• Aucun résultat trouvé

Portfolio insurance

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "Portfolio insurance"

Copied!
41
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

Introduction to portfolio insurance

(2)

Portfolio insurance

Maintain the portfolio value above a certain

predetermined level (floor) while allowing some upside potential.

Performance may be compared to a stock market

index, or may be guaranteed explicitly in terms of this index.

Usually implementented via strategic allocation

between the benchmark index, risk-free account and (possibly) option on the benchmark index.

(3)

Portfolio insurance example (equity)

Example: Hawaii 3 fund marketed by BNP Paribas:

At maturity, the value of the fund will be greater or equal to the largest of:

105% of the initial value. ⇐ less than the risk-free return over the holding period.

85% of the highest value attained by the Fund

between 23/01/2007 and 3/07/2013 ⇐ floor can be adjusted throughout the life of the portfolio

The portfolio protection is valid only at maturity.

(4)

Portfolio insurance example (cont’d)

Objective: benefit from the performance of a basket (DJ Euro STOXX 50, S&P 500 and Nikkei 225) while ensuring minimum annual performance of 0.7%.

Danger of monetarization: to satisfy the insurance constraint, the exposure to risky asset may become and remain zero.

Even if the Fund performance depends partially on the Basket, it can be different due to capital insurance.

Strategy: The Fund will be actively managed using portfolio insurance techniques.

(5)

Portfolio insurance techniques

Stop-loss (for someone who doesn’t know stochastic calculus).

Option-based portfolio insurance (OBPI).

OBPI with option replication.

Constant proportion portfolio insurance (CPPI).

(6)

Stop-loss strategy

(7)

Stop-loss strategy

The simplest and the most intuitive strategy but its cost is difficult to quantify in practice.

The entire portfolio is initially invested into the risky asset.

As soon as the risky asset St drops below the floor Ft, the entire position is rebalanced into the risk-free

asset.

If the market rebounds above the floor, the fund is reinvested into risky assets.

(8)

Stop-loss strategy

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0

0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3

Stock Floor Fund

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0

0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.3

Stock Floor Fund

Stop-loss strategy in ’theory’ (left) and in practice.

(9)

The loss is not stopped

The cost of stop-loss can be quantified via the Itô-Tanaka formula:

max(St, F) =

Z t

0

1Ss≥FdSs + 1 2Lt,

where L is the local time of S at F (increasing process).

• The price (risk-neutral expectation) of the loss equals to the price of an at the money call option on the index.

(10)

Option-based portfolio insurance

(11)

Basic strategy with European guarantee

Let K be the floor (with KB(0, T) < 1).

Invest a fraction λ of the fund into the index S.

Use the remainder to buy a Put on λS.

The total cost is

f(λ) = λ + PλS(T, K)

increasing function with f(0) = KB(0, T) < 1 and f(1) = 1 + PS(T, K) > 1.

⇒ There exists a unique λ ∈ (0, 1), realizing the put-based strategy.

(12)

Optimality of the put-based strategy

Let u(x) = x1−γ1γ and let ST be the optimal unconstrained portfolio:

E[u(ST )] = max E[u(XT )] subject to X0 = 1.

Then the put-based strategy is the optimal strategy subject to the floor constraint (El Karoui, Jeanblanc, Lacoste ’05).

(13)

Equivalent strategy using calls

By put-call parity, the put-based strategy is equivalent to:

Buy zero-coupon with notional K to lock in the capital at maturity

Use the remainder to buy a call on λST with strike K (or anything else!).

Often, at-the-money calls are used; fund’s performance is then proportional to the risky asset performance:

VT = 1 + k(ST − 1)+, k = 1 − B(0, T)

C(T ) < 1.

k is called gearing or indexation.

(14)

The gearing factor

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

0.35 0.40 0.45 0.50 0.55 0.60 0.65 0.70 0.75 0.80 0.85

T

k

0.010 0.015 0.020 0.025 0.030 0.035 0.040 0.045 0.050 0.055 0.060 0.2

0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

r

k

Dependence of the indexation k on the time to maturity (left) and the interest rate (right). Other parameters: K = S0, σ = 0.2, r = 4% (left) and T = 5 years (right).

(15)

American capital guarantee

One cannot simply buy and hold an American put because it is not self-financing.

The correct strategy is dynamic trading in S and American puts on S:

Vt = λtSt + P a(t, λtSt), λt = λ0 ∨ sup

u≤t

b(u) Su

, where b(t) is the exercise boundary and λ0 is chosen from the budget constraint.

This self-financing strategy, satisfies Vt ≥ K, 0 ≤ t ≤ T

and is optimal for power utility in complete markets (EKJL).

(16)

Replicating options

Danger of the OBPI approach: absence of liquid options for long maturities (especially in the credit world)

Counterparty risk if the option is bought over-the-counter

Marking-to-market difficult at intermediate dates

Common solution: replicate the option with a self-financing portfolio containing ∆(St) stocks.

