• Aucun résultat trouvé

Structural change in agriculture: Confronting the transition issue

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "Structural change in agriculture: Confronting the transition issue"

Copied!
22
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

1

Structural Change in

Agriculture: Confronting

the Transition Issue

45th Annual Conference

of the Agricultural Economics Association of South Africa 26-28 September 2007 - Johannesburg

Bruno Losch (Cirad /World Bank)

Thierry Giordano (FMFA/DBSA)

This presentation relies on the first results of a World Bank program launched in 2005, entitled “Structural implications of trade liberalisation on rural development”. We greatly thank the French Cooperation and the International Fund for Agricultural

(2)

Main Thrusts

Could the classical evolutionary model of national economies

(agricultural and industrial revolutions) still be replicated in LDCs? Economic transition: very slow in LDCs over the last 50 years => LDCs do not manage to take off

Hurdles to further acceleration:

still-to-happen demographic transition, restructuring of world markets,

tremendous gaps of competitiveness in agriculture between developing and developed countries

National government: Rethink agricultural and more broadly public policies to speed up economic transition

(3)

3

Economic Transition

Classical model: the productivity of family farms increases

and resources (capital and/or labour) are released and

transfered to industry and services

How has LDCs started to engage in the economic

transition process?

Transfer of resources:

Labour = distribution of employment amongst the various economic sectors

Capital = weight of agriculture in the domestic economy

=> understand whether resource transfers have operated, are operating or will operate

Seven countries: Mexico, Nicaragua, Morocco, Mali,

Senegal, Kenya, Madagascar

(4)

Agricultural EAP and GDP per capita

(1) 1977-84; (2) 1987-94; (3) 1997-04

Mada1 Mali1 Mex1 Nicaragua1 Mali2 Mexico2 Morocco2 Mali3 Mexico3 Morocco3 Kenya1 Morroco1 Senegal1 Kenya2 Madagascar2 Nicaragua2 Senegal2 Kenya3 Madagascar3 Nicaragua3 Senegal3 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 2,70 2,90 3,10 3,30 3,50 3,70 3,90 4,10

Log GDP per capita (2000 constant US$)

A g ric u ltu ra l G D P / T o ta l G D P

(5)

5

Agricultural EAP and GDP per capita

(1) 1977-84; (2) 1987-94; (3) 1997-04

Mex1 Morroco1 Mexico2 Morocco2 Nicaragua2 Mexico3 Kenya1 Mada1 Mali1 Nicaragua1 Senegal1 K2 Mada2 Mali2 Senegal2 Kenya3 Madagascar3 Mali3 Morocco3 Nicaragua3 Senegal3 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% 2,70 2,90 3,10 3,30 3,50 3,70 3,90 4,10

Log GDP per capita at PPP (2000 constant US$)

A g ric u ltu ra l E A P / T o ta l E A P

(6)

Demographic transition

Population growth rate:

Mexico and Morocco: slowing down since the 70s’ => below 2 % In stark contrast, Mali : still increasing => ~3 %.

Senegal and Madagascar: declining since the end of the 80s’ and 90s’ => between 2.4 and 2.8 %

(7)

7

Population growth rate (1962-2004)

1,00% 1,50% 2,00% 2,50% 3,00% 3,50% 4,00% 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004

Kenya Madagascar Mali Mexico Morocco Nicaragua Senegal

(8)

Demographic transition

Population growth rate

Mexico and Morocco: slowing down since the 70s’ => below 2 % In stark contrast, Mali : still increasing => ~3 %.

