• Aucun résultat trouvé

Nonequilibrium phase transition in negotiation dynamics Andrea Baronchelli,

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "Nonequilibrium phase transition in negotiation dynamics Andrea Baronchelli,"

Copied!
4
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

Nonequilibrium phase transition in negotiation dynamics

Andrea Baronchelli,1,2Luca Dall’Asta,3,4Alain Barrat,3,5and Vittorio Loreto1

1Dipartimento di Fisica, “Sapienza” Università di Roma and SMC-INFM, P.le A. Moro 2, 00185 Roma, Italy

2Departament de Física i Enginyeria Nuclear, Universitat Politècnica de Catalunya, Campus Nord B4, 08034 Barcelona, Spain

3LPT, CNRS (UMR 8627) and Univ Paris-Sud, Orsay, F-91405, France

4Abdus Salam International Center for Theoretical Physics, Strada Costiera 11, 34014, Trieste, Italy

5Complex Networks Lagrange Laboratory, ISI Foundation, Turin, Italy 共Received 2 November 2006; published 5 November 2007兲

We introduce a model of negotiation dynamics whose aim is that of mimicking the mechanisms leading to opinion and convention formation in a population of individuals. The negotiation process, as opposed to

“herdinglike” or “bounded confidence” driven processes, is based on a microscopic dynamics where memory and feedback play a central role. Our model displays a nonequilibrium phase transition from an absorbing state in which all agents reach a consensus to an active stationary state characterized either by polarization or fragmentation in clusters of agents with different opinions. We show the existence of at least two different universality classes, one for the case with two possible opinions and one for the case with an unlimited number of opinions. The phase transition is studied analytically and numerically for various topologies of the agents’

interaction network. In both cases the universality classes do not seem to depend on the specific interaction topology, the only relevant feature being the total number of different opinions ever present in the system.

DOI:10.1103/PhysRevE.76.051102 PACS number共s兲: 64.60.Cn, 89.65.Ef, 05.70.Ln, 89.75.Hc

Statistical physics has recently proved to be a powerful framework to address issues related to the characterization of the collective social behavior of individuals, such as culture dissemination, the spreading of linguistic conventions, and the dynamics of opinion formation关1兴.

According to the “herding behavior” described in sociol- ogy关2兴, processes of opinion formation are usually modeled as simple collective dynamics in which the agents update their opinions following local majority关3兴or imitation rules 关4兴. Starting from random initial conditions, the system self- organizes through an ordering process eventually leading to the emergence of a global consensus, in which all agents share the same opinion. In analogy with kinetic Ising models and contact processes关5兴, the presence of noise can induce nonequilibrium phase transitions from the consensus state to disordered configurations, in which more than one opinion is present.

The principle of “bounded confidence”关6,7兴, on the other hand, consists in enabling interactions only between agents that share already some cultural features共defined as discrete objects兲 关8兴or with not too different opinions 共in a continu- ous space兲 关6,9兴. By tuning some threshold parameter, tran- sitions are observed concerning the number of opinions sur- viving in the共frozen兲final state关10兴. This can be a situation of consensus, in which all agents share the same opinion, polarization, in which a finite number of groups with differ- ent opinions survive, or fragmentation, with a final number of opinions scaling with the system size.

In this paper, we propose a model of opinion dynamics in which a consensus-polarization-fragmentation nonequilib- rium phase transition is driven by external noise, intended as an “irresolute attitude” of the agents in making decisions.

The primary attribute of the model is that it is based on a negotiation process, in which memory and feedback play a central role. Moreover, apart from the consensus state, no configuration is frozen: the stationary states with several co- existing opinions are still dynamical, in the sense that the

agents are still able to evolve, in contrast to the Axelrod model关8兴.

