• Aucun résultat trouvé

A note on robustness in Merton's model of intertemporal consumption

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "A note on robustness in Merton's model of intertemporal consumption"

Copied!
17
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

Fabio Trojani, Paolo Vanini

A Note on Robustness in Merton's Model of Intertemporal Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Quaderno N. 99-11

Decanato della Facolta di Scienze Economiche

Via Ospedale, 13 CH-6900 Lugano. Tel. 091 912 46 09 / 08. Fax 091 912 46 29

(2)

A Note on Robustness in Merton's Model of Intertemporal

Consumption and Portfolio Choice

Paolo Vanini ECOFIN AG

Switzerland

Fabio Trojani University of Southern

Switzerland

y

December 9, 1999

Abstract

The paper presents a robust version of a simple two-assets Mer- ton's (1969) model where the optimal choices and the implied shadow market prices of risk for a representative robust decision maker (RDM) can be easily described.

With the exeption of the log utility case, precautionary behaviour is induced in the optimal consumption-investment rules through a sub- stitution of investment in risky assets with both current consumption and riskless saving. For the log utility case, precautionary behaviour arises only through a substitution between risky and riskless assets.

On the nancial side, the decomposition of the market price of risk in a standard consumption based component and a further price for model uncertainty risk (which is positively related to the robustness parameter) is independent of the underlying risk aversion parameter.

Keywords: Merton's Model, Knightian Uncertainty, Model Con- tamination, Model Misspecication, Robust Decision Making.

ECOFIN Research and Consulting AG, Neumunsterallee 6, CH-8032 Zurich, tel: +41 1 389 66 80, e-Mail: Paolo.Vanini@econ.ch

yInstitute of Finance, University of Southern Switzerland, Centro Civico, Via Ospedale 13, CH-6900 Lugano, tel: +41 91 912 47 23, e-Mail: Fabio.Trojani@lu.unisi.ch.

(3)

3

1 Introduction

This paper presents a robust version of a simple two-assets Merton's (1969) model where the optimal consumption and portfolio choices as well as the implied market price of risk of a representative "robust decision maker"

(RDM) (cf. Hansen, Sargent and Tallarini (1998) and Anderson, Hansen and Sargent (1999); AHS (1999) in the sequel) can be easily described.

Robustness leads generally to focusing on worst case scenarios over a re- stricted set of appropriately dened relevant model misspecications. In the present formulation of robustness we model asset prices that inherently re- ect a form of risk aversion to a particular kind of Knightian uncertainty (cf. Knight (1921) and Epstein and Wang (1994)). Unlike other formula- tions - as for instance those directly linked to the literature of risk sensitive control (cf. Whittle (1990)) - this formulation yields explicit and very easy and interpretable expressions for the relevant variables in the robust Mer- ton's problem. In fact, the solution for the robust problem is of the same functional form as that for the classical Merton's problem.

Similarly to AHS (1999), we model robustness through a RDM determin- ing worst case consumption and portfolio rules over a class of alternative models that are constrained in their "distance" from a reference model for asset prices. The reference model is the standard geometric Brownian mo- tion process while the maximal admissible "distance" therefrom is measured with a continuous time version of relative entropy. This single "distance" pa- rameter models a preference for robustness by constraining the set of model misspecications relevant to a RDM.

The contribution of the paper consists in deriving explicit and easily under- standable robust consumption and investment rules that can be compared to those of a non-robust decision maker in Merton's model. AHS (1999) develop a theoretical framework to robust decision making in continuous time that provide general characterizations of the impact of a preference for robustness on the optimal decision rules and on pricing. However, when analyzing a specic model one still has to solve the arising Bellman equations in order to fully characterize the implied optimal robust decision rules; in the Merton's model this can be done explicitly and easily.

With the exeption of the log utility case robustness aects the optimal de- cision rules through a substitution of investment in risky assets with both current consumption and riskless saving. For the log utility case, precau- tionary behaviour comes up only through a substitution between risky and riskless assets.