Senegal and Madagascar: declining since the end of the 80s’ and 90s’ => between 2.4 and 2.8 %

SSA: growth rates => the higher in the world

Consequences

Future GDP growth rate has to exceed the population growth rate => require greater efforts

The stronger the population growth rate, the higher the number of young people entering annually the labour market, and the larger the share of the working youth in the total population => more employments

(9)

9

Low employment opportunities

Supply side: Current level of formal jobs

Mali: 32,000 formal jobs in 1995; 39,500 in 1999 cohort = 100,000

Madagascar: 42,000 formal jobs (tourism + textile-garment) 11 % of the 387,000

Senegal: since 2000, less than 30,000 jobs have been created annually cohort =100 000

Nicaragua, 32,000 jobs each year cohorts: 90,000 annually Morocco: 217,000 jobs between 1994 and 2003 460,000 annual new comers

Demand side:

The situation is going to worsen because of the still to happen demographic transition

(10)

Estimated annual youth cohorts

(2005-2024, base 100 = 2005).

60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 220 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 Kenya Madagascar Mali Mexico Morocco Nicaragua Senegal

(11)

11

Yearly cohorts in sub-Saharan Africa, South

Africa excluded, in millions (2004-2024)

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024 Rural Urban

(12)

Informal employments dominate

Due to the lack of alternatives in formal sectors, workers

mainly rely on informal employment.

Mali: the informal sector is the main source of employment, gathering 80 % of total jobs

Madagascar: in 2004, salaried jobs were rather an exception to the rule: only 13 % of the workers are salaried. This figure was slightly lower in rural areas, 12%

Senegal: in 2005, informal employments made up 28 % and 64 % of total employment respectively in urban and rural areas, and this trend is strengthening since 92 % of the new jobs were created by the informal sector

Most of the informal employments emphasize

self-financed, under-capitalized, small-scale, unskilled-labour

intensive production leading to low revenue, bad work

conditions and low productivity = Poor living conditions,

slow economic transition

(13)

13

Absorption capacity of agriculture:

Sustainable?

Consequences of the large absorption capacity of

agriculture over the last 40 years:

Extension of the agricultural frontier => marginal land colonization => land degradation

Downsizing of farms => the growth of the agricultural population has outpaced the growth of the agricultural land

• In Senegal, the number of farms has raised by 48 %, from 295,000 to 437,037, between 1960 and 1998. The average surface per agricultural worker has dropped from 1 ha in 1960 to 0.57 in 1998

• In Madagascar, between 1985 and 2005, nearly 970,000 new farms were created => the share of employed people working in the agricultural sector has dramatically increased between 1993 and 2004, from 65 % to 82 % => farm size dropped from 1.2 ha in 1985 to merely 0.86 ha in 2005

(14)

14

The structural evolution of markets

vertical integration of commodity chains and “horizontal”

integration through the new distribution systems

(supermarkets revolution)

demand-driven markets characterized by segmentation

processes based on norms and standards => contracts

new rules of the game: opportunities for a few and

constraints for the many:

the production of green beans in Madagascar merely gathers 10 000 contracted producers over a total of 2.4 million farms (0.4 %).

In Kenya, horticultural production is sold mainly on local markets, the supermarket share representing only 4.4 %. Furthermore the development of supermarkets in developed countries lead to

exports decline in the early 1990s due to the stringent quality standards which were set up for world horticultural exports.

(15)

15

Productivity and competitiveness gaps

Source: Mazoyer (2001), according to cereal production

EAP (Million) % Ag. EAP Green revolution Type of haulage Ha / Ag. EAP Production (Tons) Productivity 30 2 Yes Mecanichally drawn 100 10 1000 423 33 Yes Hauled by animals 5 10 50 423 33 Yes manual 1 10 10 423 33 No manual 1 1 1 1300 100

(16)

Households adaptation strategies

These evolutions question the ability of farmers to carry on

living on their own-farm activities

What are the adaptation strategies developed by farmers to

remain on their land while:

labour productivity is weakening (labour surplus), land productivity is decreasing (downsizing of farms), and capital per farmer is dwindling?

And when:

Formal employment opportunities are weak

Informal rural and urban employments does not offer better income

Agricultural absorption capacity is shrinking

(17)

17

Migration as an exit option

Economic transition in Europe at the turn of the century:

40 millions people have emigrated to the new world

between 1850 and 1913 (Hatton and Williamson, 1994).

