• Aucun résultat trouvé

80-646-08StochasticcalculusGeneviŁveGauthier Introductiontodiscrete-timemarketmodels:thebinomialmodel

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "80-646-08StochasticcalculusGeneviŁveGauthier Introductiontodiscrete-timemarketmodels:thebinomialmodel"

Copied!
86
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

model

Single-period binomial model Two-period binomial model

Introduction to discrete-time market models:

the binomial model

80-646-08 Stochastic calculus

Geneviève Gauthier

HEC Montréal

(2)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

The riskless security I

The market model

The stochastic process n

St(1) :t =0,1o

represents the evolution of the share price of a riskless security (a bond, for example).

Let’s assume that time is measured in periods (a period may be one year, one month, one day, one hour, one second, etc.)

And let’s assume that theperiodic interest rate r is constant during the process observation,

then

8ω2, S1(1)(ω) =S0(1)(ω) (1+r).

We can assume that8ω2,S0(1)(ω) =1 which implies that

8ω2Ω, S1(1)(ω) = (1+r).

(3)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

The risky security I

The market model

The second stochastic process n

St(2) :t =0,1o , for its part, represents the evolution of the share price of a risky security, St(2) being the price of a share at time t.

Since the current share price of that security is known with certainty,

8ω2 , S0(2)(ω) =s0 2R+= (0,∞).

We will assume that, in the next period, the share price of the risky security can only take one of two values, say s11

ands12 (s11,s12 2R+,s11 <s12).

(4)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Measurable space I

Question. What is the …ltered measurable space that allows us to model such a situation?

Answer. In this example, the random experiment is not clearly de…ned. However, if we consider the

two-dimensional stochastic process

!S

t =n St(1),St(2) :t =0,1o ,

we note that such a process has two di¤erent paths only, i.e.

S0(1),S0(2) > S1(1),S1(2) >

trajectoire #1 (1,s0)> (1+r,s11)>

trajectoire #2 (1,s0)> (1+r,s12)>

(5)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Measurable space II

As a consequence, if Card()>2, then there would be some identical paths, i.e.

9ω1,ω2 2such that 8t 2 f0,1g, !S

t (ω1) =!S

t(ω2) and, in such a case, even our largest source of information,

F1 =σ S0(1),S0(2),S1(1),S1(2) ,

could not distinguish between ω1 andω2 being realized.

(6)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Measurable space III

For that reason, we choose Card(Ω) =2 and

ω S0(1)(ω),S0(2)(ω) > S1(1)(ω),S1(2)(ω) >

ω1 (1,s0)> (1+r,s11)>

ω2 (1,s0)> (1+r,s12)>

This is not the only possible form for Ω, but this is a convenient one.

Grouping all undi¤erentiated ω under the same name is common practice. This is also one of the reasons why many people mix up the concepts of sample space and random variable.

(7)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Measurable space IV

By choosing such an Ω= fω1,ω2g, we will be able to distinguish which of its elements has occured after observing the process until maturity, i.e. untilt =1.

That’s why,

F1 = F

= fall events inΩg

= f?,fω1g,fω2g,g. Since the process S is constant at time t =0,F0 =f?,g.

(8)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

The portfolio I

Let

φ1 = the number of shares of the riskless security being held φ2 = the number of shares of the risky security being held.

De…nition The pair !

φ = (φ1,φ2)2R Ris called aportfolio.

Ifφi is negative, its means a short sale of φi shares of securityi has occurred.

The value of such a portfolio at timet is

Vφ(t,ω) =φ1St(1)(ω) +φ2St(2)(ω).

(9)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

The portfolio II

Since Vφ(0,ω) =φ1+φ2s0, we will need to pay out an amount of φ1+φ2s0 in order to acquire the portfolio ! φ ifφ1+φ2s0<0, we will receive an amount of

(φ1+φ2s0)in acquiring the portfolio ! φ.

(10)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Arbitrage opportunity

De…nition We say that !

φ is an arbitrage opportunity if (A1) 8ω 2, Vφ(0,ω) =0 (A2) 8ω 2, Vφ(1,ω) 0 (A3) 9ω2 Ω, Vφ(1,ω)>0,

i.e., starting from a zero investment(A1), we are certain not to incur a loss(A2) and we have a positive probability to make a gain (A3).