On the nancial side, the decompositions of the market price of risk in a standard consumption based component and a further price for model un-

(4)

4 certainty risk (which is positively related to the robustness parameter) is independent of the underlying risk aversion parameter.

In Section 2 we present a general robust version of Merton's (1969) two assets model. Section 3 derives the implied optimal consumption and portfolio rules for isoelastic utility functions. Section 4 makes the structure of the implied market price of risk explicit while Section 5 concludes.

2 A Robust Merton's two Assets Model

There are two assets, a risk free asset with price Bt at time t and a risky asset with price Pt at timet whose dynamics are given by

dB

t =rBtdt (1)

dP

t = Ptdt+PtdZt : (2) The drift and volatility and as well as the short rate r are assumed constant. Z is a standard Brownian motion in IR.

Let wt be the proportion of current wealth Wt invested in the risky asset.

The budget constraint for current wealth Wt is given by

dW

t=wt(,r)Wtdt+ (rWt,ct)dt+wtWtdZt ; (3) where ct is the consumption rate at time t.

Associated to the joint Markov process dened by (2) and (3) is a semigroup (Tt)t0 of operators dened by

T

t

'(y) =E['(Wt;Pt)j(W0;P0) = y] ; (4) and a generator A dened by

A(') = lim

t!0 T

t ','

t

; (5)

for all test functions 'such that this limit exists. In the case of the classical Merton's (1969) and (1971) model the generator (AM) is given by1

A

M(') =@'

@P

+ (w(,r) + (rW ,c))@'

@W

+122P2@@22P' + 122w2W2@@22W' +2wWP @2'

@W@P

: (6)

1See for instance Merton (1971), Section 4.

(5)

5 We model a RDM by an ecomomic agent taking into account the possibility of a misspecied model (2) for asset prices. Specically, we consider rational economic agents which are looking for decision rules that perform well not only at the reference model (2), but also over a set of relevant (local) model misspecications of (2).

In order to dene and measure such model misspecications we consider absolutely continuos contaminations of (2) and (3) by introducing families (Tt)t0 of distorted semigroups dened by

T

t(') = Tt(')

T

t() ; (7)

for nonnegative random variables such that these operators are well de- ned2. The generator AM; associated to the "-contaminated" price and wealth dynamics in Merton's model is easily obtained. It is given by3:

A

M;(') =AM(') +A(') (9) where

A

(') =2P2@log

@P

@'

@P

+2w2W2@log

@W

@'

@W

+2PwW@log

@P

@'

@W

+2PwW@log

@W

@'

@P :

(10) The associated distorted price dynamics are

dP

t= Pt+ 2Pt2@log

@P

+2wtPtWt@log

@W

!!

dt+PtdZt (11) while the budget constraint for distorted current wealth is:

dW

t =wt (,r) + 2Pt@log

@P

+2wtWt@log

@W

!!

W

t dt

+(rWt,ct)dt+wtWtdZt : (12)

2For a more extensive discussion of these denitions we refer to AHS (1999).

3To proove this, remark that (6) denes the generator of the diusions (2) and (3).

Denition (5) applied to the distorted semigroup (7) then implies:

A

M;(') = AM('),'AM()

: (8)

Using the product rule to computeAM(') one then nally gets (9).

(6)

6 These two equations describe the dynamic budget constraint of a RDM when the conditional distributions of the given reference model are contaminated by a specic absolutely continuous change of measure (cf. equation (7)).

A RDM will not generally be able to determine which particular model mis- specication is already aecting the assets price dynamics; he will rather have a rough perception of the set of misspecications which are dicult to distin- guish from its reference model. We assume that such a set of relevant model misspecications can be described by a maximal continuous-time entropy radius from the given reference model. Before introducing the optimization problem of a RDM in Merton's model we dene the relevant magnitudes in this respect.