(17)

OBPI with option replication

Advantages:

No need to structure a long-dated option

The portfolio is easy to mark to market and liquidate Drawbacks:

The replication is only approximate, especially in incomplete markets

Transaction costs may be high

Model-dependent

(18)

Constant proportion portfolio

insurance

(19)

The basic CPPI strategy

Introduced by Black and Jones (87) and Perold (86).

A fixed amount N is guaranteed at maturity T.

At every t, a fraction is invested into risky asset St and the remainder into zero-coupon bond with maturity T and nominal N (denoted by Bt).

If Vt > Bt, the risky asset exposure is mCt ≡ m(Vt − Bt), with m > 1.

If Vt ≤ Bt, the entire portfolio is invested into the zero-coupon.

(20)

Features and extensions

Model-independent (for continuous processes).

Maturity-independent, open-entry and open-exit.

Greater upward potential than OBPI: while in OBPI the exposure is limited to the indexation k < 1, the CPPI exposure in bullish markets is only limited by the

multiplier.

Variable floor (ratchet) easily incorporated.

(21)

Analysis of CPPI: Gaussian setting

Suppose that the interest rate r is constant and dSt

St = µdt + σdWt. Then the fund’s evolution is given by

dVt = m(Vt − Bt)dSt

St + (Vt − m(Vt − Bt))rdt.

Ct satisfies the Black-Scholes SDE:

dCt

Ct = (mµ + (1 − m)r)dt + mσdWt.

(22)

Analysis of CPPI: Gaussian setting

In the Black-Scholes model, CPPI strategy is equivalent to

Buying a zero-coupon with nominal N to guarantee the capital at maturity (superhedging the floor);

Investing the remaining sum into a risky asset which has m times the excess return and m times the

volatility of S and is perfectly correlated with S.

(23)

Analysis of CPPI: Gaussian setting

The portfolio value is explicitly given by

VT = N+(V0−N e−rT) exp

rT + m(µ − r)T + mσWT − m2σ2T 2

. which can be rewritten as

VT = N + (V0 − N e−rT)Cm

ST S0

m

, where

Cm = exp

−(m − 1)rT − (m2 − m)σ2 2 T

.

(24)

Gain profiles of the CPPI strategy

−0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0

100 110 120 130 140 150 160

m=4 m=6 m=2 OBPI

0 2 4 6 8 10 12

100 150 200 250 300 350 400

m

Return = 0%

Return = 100%

Return = 200%

Left: CPPI portfolio as a function of stock return. Right CPPI portfolio return as a function of multiplier for given stock re- turn. Parameters are r = 0.03, σ = 0.2, T = 5.

(25)

Optimality of CPPI

The CPPI strategy can be shown to be optimal in the context of long-term risk-sensitive portfolio optimization (Grossman and Vila ’92, Sekine ’08):

sup

π∈A

lim sup

T→∞

1

γT log E (XTx,π)γ (RS)

The optimal strategy π and the value function do not depend on the initial value x > 0.

In the Black-Scholes setting, the Merton strategy πσ2µ−r(1−γ) is optimal.

(26)

Optimality of CPPI

For the problem (RS) under the constraint Xtx,π ≥ Kt for all t, an optimal strategy is described by

Superhedge the floor process with any portfolio K¯ satisfying K¯0 < x.

Invest x − K¯0 into the unconstrained optimal portfolio.

In the Black-Scholes model ⇒ classical CPPI with multiplier given by the Merton portfolio π.

Extension by Grossman and Zhou ’93 and Cvitanic and Karatzas ’96: the CPPI strategy with stochastic floor is optimal for (RS) in case of drawdown constraints.

(27)

Optimality of CPPI: critique

Merton’s multiplier may be too low: it results from the unconstrained problem which takes into account both gains and losses, and under the floor constraint

investors accept greater risks to maximize gains.

In models with jumps, the positivity constraint often implies 0 ≤ π ≤ 1, which is not sufficient for CPPI ⇒ one may want to authorise some gap risk ⇒

optimisation under VaR constraint.

Market practice is to use basic CPPI with m fixed as function of the VaR constraint.

(28)

Some explicit computations for

CPPI with jumps

(29)

Introducing jumps

Suppose that S and B may be written as dSt

St− = dZt and dBt

Bt = dRt,

where Z is a semimartingale with ∆Z > −1 and R is a continuous semimartingale.

This implies

Bt = B0 exp

Rt − 1

2[R]t

> 0.

Example: Rt = rt and Z is a Lévy process.

(30)

Stochastic differential equation

Let τ = inf{t : Vt ≤ Bt}. Then, up to time τ, dVt = m(Vt− − Bt−)dSt

St− + {Vt− − m(Vt− − Bt−)}dBt Bt− , which can be rewritten as

dCt

Ct− = mdZt + (1 − m)dRt. where Ct = Vt − Bt is the cushion.

