   considered   as   a   specific   asset.   Unexpectedly,  the  results  show  that  the  higher  the  QM's  skills  and  experience,  the  lower   the   allocation   of   rights   for   product   safety   control.   The   negative   impact   on   product   control  can  be  interpreted  as  follows:  first,  we  have  to  stress  that  the  main  task  of  a  QM   is   to   control   for   commercial   quality   and   to   arrange   for   disputes   that   may   arise   with   customers   who   claim   to   be   dissatisfied   upon   reception   of   the   product   (Bonnaud   et   al,   2012).  So  far,  most  disputes  concern  quality,  packaging,  delays  or  quantities  while  there   are  very  few  claims  for  non-­‐compliance  with  safety  requirements.  Moreover,  there  may   be  a  conflict  of  compliance  between  shipping  orders  and  safety  requirements,  as  soon  as   demand   outstrips   the   quantities   available   supplied   by   PO's   growers.   Thus,   much   less   priority   is   often   given   to   safety   control   than   to   commercial   control.   Consequently,   we   may  consider  that  investments  in  managing  quality  are  often  barely  specific  to  safety.      

Second,  we  may  assume  that  a  senior  QM  with  a  good  knowledge  of  growers'  practices   may   relieve   the   pressure   of   residue   analysis   by   concentrating   sampling   on   the   more   suspicious  growers.  Our  hypothesis  of  a  positive  correlation  between  QM  seniority  and  

(14)

good  knowledge  of  growers'  practices  is  confirmed  by  our  analysis  which  demonstrates   a   strong   positive   impact   of   QM   seniority   on   frequent   QM   field   visits.   It   is   worth   mentioning,  however,  that  despite  this  positive  relationship,  the  impact  of  QM  seniority   and  educational  skills  shows  up  as  a  significant  negative  impact  on  process  control  due   to  the  fact  that  formal  cooperation  with  the  IPM  technician  is  less  necessary  than  with   new  QMs  and  also  due  to  the  weighting  used  for  aggregation  (process  control  =  4  crop   sheets  management  +  2  QM-­‐technician  cooperation  +  1  QM  field  visits  frequency).  

 

Complementarities  between  variables  of  control    

In  line  with  Arunada  &  al.  approach  (2001),  we  also  assume  that  safety  risk  management   is  a  system  of  interdependent  choices,  in  which  the  two  types  of  strategy  –  those  based   on   control   over   products   and   those   based   on   control   over   practices   –   can   be   complementary   or   substitutes.   To   verify   this   hypothesis,   we   examined   the   conditional   correlations   between   each   pair   of   strategic   variables:   “Pressure   of   residue   analysis”,   “Sanctions”,  “Procedures  of  control  over  products”  and  “Control  over  practices”  (Table   7).    

 

Table  7  –  Complementarities:  conditional  correlations  

  Pressure  of  residue  

analyses     sanctions  Level  of   Procedures  of  control  over  products   Control  over  practices   Pressure   of   residue  

analysis   1.0000        

Level  of  sanctions      0.1255   1.0000       Product  control  

procedures   0.1004   -­‐0.0352   1.0000     Control  over  practices   -­‐0.4805*      -­‐0.0274   -­‐0.1761   1.0000  

*  Significant  at  5%  level    

Globally  speaking,  even  though  only  one  correlation  is  significant  (between  pressure  of   analysis   and   control   over   practices),   results   are   clear   cut   between   the   two   types   of   strategy,   that   based   on   control   over   the   product   and   that   based   on   control   over   practices.  Indeed  all  correlations  between  the  three  variables  of  product  control  and  the   variable   of   process   control   are   negative,   leading   us   to   conclude   that   there   is   substitutability  between  the  two  strategies.  This  is  particularly  true  between  “Pressure   of  residue  analysis”  and  “Control  over  practices”:  this  relationship  suggests  that  strong   investment   in   control   over   practices   may   facilitate   a   reduction   in   the   pressure   of   analysis.   Such   complementarity   has   to   be   highlighted   by   considering   the   long-­‐ term/short-­‐term  effects  of  the  two  types  of  management.  While  sustainable  control  over   practices  focuses  more  on  learning  than  on  punishing  and  needs  to  be  embedded  in  a   long-­‐term   quality   management   system,   successful   control   over   the   product   can   be   obtained   with   less   preparation   and   more   reactivity.   The   more   embedded   the   former   control,  the  more  information  asymmetries  may  be  reduced  between  growers  and  the   PO   and   the   less   sanctions   are   needed   for   control   over   the   product.   However,   grower   opportunism   or   free   riding   cannot   be   totally   dismissed   when   adopting   a   long-­‐term   strategy,   thus   causing   the   product   control   lever   to   be   kept   operational.   This   is   all   the   more   important   as   safety-­‐demanding   customers   are   targeted   by   the   PO   marketing   strategy.    