Let

I

t() =Tt

T

t() log

T

t()

!!

be the relative entropy of the discrete time density of (Pt;Wt) under the contaminated model (11) and (12), relative to that implied by the reference model (2) and (3). It is not a metric, however it measures the discrepancy of the two densities under scrutiny by the so-called information inequality4. Further It() has an important information-theoretic interpretation; it can be interpreted as the expected surprise experienced (over the time period [0;t]) when believing that (2) and (3) describe the model dynamics and being informed that in fact these are described by (11) and (12); cf. Renyi (1961) and (1971) for a deeper discussion of this point.

The continuous-time measure of relative entropy to be used in the sequel is5 (see also AHS (1999)):

I

0() := lim

t!0 I

t()

t

= 1

A

M(log), log

A

M(), 1

A

M() : (13) Using equation (8) and (9) applied to '= log we can write this as:

I

0() =AM(log) +A(log), 1

A

M() = 12A(log) : (14)

4See for instance White (1996), Theorem 2.3, p. 9. Remark thatIt() = 0 if and only if the two densities to be compared are identical almost surely.

5To proove this formula note that:

I

t()

t

= 1

T

t()

T

t(log),Tt()logTt()

t

= 1

T

t()

T

t(log),log

t

,logTt()(Tt(),)

t

,

(logTt(),log)

t

:

Taking limits ast!0 and using the continuity of semigroups the desired result is obtained.

(7)

7 We interpret this continuous time entropy measure as the marginal rate of change with which expected surprises are experienced when we are continu- ously informed over time about the underlying data generating mechanism.

As in AHS (1999) we model robustness as a two player (zero sum) game in which the second player (the nature say) is malevolent and chooses a worst case model from the set of model misspecications that a RDM considers as relevant. A preference for robustness is introduced through a bound on the maximal admissible continuous time entropy "distance" (13) between a perturbed model and the reference one.

Letu() be the current utility function of consumption and %be a subjective discounting factor. The two player decision problem of a RDM in Merton's model is:

J(W) = max

fc;wg

min

fg E

Z

1

0

exp(,%s)(u(cs))ds (15) subject to the dynamic constraints (11) and (12) and to the "maximal con- tinuous time entropy" restriction:

I

0() : (16)

We can interpret al the largest continuous time entropy distance for which a model misspecication is seen as relevant by the RDM. The choice of therefore restricts the amount of (relevant) model misspecication6. From this perspective we can also interpretas a parameter modelling a preference for robustness. Indeed, the larger the parameter , the less the malevolent player is restricted in determining a worst case model over the relevant model misspecications, the greater the incentive for robustness in determin- ing optimal consumption and investment.

Given a preference for robustness the minimization with respect to de- termines a worst case model . It is easy to show (see the Appendix):

@log

@P

=,q2 JP

(Pt2JP2 +wt2Wt2JW2 + 2wtWtPtJWJP)12 ; (17)

@log

@W

=,q2 JW

(Pt2JP2 +wt2Wt2JW2 + 2wtWtPtJWJP)12 : (18) In the present setting the problem can be solved by a value function depend- ing only on current wealth. This implies:

@log

@P

= 0 ; @log

@W

=,

p2

w

t W

t :

6One could try to set this parameter in a way such that model misspecications which are statistically easily detectable are outside the given maximal-entropy "radius".

(8)

8 By inserting these expressions in the perturbed dynamics (11) and (12) prob- lem (15) can be rewritten as a standard single agent Merton's problem.

3 Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Rules

The single agent problem equivalent to (15) is:

J(W) = max

fc;wg E

Z

1

0

exp(,%s)u(cs)ds (19) subject to the dynamic constraints

dP

t =Pt,q2dt+PtdZt ; (20)

dW

t =Wtwt(,r),q2dt

+(rWt,ct)dt+wtWtdZt ; (21) The corresponding Hamilton Jacobi Bellman (HJB) equation for this problem reads

%J(W) = maxc;w fA

M;

J(W) +u(c)g ; (22) where

A M;

=AM +A ; A =,q2wW@W ; (23) with J(0) = 0 as a boundary condition.