(11)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

What are the arbitrage opportunities in the model I

Condition (A1)implies that, for !

φ = (φ1,φ2)to be an arbitrage opportunity, we must have

φ1 = φ2s0 (1) since 0=Vφ(0,ω) =φ1+φ2s0.

It is to be noted as of now that condition (A3)ensures that (0,0)is not an arbitrage opportunity. As a result, ( φ2s0,φ2)cannot be an arbitrage opportunity ifφ2 =0.

So, let’s assume φ2 6=0.

(12)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

What are the arbitrage opportunities in the model II

From condition (A2), it follows that( φ2s0,φ2)is an arbitrage opportunity only if

Vφ(1,ω1) = φ2s0S1(1)(ω1) +φ2S1(2)(ω1)

= φ2s0(1+r) +φ2s11

= φ2(s11 s0(1+r)) 0 and

Vφ(1,ω2) = φ2s0S1(1)(ω2) +φ2S2(1,ω2)

= φ2s0(1+r) +φ2s12

= φ2(s12 s0(1+r)) 0.

Therefore, arbitrage will be possible only if

s12 >s11 s0(1+r)or ifs11 <s12 s0(1+r).

(13)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

What are the arbitrage opportunities in the model III

Adding the third condition (A3) implies that, if

s12 >s11 s0(1+r),then, for allφ2>0, the portfolio ( φ2s0,φ2)is an arbitrage opportunity since

Vφ(1,ω1) = φ2(s11 s0(1+r)) 0;

Vφ(1,ω2) = φ2(s12 s0(1+r))>0 and if s11 <s12 s0(1+r)then, for allφ2 <0,the portfolio ( φ2s0,φ2)is an arbitrage opportunity since

Vφ(1,ω1) = φ2(s11 s0(1+r))>0;

Vφ(1,ω2) = φ2(s12 s0(1+r)) 0.

(14)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

What are the arbitrage opportunities in the model IV

In other words, if s12 >s11 s0(1+r) then one just has to

sell shortns0 shares of the riskless security (borrow an amount ofns0 dollars)

and buynshares of the risky security for the same amount.

The amount to be paid out isVφ(0) = ns0 1+n s0 =0.

Att =1, we sell the shares of the risky security (we get nS1(2)(ω)dollars)

and pay back our loan, with interest (which amounts to ns0(1+r)dollars).

We therefore get a net amount of

nS1(2)(ω) ns0(1+r) =V( ns0,n)(1,ω)

= ns11 ns0(1+r) =n(s11 s0(1+r)) 0 if ω=ω1

ns12 ns0(1+r) =n(s12 s0(1+r))>0 if ω=ω2.

(15)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

What are the arbitrage opportunities in the model V

Ifs11 <s12 s0(1+r)then we can sell shortnshares of the risky security and

and invest the amount ofns0 thus obtained in purchasing ns0 shares of the riskless security:

Vφ(0) =ns0 1 n s0 =0.

At timet =1,an amount ofns0(1+r)dollars is obtained from selling the riskless security and we buy at a cost of nS1(2)(ω)thenshares of the risky security which we had sold short.

The net proceeds from such a transaction are

ns0(1+r) nS1(2)(ω)

= V(ns0, n)(1,ω)

= ns0(1+r) ns11=n(s0(1+r) s11)>0 siω=ω1

ns0(1+r) ns12=n(s0(1+r) s12) 0 siω=ω2.

(16)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

What are the arbitrage opportunities in the model VI

By contrast, if s11 <s0(1+r)<s12,there are no portfolios providing arbitrage opportunities since

Vφ(0) =0)φ1 = φ2s0.

Ifφ2=0,then Vφ(1,ω1) =Vφ(1,ω2) =0 and,

ifφ2 6=0,then Vφ(1,ω1) andVφ(1,ω2)cannot be both non-negative since

Vφ(1,ω1) = φ2(s11 s0(1+r))

| {z }

<0

andVφ(1,ω2) = φ2(s12 s0(1+r))

| {z }

>0

.

(17)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

What are the arbitrage opportunities in the model VII

In what follows, we will assume that our model contains no arbitrage opportunities, i.e.

s11 <s0(1+r)<s12. (2)

(18)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Contingent claim I

De…nition

Acontingent claim is a contract between two parties, a seller and a buyer, the value of which will depend on the state of the market during the contract validity period. It is like an

insurance contract.