       

(15)

5.  Conclusion  

 

Our  paper  aims  to  explain  the  design  of  a  pesticide  safety  control  strategy  in  a  marketing   group   by   referring   to   the   literature   on   incomplete   contracts   with   transfer   of   property   rights.  It  defines  such  a  strategy  of  control  as  a  combination  of  control  over  the  product   and   control   over   growers’   practices   giving   insights   into   the   different   nature   of   such   controls.   While   the   former   may   primarily   be   considered   as   a   short-­‐term   management   tool  which  basically  aims  to  control  residues  in  the  products  and  to  penalize  fraudulent   deviant   behavior,   the   latter   is   more   preventive   and   educational   in   nature   and   is   implemented  in  a  long-­‐term  perspective.    

 

Our   analysis   confirmed   most   of   the   theoretical   predictions   and   in   particular   demonstrated   that   the   allocation   of   monitoring/decision   rights   increases   with   commercial   reputation,   customer   safety   demand   and   specific   investments   in   IPM   technical  assistance.    A  more  thorough  analysis  helps  to  differentiate  the  impacts  of  the   nine  independent  variables  on  the  ten  dependent  variables  and  in  particular  sheds  light   on  the  following  aspects.  First,  it  highlights  the  considerable  sensitivity  of  the  pressure   of   residue   analysis   to   customer   safety   demand,   in   particular   when   compliance   with   private   standards   is   required.   Second,   it   invalidates   the   initial   assumption   of   a   strong   specificity   of   the   investment   made   by   the   marketing   group   in   employing   a   quality   manager,   considering   that   the   investment   is   primarily   implemented   to   control   commercial  quality,  which  may  conflict  with  safety  quality.  This  finding  is  in  line  with   the  qualitative  analysis  made  by  Bonnaud  et  al  (2012).  Third,  it  emphasizes  the  role  of   the  IPM  technician  who  not  only  provides  technical  assistance  and  education,  but  also   makes  a  decisive  contribution  to  assessing  the  responsibility  of  a  grower  in  the  event  of   deviant  residue  analysis.  Fourth,  it  does  not  help  conclude  about  the  effect  of  group  size   which  remains  ambiguous,  most  likely  because  of  a  trade-­‐off  between  gains  obtained  by   economies  of  scale  and  costs  to  protect  from  potential  free  riding.  Fifth,  product  control   and   process   control   are   substitutes,   in   particular   regarding   the   pressure   of   residue   analysis   which   may   be   reduced   with   increased   control   over   growers’   practices.   Nonetheless,  as  soon  as  POs  have  a  good  commercial  reputation  and  sell  to  demanding   customers,  both  controls  are  necessary  and  cannot  be  exclusive.    

 

It   is   worth   mentioning   some   limitations   to   and   perspectives   of   our   analysis.   A   first   limitation  is  the  specificity  of  our  case  study  which  applies  to  pesticide  safety  issues  and   to   hybrid   forms   of   the   cooperative   type.   Extension   of   the   problem   to   other   empirical   domains  nevertheless  looks  quite  promising.  We  may,  for  instance,  consider  applications   of   the   problem   for   other   types   of   quality   attribute   which   are   difficult   to   measure   or   complex  to  produce  (such  as  fair  trade  or  environmental-­‐friendly  products)  or  to  other   types   of   buyer   such   as   private   shippers.   In   the   latter   case,   some   modifications   in   the   analytical   framework   are   necessary,   in   particular   regarding   commercial   reputation   which  is  no  longer  a  collective  good  with  potential  free  riding  but  a  buyer-­‐specific  asset   with   potential   hold-­‐up   from   the   suppliers.   A   second   limitation   is   the   size   of   our   population   which,   although   exhaustive,   does   not   provide   much   robustness   to   testing.   Given  the  crucial  role  of  safety  in  food  chain  competitiveness,  many  industries  or  grower   associations   should   be   interested   in   such   a   topic   offering   numerous   opportunities   to   apply   the   problem   and   contribute   to   the   empirical   literature   on   incomplete   contracts   with  transfer  of  property  rights.  

(16)

6.  Bibliography  

Alchian, A.A. and H. Demsetz (1972). Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization, American Economic Review, 62 (5), 777-795

Arrunada, B., Garicano, L. and Vazquez, L., 2001. Contractual allocation of decision rights and incentives: the case of automobile distribution, Journal of Law, Economics and

Organization, 17(1), 257-284.

Aubert, M., Bouhsina, Z., Codron, J.-M. and Rousset, S. (2013), "Pesticides safety risk, food chain organization, and the adoption of sustainable farming practices. The case of Moroccan early tomatoes" 134th EAAE Seminar, Labels on sustainability: an issue for consumers,

producers, policy makers, and NGOs, March 21-22, 2013, INRA, Paris, France.