Assuming an isoelastic current utility of consumption

u(c) = cp

p

; p2(0;1) ; the HJB equation for this problem reads explicitly

%J = max

w 1

22w2W2JWW +,r,q2wWJW +rWJW + maxc

(

c p

p ,cJ

W )

(24) and is of the same functional form as the HJB equation for the classical Merton's problem. It is solved by the well-known functional form

J(W) =K()Wp ; (25)

(9)

9 with an dependent parameter K() given by

%

1,p,p (,r,p2)2

22(1,p)2 + 1,r p

!!

p,1=pK() : (26) The implied optimal rules are:

w

RM() = (,r,

p2)

2(1,p) ; cRM() = (pK())p,11 W : (27) As a consequence we see7:

@w RM

@

=, 1

(1,p)p2 <0 ; @cRM

@

= p(,r,p2)

(1,p)2p2 >0 :(28) We thus conclude:

Robustness increases optimal consumption if and only if the uncertainty adjusted market price of risk

,r, p2

is larger than zero8 and lowers the optimal fraction of wealth invested in risky assets,

When utility is logarithmic (that is forp!0), robustness only reduces the optimal fraction allocated to risky assets. Optimal consumption is independent of the nancial parameters, except through the eect of changing this fraction.

4 Robust Pricing

Let (coptt ) denote the optimal consumption plans of a RDM and introduce a further risky asset that does not pay dividends, with price dynamics

dP~t = ~tP~tdt+ ~tP~tdZt ; (29) where (~t;~t) are some corresponding drift and diusion processes under the given reference model.

7Some graphs of the implied optimal rules in dependence of pand are presented in the Appendix for a possible choice of the parameters,, %andr.

8We discuss the market price of risk in the next section. Without loss of generality we will assume in the sequel this quantity to be non-negative.

(10)

10 This implies a "worst case model" market price of risk given by

~

t ,

p2~t,r

~

t

=,coptt ucc(coptt )

u

c(coptt ) coptt = (1,p)copt

t

; (30) where (coptt ) is the diusion process of optimal consumption growth.

We therefore obtain a decomposition of the market price of risk for the given reference model as:

~

t ,r

~

t

= (1,p)coptt +q2 : (31) The rst term on the right hand side of (31) corresponds to the usual con- sumption based motivation for the market price of risk9. The second term on the right hand side of (31) corresponds to an extra equilibrium reward for risk that arises because of a possible misspecication of the given reference model for asset prices. This term is positive and enhances the market price of risk resulting from the pure consumption based motives.

Using the derived robust optimal rules and the linearity in wealth of optimal consumption the dynamics of aggregate optimal consumption are

dc opt

t =coptt r+ ((,r),p2)2

2(1,p) ,(pK())p,11

!

dt

+ (,r),p2

(1,p)

!

c opt

t dZ

t

: (32) A preference for robustness therefore implies:

A lower instantaneous variance of equilibrium optimal aggregate con- sumption growth,

A lower instantaneous expected growth of equilibrium optimal aggre- gate consumption.

The consumption based part of the implied market price of risk is:

,r

,

q2 : (33)

As a consequence, robustness yields a lower consumption based shadow mar- ket price of risk in Merton's model. This part is independent of the risk

9Note however, that this term depends on the volatility of optimal consumption growth under the selected worth case model which will be lower than the volatility of optimal consumption growth when no model misspecication is assumed.

(11)

11 aversion parameter p but depends crucially on the amount of risk aversion to model misspecication (which is a function of )10. The resulting market prices of risk also reects the price of model uncertainty risk and it is higher by a factor p.