Mathematically speaking, a contingent claim C is any non-negative (Ω,F) random variable.

(19)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Contingent claim II

For example, a put option is a contingent claim entered into by the two parties at time t =0, and allowing the buyer to sell, at time t=1,a share of the risky security at a price determined as of now, sayK,which is called the strike price.

Thus, ifS1(2)<K then the buyer will exercise his option and sell his risky security share for an amountK greater than the price he would obtain on the market.

By contrast, ifS1(2) K, the buyer will not exercise his option, since he can obtain on the market a better price than the one set by the contract.

Hence, the value of the put option is max K S1(2),0 . Obviously, the contingent claim seller will not o¤er such a bene…t to the buyer without being compensated. The amount paid out at timet =0 by the buyer to the seller in order to acquire the option is the contingent claim price.

(20)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Pricing

Contingent claim

Question. What is the contingent claim price?

(21)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Pricing I

The seller

Can the portfolio be chosen in such a way that its value at t=1 matches the contingent claim value? In the case when there are as many scenarios as securities, it is possible to obtain a single solution under certain conditions.

Ifci =C (ωi)then

8ω 2Ω,Vφ(1,ω) =C(ω)

, φ1(1+r) +φ2s11 =c1 andφ1(1+r) +φ2s12 =c2 , φ1

φ2 =

s12c1 s11c2

(s12 s11)(1+r) c2 c1

s12 s11

!

(22)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Pricing II

The seller

Thus, the value at timet =0 of such a portfolio is Vφ(0,ω)

= s12c1 s11c2

(s12 s11) (1+r)+ c2 c1 s12 s11s0

= c1 1+r

s12 s0(1+r) s12 s11

+ c2 1+r

s0(1+r) s11

s12 s11

. (3)

(23)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Risk-neutral measure I

So far, we have been working on a …ltered measurable space, and it has not been spoken of probability measure yet.

Let’s set

q = s12 s0(1+r) s12 s11

and note that the no-arbitrage condition is equivalent to the fact thatq is comprised between 0 and 1:

s11 <s0(1+r)<s12 ,0<q <1.

Thus, if Q(ω1) =q and Q(ω2) =1 q then Qis a probability measure built on our measurable space (Ω,F).

(24)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Risk-neutral measure II

It is important to note that Q(ω1)likely does not correspond to the ”real” probability that the event ω1

occurs.

Generally, that probability is not known.

Let’s call P the probability measure that associates to each ω in the sample space the ”real” probability that such an event occurs (P(ω1) =p and P(ω2) =1 p).

(25)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Risk-neutral measure III

As we have established in equation (3), the contingent claim price C is

c1

1+r

s12 s0(1+r) s12 s11 + c2

1+r

s0(1+r) s11

s12 s11

= c1 1+r

s12 s0(1+r) s12 s11 + c2

1+r 1 s12 s0(1+r) s12 s11

= c1

1+rq+ c2

1+r (1 q)

= EQ C

1+r = 1

1+rEQ[C].

So, the price of any contingent claim C is the expectation, under the measure Q, of that contingent claim discounted value 1C+r

(26)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Risk-neutral measure IV

Wonderful! Rather than having to solve an optimization problem in order to determine a contingent claim price, we just have to calculate an expectation, provided the

appropriate probability measure to be placed on our

…ltered measurable space is known.

(27)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Risk-neutral measure I

Why such a name?

Why such a name?

The return on a security during the time period going fromt 1 tot is de…ned as

RS(t,ω) = St(ω) St 1(ω) St 1(ω)

whereSt(ω)denotes the share price of the security at time t.

(28)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Risk-neutral measure II

Why such a name?

For any probability measure Pb, the expected return on the riskless security over the time period[0,1] is

EPb[RS(1)(1)] =

ω2

S1(1)(ω) S0(1)(ω) S0(1)(ω)

Pb(ω)

=

ω2

(1+r) 1 1 Pb(ω)

=

ω2

rPb(ω)

= r.

(29)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Risk-neutral measure III

Why such a name?

The expected return on the risky security, under the measurePb, is

EPb[RS(2)(1)] =

2 i=1

S1(2)(ωi) S0(2)(ωi) S0(2)(ωi)

Pb(ωi)

= s11 s0

s0 Pb(ω1) +s12 s0

s0 Pb(ω2).