Baker, G., Gibbons, R., and Murphy, K.J. (2006) "Contracting for control". Working paper, MIT. May 2006 version

Barzel, Y.A. (1982). Measurement cost and the organization of markets, Journal of Law and

Economics, Vol. XXV, n°1 : 27-48

Barzel, Y. (1989) Economic Analysis of Property Rights, Cambridge University Press, First Edition 1989, Second Edition 1997.

Barzel, Y.A. (2005). Organizational Forms and Measurement Costs. Journal of Institutional

and Theoretical Economics. 161(3): 357-373.

Bignebat, C and Codron, J.M. (2006) – Organizational innovations and food safety monitoring in the fresh produce industry. Research in Economics and Rural Sociology. INRA   n°  5-­‐6,  November  2006,  4  p.

 

Bijman, J. (2007) "The role of producer organisations in quality-oriented agrifood chains: an economic organisation perspective" In: R. Ruben, M. van Boekel, A. van Tilburg and J. Trienekes (eds) Tropical food chains: governance regimes for quality management. Wageningen, Wageningen Acad. Publ., 257-277.

Bonnaud L., Bouhsina Z. and Codron J. M., (2012) -Le rôle du marché dans le contrôle des traitements phytosanitaires. Terrains et Travaux, n° 20, 2012, 87-103

Bonnaud L. ; Bouhsina Z. and Codron J.M. (2012). Tracer les tomates. In : Bonnaud, L. ; Joly, L. (éds) - L'alimentation sous contrôle : tracer, auditer, conseiller. – Paris (FRA) : Editions Quae, 2012. - P. 77-90 - (Sciences en partage)

Bouhsina, Z., Codron, J.M., Cordier, E. and Soubeyran, R. (2009). Les stratégies de contrôle de la qualité dans les Organisations de Producteurs de tomates [En ligne] - Montpellier (FRA) : UMR MOISA, 2009. - 36 p. – (Série Cahier de recherche ; 6)

http://ideas.repec.org/b/umr/ecbook/200906.html

Chaddad, F.R. and C. Iliopoulos, (2013). Control Rights, Governance and the Costs of Ownership in Agricultural Cooperatives, Agribusiness: An International Journal, 29 (1), 3-22.

(17)

Codron, J.-M., E. Montaigne, and S. Rousset (2013). Quality management and contractual incompleteness: grape procurement for high-end wines in Argentina. Journal of Chain and

Network Science, 2013, 13(1): 11-35

Eisenhardt, K.M. (1985). Control: Organizational and economic approaches, Management Science, Vol. 31, n°2 : 134-149

Hu, Y and G.W.J. Hendrikse (2009). Allocation of Decision Rights in Fruit and Vegetable Contracts in China. International Studies of Management and Organization 39(4): 8-30. Ménard. C. (2012). Hybrid Modes of Organization. Alliances, Joint Ventures, Networks, and Other ‘Strange’ Animals. In: R. Gibbons and J. Roberts (eds.) The Handbook of Organizational Economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, 1248 p.

Raynaud, E., L. Sauvée, and E. Valceschini (2009). Aligning branding strategies and governance of vertical transactions in agri-food chains. Industrial and Corporate Change 18(5): 835-868.

Sykuta, M. and Cook, M.L. (2001). A New Institutional Economics Approach to Contracts and Cooperatives, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 83(5), 1273-1279.

Williamson, O.E. (1991). Comparative economic organization: the analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly 36(2): 269-296.

Figure

Table   1:   Structures   and   marketing   characteristics   of   Tomato   Producer   Organizations   (2010)   
Table   4:   Weighting   of   the   independent   variables   
Table   6:   Marketing   group   discretion   
Table   7   –   Complementarities:   conditional   correlations   

Références

Documents relatifs

The safety climate was assessed using 5-point Likert-type scales ranging from 1 (completely disagree) to 5 (completely agree) with three sub-dimensions: perceived attitude of

The first involves a compliance assessment, while the second describes the management of action plans and discusses the conditions of legal liability and penalties in the case of

It is important to keep in mind that while harvesting costs are realized ex-post, the cost of pesticide is paid ex-ante and corresponds to the decision of how much to minimize the

Diversification.— The degree of farm’s diversification is expected to have a negative effect on insurance demand and pesticide use since it can be considered as a substitute

The failures of control components may lead to a loss of the switching functions which handle the redundancy mechanisms between the process components. Hence we propose

Compromised tasks may exhibit arbitrary execution patterns over the resources they can get hold of. In systems with dynamic resource allocation, as they will be required for

partially blind thrusting along the eastern piedmont of the Western range on Quito Fault System but that part of the stress may also be transferred north to the Otavalo –El

Phylogenetic analysis was performed using the maximum likelihood method on protein sequences from the four TF families: C 2 H 2 , ERF, GRAS and NF-YA, identified in C.. glauca