5 Conclusions

We proposed a simple robust version of Merton's (1969) and (1971) model of intertemporal consumption and portfolio choice where the optimal rules and the implied market price of risk of a representative RDM can be computed explicitly.

Robustness aects the optimal rules through a substitution of risky invest- ment with saving in riskless assets and (or) current consumption. The con- sumption based part of the market price of risk is lower, as a consequence of a lower volatility of consumption growth, and is enxanced by a market price for model uncertainty that is monotonically related to the robustness parameter and that is independent of the risk aversion parameter.

10Indeed, the substitution eect discussed in the last section produced a redistribution of optimal wealth in favour of riskless assets and current consumption. This gives a lower volatility of aggregated wealth growth. By the linearity of optimal consumption in optimal wealth this implies a lower volatility of aggregated consumption growth too, that is a lower aggregated consumption risk. Since the assumed utility function are of the constant relative risk aversion type, the consumption based part of the equilibrium shadow market price of risk implied by a concern for robustness has to be lower.

(12)

12

References

Anderson, E. W., L. P. Hansen, and T. J. Sargent (1999):

\Risk and Robustness in Equilibrium, http://www.stanford.edu/ sar- gent/research.html.

Epstein,L.G.,and T.Wang(1994): \Intertemporal Asset Pricing Under Knightian Uncertainty,"Econometrica, 62, 283{322.

Hansen, L. P., T. J. Sargent, and T. D. Tallarini Jr. (1998):

\Robust Permanent Income and Pricing, http://www.stanford.edu/ sar- gent/research.html.

Knight, F.(1921): Risk, Uncertainty and Prot. Boston, Mass: Houghton Miin. Reprint, London: London School of Economics, 1946.

Merton, R. C. (1969): \Lifetime Portfolio Selection Under Uncertainty:

the Continuous Time Case,"Review of Economics and Statistics, 51, 247{

257. (1971): \Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model,"Journal of Economic Theory, 3, 373{413.

Renyi, A. (1961): \On Measures of Entropy and Information," in Proceed- ings of the Fourth Berkely Symposium in Mathematical Statistics. Berkeley:

University of California Press.

(1971): Probability Theory. Amsterdam: North Holland.

White, H.(1996): Estimation, Inference and Specication Analysis. Econo- metric Society Monographs, No. 22, Cambridge University Press.

Whittle, P. (1990): Risk Sensitive Optimal Control. Wiley, New York.

(13)

13

6 Appendix

Proof of (17) and (18)

: We consider the minimization with respect to of the objective function in (15) under the entropy constraint (16). Using (14) the HJB equation corresponding to this problem reads:

%J(W) = min

A M;

J(W) +u(c) +1

2A(log), ; (34) with the compensatory slackness conditions:

1

2A(log),= 0 ; 0 : (35)

By (8) and the explicit expression (10) a dierentiation with respect to @@Plog and @@Wlog yields the optimality conditions:

2

P 2

@log

@P

+2PwW@log

@W

=,1

(2P2JP +2PwWJW) ;

2

w 2

W 2

@log

@W

+2PwW@log

@P

=,1

(2w2W2JW +2PwWJP) ; that is:

@log

@P

=,1

J

P

;

@log

@W

=,1

J

W

: (36)

Finally, is given by the equation:

= 12A(log)

= 122P2@log

@P

@log

@P

+2w2W2@log

@W

@log

@W

+2PwW@log

@P

@log

@W

+2PwW@log

@W

@log

@P

=, 1 22

2

P 2

J 2

P +2w2W2JW2 +2PwWJPJW +2PwWJWJP ; using (36). This gives (17) and (18) in the paper.

(14)

14

Figures

Figure 1: Optimal consumption cRM() (withW normalized to 1) as a function of the risk aversion parameter p(between 0.1 and 0.6) and the maximum entropy distance (between 0 and 0.03). The other parameters were set to % = 0:08,

r = 0:05,= 0:10 and = 0:2.