(30)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Risk-neutral measure IV

Why such a name?

So, the ”true” expected return on the risky security is the one calculated under the measure P and it is equal to

EP[RS(2)(1)] = s11 s0

s0 P(ω1) + s12 s0

s0 P(ω2)

= s11 s0 s0

p+s12 s0 s0

(1 p)

= s11 s0 s0

s12 s0

s0 p+ s12 s0 s0

= s12 s0 s0

s12 s11 s0

p

and this latter quantity will be, in general, di¤erent fromr.

(31)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Risk-neutral measure V

Why such a name?

By contrast, the expected return on the risky security, calculated under the measure Q, is

EQ[RS(2)(1)]

= s11 s0

s0 Q(ω1) +s12 s0

s0 Q(ω2)

= s11 s0 s0

s12 s0(1+r) s12 s11 +s12 s0

s0

1 s12 s0(1+r) s12 s11

= r

which means that, on the space (Ω,F,Q), there is no bene…t associated with risk, the expected return on the risky security is the same as the one on the riskless security.

(32)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Martingale measure I

Why such a name?

Why such a name?

Because, on the …ltered probability space(Ω,F,F,Q), the discounted price processes of the securities S(

i) t

(1+r)t :t=0,1 are martingales.

(33)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Martingale measure II

Why such a name?

Proof. In the case of the riskless security,

EQ

"

S1(1) 1+r F0

#

= EQ 1+r 1+r F0

= 1

= S

(1) 0

(1+r)0.

(34)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Martingale measure III

Why such a name?

With respect to the risky security,

EQ

"

S1(2) 1+r F0

#

= EQ

"

S1(2) 1+r

#

=

2 i=1

S1(2)(ωi) 1+r Q(ωi)

= s11

1+rQ(ω1) + s12 1+rQ(ω2)

= s11 1+r

s12 s0(1+r) s12 s11

+ s12 1+r

s0(1+r) s11 s12 s11

= s0

= S

(2) 0

(1+r)0.

(35)

model

Single-period binomial model

Prices Measurable space Portfolio Arbitrage Contingent claim Pricing Risk-neutral measure

Martingale measure Discount factor Two-period binomial model

Discount factor

We have seen that, if the model contains no arbitrage opportunities, then there exists a probability measureQ such that the contingent claim price at time 0 is the expectation of the discounted value of its future cash ‡ows

Price=EQ C 1+r .

But, under the « true» probability measure P,there is no reason to discount the future cash ‡ows with a discount factor based on the riskless interest rate since the contingent claim is a risky asset.

The contingent claim price could be obtained by taking the expectation, under the measure P, of the discounted value of its future cash ‡ow.

The problem in this case is to determine the discount factor.

(36)

model

Single-period binomial model Two-period binomial model

The model Measurable space Example Predictable process Trading strategy Example Arbitrage Risk-neutral measure Pricing

The riskless security

The model

The stochastic process n

St(1) :t =0,1,2o

represents the evolution of the share price of a riskless security.

Let’s assume that the periodic interest rater is constant during the process observation and that

8ω 2, S0(1)(ω) =1, then

8ω 2, St(1)(ω) = (1+r)t.

(37)

model

Single-period binomial model Two-period binomial model

The model Measurable space Example Predictable process Trading strategy Example Arbitrage Risk-neutral measure Pricing

The risky security I

The model

The second stochastic process n

St(2) :t =0,1,2o , for its part, represents the evolution of the share price of a risky security, St(2) being the share price of the security at time t.

Since the current share price of such as security is know with certainty,

8ω2 , S0(2)(ω) =s0 2R+= (0,∞).

We assume that, in the following period, i.e. at t =1, the share price of the risky security can only take one of two values, says11 and s12 (s11,s12 2R+,s11 <s12).

(38)

model

Single-period binomial model Two-period binomial model

The model Measurable space Example Predictable process Trading strategy Example Arbitrage Risk-neutral measure Pricing

The risky security II

The model

We assume that, in the second period, i.e. att =2, there are only four possible values for the share price of the security, says21,s22 (if S1(2) =s11), s23 ands24 (if S1(2) =s12) subject to the constraintss21,s22,s23, s24 2R+,s21 <s22,s23 <s24.