Migration has also been an option for some countries

engaged in economic transition like Mexico, Morocco and

Nicaragua

(18)

Migrations and remittances

Migrants (Millions) Population (Millions) Migrants / Pop. Main Destinations Remittances (Millions $US) Morocco 2,7 29,9 9% Europe 4 724 Mexico 11,5 104,3 11% US 21 802

Nicaragua 0,7 5,6 12% Costa Rica; US 600

Senegal 0,5 11,7 4% Western Africa 511

Mali 1,2 11,4 11% Western Africa 175

Kenya 0,4 33,4 1% - 494

(19)

19

Migration as an exit option?

Economic transition in Europe at the turn of the century:

40 million people have emigrated to the new world

between 1850 and 1913 (Hatton and Williamson, 1994).

Migration has also been an option for some countries

engaged in economic transition like Mexico, Morocco and

Nicaragua

Academic studies emphasize the attraction effects of

developed countries (Hatton and Williamson, 2001) an

migration as an inevitable step towards the development of

country of origin (De Haas, 2006)

Such a conclusion should help developed countries to

rethink their migration policies and all their foreign aid

strategies if they truly want to help economic transition in

developing countries to happen (Bakewell, 2007).

(20)

Conclusion

Agriculture in SSA:

Larger share of the EAP (60%)

Labour surplus (informal, underemployment) = low productivity of labour Small farm size + low productivity of land

Impoverishment = decapitalisation => huge competitiveness gap

How could these farmers seize opportunities following the restructuring of markets that requires:

Technical assistance (norms and standards) Investments

Capital

Inputs (technical package)

=> only a small fringe of farmers is involved, the large majority is excluded

Still to happen demographic transition threatens the capacity of the agricultural

sector to abide by absorbing a notable share of the young people entering the labour market

Since classic economic transition is based on agricultural development => economic transition impasses?

(21)

21

Conclusion

Mainly depends on policies that could support households adaptation strategies => requires a better understanding of these strategies

Production diversification => to help farmers to connect to the markets • Public goods provision (agricultural research, infrastructures…)

• Support missing and imperfect markets (financial services…) • Transfers

Non-farm activities => help workers to connect to the market • Develop opportunities outside agriculture (supply side)

• Strengthen the skills of the workforce (demand side) Migrations

• Reduction of the labour surplus • Remittances / Private transfers

Capacities of SSA countries are weak: Economic transition is nor a sectorial challenge neither a domestic stake => requires global development strategies and international policy coordination

Economic transition could probably not be engaged without a concomitant development of other economic sector absorbing agricultural workforce surplus How to define this new domestic and global policy spaces in today’s globalized world?

(22)

Thank you for your attention

Contact:

Références

Documents relatifs

Dans le troisi`eme chapitre, l’impact du facteur d´emographique sur la croissance du secteur des services ` a long terme est mis en exergue. Les travailleurs et la production

For all branches, technological change constitutes the sole part of TFP change, except for sheep farms, which recorded a high technical efficiency progress and livestock on

These authors demonstrate that food abundance has provided HGs an incentive to shift from an economy with resources in open-access to an economy with exclusive property rights,

 Looked at housing, community and social services, public safety, health care, recreation and sports facilities and programs, cultural facilities and programs, kindergarten to

It promotes local economies, very low or no competition, share price determination for supporting the farmer, some risk- sharing between members, and

Therefore, the focus of experimental studies should be on how they can add robust evidence to the existing impact assessment and evaluation process

The emergence of the EKC inverted U-shaped relationship between deforestation and socio- economic development in the Brazilian Amazon is the result of a transition in environmental

Overall, the final value of SEIB is highly affected by two bio-based sectors (agriculture K=1 and manufacture of food, beverages and tobacco K=4). Both are completely pure, namely