(15)

15

Figure 2: Optimal investment in risky assets wRM() as a function of the risk aversion parameter p (between 0.1 and 0.6) and the maximum entropy distance

(between 0 and 0.03). The other parameters were set to % = 0:08, r = 0:05,

= 0:10 and = 0:2.

(16)

QUADERNI DELLA FACOLTA

I quaderni sono richiedibili (nell'edizione a stampa) alla Biblioteca universi- taria di Lugano via Ospedale 13 CH 6900 Lugano tel. +41 91 9124675 ; fax +41 91 9124647 ; e-mail: biblioteca@lu.unisi.ch

La versione elettronica (le PDF) e disponibile all'URL:

http://www.lu.unisi.ch/biblioteca/Pubblicazioni/f pubblicazioni.htm

The working papers (printed version) may be obtained by contacting the Bi- blioteca universitaria di Lugano via Ospedale 13 CH 6900 Lugano tel. +41 91 9124675 ; fax +41 91 9124647 ; e-mail: biblioteca@lu.unisi.ch

The electronic version (PDF les) is available at URL:

http://www.lu.unisi.ch/biblioteca/Pubblicazioni/f pubblicazioni.htm Quaderno n. 98-01

P. Balestra

, Ecient (and parsimonious) estimation of structural dyna- mic error component models

Quaderno n. 99-01

M. Filippini

, Cost and scale eciency in the nursing home sector: evi- dence from Switzerland

Quaderno n. 99-02

L. Bernardi

, I sistemi tributari di oggi: da dove vengono e dove vanno Quaderno n. 99-03

L. L. Pasinetti

, Economic theory and technical progress Quaderno n. 99-04

G. Barone-Adesi, K. Giannopoulos, L. Vosper

, VaR without corre- lations for portfolios of derivative securities

Quaderno n. 99-05

G. Barone-Adesi, Y. Kim

, Incomplete information and the closed-end fund discount

Quaderno n. 99-06

G. Barone-Adesi, W. Allegretto, E. Dinenis, G. Sorwar

, Valuation of derivatives based on CKLS interest rate models

Quaderno n. 99-07

M. Filippini, R.Maggi, J.Magerle

, Skalenertrage und optimale Be- triebsgrosse bei den schweizerische Privatbahnen

Quaderno n. 99-08

E. Ronchetti, F. Trojani

, Robust inference with GMM estimators

(17)

Quaderno n. 99-09

G.P. Torricelli

, I cambiamenti strutturali dello sviluppo urbano e re- gionale in Svizzera e nel Ticino sulla base dei dati dei censimenti federali delle aziende 1985, 1991 e 1995

Quaderno n. 99-10

M. Filippini, J. Wild

, Yardstick regulation of electricity distribution utilities based on the estimation of an average cost function

Quaderno n. 99-11

F. Trojani, P. Vanini

, A note on robustness in Merton's model of in- tertemporal consumption and portfolio choice

Références

Documents relatifs

In international emissions trading schemes such as the Kyoto Protocol and the European Union Emissions Trading Scheme, the suboptimal negotiation of the cap with respect to

Based upon two cases, their analysis reveals first that the large agent might manipulate the market by banking allowances when it owns all the stock of permits and second when

price-sensitivity and our structural estimates indicate that the clear majority of the effect of all of our treatments (whether depletion, sugar drink or placebo drink) is not on the

It would indeed seem that enhanced information work in the refugee law area serves the dual purpose of improving the legal protection of refugees in the present situation at

Remark 3.9 The i-reversal in Theorem 3.8 can even be supported by a discount func- tion satisfying decreasing impatience. Let endowment risk be increasing and let the DM’s

To improve quality, we need management science, clinical sciences such as medicine and nursing, clinical epidemiology, sociology and psychology of health, anthropology, human

L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, émanant des

A new methodology was developed to estimate and account for additive systematic model error in linear filtering as well as in nonlinear ensemble based data assimilation. In contrast