(39)

model

Single-period binomial model Two-period binomial model

The model Measurable space Example Predictable process Trading strategy Example Arbitrage Risk-neutral measure Pricing

The risky security III

The model

ω S0(1)(ω) S0(2)(ω)

!

S1(1)(ω) S1(2)(ω)

!

S2(1)(ω) S2(2)(ω)

!

ω1 (1,s0)> (1+r,s11)> (1+r)2,s21

>

ω2 (1,s0)> (1+r,s11)> (1+r)2,s22 >

ω3 (1,s0)> (1+r,s12)> (1+r)2,s23

>

ω4 (1,s0)> (1+r,s12)> (1+r)2,s24 >

(40)

model

Single-period binomial model Two-period binomial model

The model Measurable space Example Predictable process Trading strategy Example Arbitrage Risk-neutral measure Pricing

Filtered measurable space

The model

As we have previously argued, we can justify choosing as sample space Ω=fω1,ω2,ω3,ω4g.

The sigma-algebra F is the set of all events in Ω and the …ltrationF =fFt :t =0,1,2gconsists of the following sigma-algebras of F:

F0 =f?,g,

F1 =σffω1,ω2g,fω3,ω4ggand F2 =F.

(41)

model

Single-period binomial model Two-period binomial model

The model Measurable space Example Predictable process Trading strategy Example Arbitrage Risk-neutral measure Pricing

Example

The model

Ifr =10%then ω S0(1)(ω)

S0(2)(ω)

!

S1(1)(ω) S1(2)(ω)

!

S2(1)(ω) S2(2)(ω)

!

ω1 (1;2)> (1,1;2)> (1,21;1)>

ω2 (1;2)> (1,1;2)> (1,21;3)>

ω3 (1;2)> (1,1;4)> (1,21;1)>

ω4 (1;2)> (1,1;4)> (1,21;5)>.

(42)

model

Single-period binomial model Two-period binomial model

The model Measurable space Example Predictable process Trading strategy Example Arbitrage Risk-neutral measure Pricing

Notation

The riskless security

De…nition

A stochastic processX =fXt :t =0,1,2, ...g built on a measurable space(Ω,F) is said to bepredictable with respect to the …ltrationfFt :t =0,1,2, ...g ifX0 is a (Ω,F0) random variable and 8t 2 f1,2, ...g,Xt is a (Ω,Ft 1) random variable.

(43)

model

Single-period binomial model Two-period binomial model

The model Measurable space Example Predictable process Trading strategy Example Arbitrage Risk-neutral measure Pricing

Trading strategy I

The predictable stochastic processes n

φ(t1) :t=0,1,2o and n

φ(t2):t =0,1,2o

represent the evolution of our portfolio over time:

φ(1)t = number of shares of the riskless security held during the time period(t 1,t],

φ(2)t = number of shares of the risky security held during the time period(t 1,t].

Exceptionally, the portfolio !

φ0 = φ10,φ20 is only held at time t =0. In practice, we will set !

φ0 = ! φ1.

Références

Documents relatifs

In other words, transport occurs with finite speed: that makes a great difference with the instantaneous positivity of solution (related of a “infinite speed” of propagation

- A 2-dimensional Brownian motion, run for infinite time, almost surely contains no line segment... similarly the probability of covering at least 0N of these N

Under suitable boundary conditions and assuming a maximum principle for the interior points, we obtain a uniform convergence similar to that of Theorem 1.1.. Theorem 2.1 below can

When the vector field Z is holomorphic the real vector fields X and Y (cf. This follows from a straightforward computation in local coordinates.. Restriction to the

Delano¨e [4] proved that the second boundary value problem for the Monge-Amp`ere equation has a unique smooth solution, provided that both domains are uniformly convex.. This result

First introduced by Faddeev and Kashaev [7, 9], the quantum dilogarithm G b (x) and its variants S b (x) and g b (x) play a crucial role in the study of positive representations

If there is no nonconstant invariant rational function under f , then there exists a closed point in the plane whose orbit under f is Zariski dense1. This result gives us a

McCoy [17, Section 6] also showed that with sufficiently strong curvature ratio bounds on the initial hypersur- face, the convergence result can be established for α &gt; 1 for a