(31)

Solution via change of numeraire

Writing Ct = CBt

t and applying Itô formula, dCt

Ct− = m(dZt − d[Z, R]t − dRt + d[R]t) := mdLt, which can be written as

Ct = C0E(mL)t,

where E denotes the stochastic exponential:

E(X)t = X0eXt12[X]ct Y

s≤t,∆Xs6=0

(1 + ∆Xs)e−∆Xs.

(32)

Solution via change of numeraire

After time τ, the process C remains constant. Therefore, the portfolio value can be written explicitly as

Ct = C0E(mL)t∧τ, or again as

Vt

Bt = 1 +

V0

B0 − 1

E(mL)t∧τ.

(33)

Probability of loss

Proposition Let L = Lc + Lj, with Lc continuous and Lj independent Lévy process with Lévy measure ν. Then

P[∃t ∈ [0, T] : Vt ≤ Bt] = 1 − exp −T

Z −1/m

−∞

ν(dx)

! .

In Lévy models, the basic CPPI has constant loss probability per unit time.

(34)

Probability of loss

Proof: Vt ≤ Bt ⇐⇒ Ct ≤ 0 ⇐⇒

Ct = C0E(mL)t ≤ 0.

But since

∆E(X)t = E(X)t−(1 + ∆Xt), this is equivalent to ∆Ljt ≤ −1/m.

For a Lévy process Lj, the number of such jumps in the interval [0, T] is a Poisson random variable with intensity T R −1/m

−∞ ν(dx).

(35)

Example: Kou’s model

ν(x) = λ(1 − p)

η+ e−x/η+1x>0 + λp

ηe−|x|/η1x<0.

2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5 5.0 5.5 6.0 6.5 7.0

0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25

Microsoft General Motors Shanghai Composite

Loss probability over T = 5 years as function of the multiplier.

(36)

Stochastic volatility and variable

multiplier strategies

(37)

Stochastic volatility via time change

The traditional stochastic volatility model dSS t

t = σtdWt can be equivalently written as

St = X(vt) where vt =

Z t

0

σs2ds and dX(t)

X(t) = dWt. Similarly, Carr et al.(2003) construct stochastic volatility models with jumps from a jump-diffusion model:

St = E(L)vt, vt =

Z t

0

σs2ds, L is a jump-diffusion.

• The stochastic volatility determines the intensity of jumps

(38)

The Heston parameterization

The volatility process most commonly used is the square root process

t2 = k(θ − σt2)dt + δσtdW.

The Laplace transform of integrated variance v is known:

L(σ, t, u) =

exp

k2θt δ2

cosh γt2 + γk sinh γt2 2kθ

δ2

exp − 2σ02u

k + γ coth γt2

!

where L(σ, t, u) := E[e−uvt0 = σ] and γ := √

k2 + 2δ2u.

(39)

Loss probability with stochastic vol

If the volatility is stochastic, the loss probability

P [∃s ∈ [t, T] : Vs ≤ Bs|Ft] = 1−exp −(T − t)

Z −1/m

−∞

ν(dx)

!

becomes volatility dependent

P[∃s ∈ [t, T] : Vs ≤ Bs|Ft] = 1 − L(σt, T − t,

Z −1/m

−∞

ν(dx))

• Crucial for long-term investments: a two-fold increase in volatility may increase the loss probability from 5% to 20%.

(40)

Managing the volatility exposure

The vol exposure can be controlled by varying the multiplier mt: the loss probability is

P[τ ≤ T] = 1 − E

"

exp −

Z T 0

dt σt2

Z 1/mt

−∞

ν(dx)

!#

. The loss event is characterized by hazard rate λt,

interpreted as the probability of loss “per unit time”:

λt = σt2

Z 1/mt

−∞

ν(dx)

(41)

Managing the volatility exposure

The fund manager can control the local loss probability and the local VaR by choosing mt as a function of σt to keep

the hazard rate λt constant:

σt2

Z 1/mt

−∞

ν(dx) = σ02

Z 1/m0

−∞

ν(dx),

where m0 is the initial multiplier fixed according to the de- sired loss probability level. If the jump size distribution is α-stable, the above formula amounts to mt = m0

σt

σ0

−2/α

.

Références

Documents relatifs

In fact, the absence of state variables and the hypothesis of independence between the risk over wage rates and risks existing in the training process, and also the assumption

Contrary to standard approx- imation around the deterministic steady- state, net foreign assets are well defined at the risky steady-state and are stationary.. We believe that such

As in the case of non-life insurance with exponential claims, the ruin probabilities are either decreasing with a rate given by a power function (the case of small volatility) or

Classically, a Poisson process with drift was used to model the value of an insurance company and in that case, under some assumptions on the parameters of the process, the

A take-up rate model is then developed by introducing the two following explanatory variables: the average premium amount and the subjective annual occurrence probability, defined

Higher is the market price of risk in the insurance linked securities market, higher is the cost of capital rate, whatever the return period.. Our results differ

[r]

By applying the traditional and the generalized version of the capital asset pricing model, a class of premium principles can be derived1. This class is fully compatible with