Let us consider a population of N agents, each one en- dowed with a memory, in which ana prioriundefined num- ber of opinions can be stored. In the initial state, agents memories are empty. At each time step, an ordered pair of neighboring agents is randomly selected. This choice is con- sistent with the idea of directed attachment in the sociopsy- chological literature共see, for instance, Ref.关11兴兲. The nego- tiation process is described by a local pairwise interaction rule:共a兲the first agent selects randomly one of its opinions 共or creates a new opinion if its memory is empty兲and con- veys it to the second agent; 共b兲 if the memory of the latter contains such an opinion, with probability␤ the two agents update their memories erasing all opinions except the one involved in the interaction共agreement兲, while with probabil- ity 1 −␤ nothing happens; 共c兲 if the memory of the second agent does not contain the uttered opinion, it adds such an opinion to those already stored in its memory 共learning兲.

Note that in the special case␤= 1, the negotiation rule re- duces to the naming game rule关12兴, a model used to describe the emergence of a communication system or a set of linguis- tic conventions in a population of individuals. In our model- ing the parameter␤plays roughly the same role as the prob- ability of acknowledged influence in the sociopsychological literature关11兴. Furthermore, as already stated for other mod- els关13兴, when the system is embedded in heterogeneous to- pologies, different pair selection criteria influence the dy- namics. In the direct strategy, the first agent is picked up randomly in the population, and the second agent is ran- domly selected among its neighbors. The opposite choice is called reverse strategy; while the neutral strategy consists in randomly choosing a link, assigning it an order with equal probability. At the beginning of the dynamics, a large num- ber of opinions is created, the total number of different opin- ions growing rapidly up to O共N兲. Then, if␤ is sufficiently large, the number of opinions decreases until only one is left PHYSICAL REVIEW E76, 051102共2007兲

1539-3755/2007/76共5兲/051102共4兲 051102-1 ©2007 The American Physical Society

(2)

and the consensus state is reached共as for the naming game in the case␤= 1兲. In the opposite limit, when␤= 0, opinions are never eliminated, therefore the only possible stationary state is the trivial state in which every agent possesses all opin- ions. Thus, a nonequilibrium phase transition is expected for some critical value␤cof the parameter ␤governing the up- date efficiency. In order to find␤c, we exploit the following general stability argument. Let us consider the consensus state, in which all agents possess the same unique opinion, sayA. Its stability may be tested by considering a situation in whichA and another opinion, sayB, are present in the sys- tem: each agent can have either only opinionAorB, or both 共ABstate兲. The critical value␤cis provided by the threshold value at which the perturbed configuration with these three possible states does not converge back to consensus.

The simplest assumption in modeling a population of agents is the homogeneous mixing关i.e., mean-field共MF兲ap- proximation兴, where the behavior of the system is completely described by the following evolution equations for the den- sitiesniof agents with the opinioni:

dnA/dt= −nAnB+␤nAB2 +3␤− 1 2 nAnAB,

dnB/dt= −nAnB+␤nAB

2 +3␤− 1

2 nBnAB, 共1兲 and nAB= 1 −nAnB. Imposing the steady state condition A=B= 0, we get three possible solutions:共1兲nA= 1,nB= 0, nAB= 0; 共2兲 nA= 0, nB= 1, nAB= 0; and 共3兲 nA=nB=b共␤兲, nAB= 1 − 2b共␤兲withb共␤兲=1+5␤−1+10␤+17␤4␤ 2关andb共0兲= 0兴. The study of the solutions’ stability predicts a phase transition at

c= 1 / 3. The maximum nonzero eigenvalue of the linearized system around the consensus solution becomes indeed posi- tive for ␤⬍1 / 3, i.e., the consensus becomes unstable, and the population polarizes in the nA=nB state, with a finite density of undecided agents nAB. The model therefore dis- plays a first order nonequilibrium transition between the fro- zen absorbing consensus state and an active polarized state, in which global observables are stationary on average, but not frozen, i.e., the population is split in three dynamically evolving parts共with opinionsA,B, andAB兲, whose densities fluctuate around the average valuesb共␤兲and 1 − 2b共␤兲.

We have checked the predictions of Eqs.共1兲by numerical simulations ofNagents interacting on a complete graph. Fig- ure1 shows that the convergence timetconv required by the system to reach the consensus state indeed diverges at

c= 1 / 3, with a power-law behavior共␤c−a,a⯝0.3关18兴.

Very interestingly however, the analytical and numerical analysis of Eqs.共1兲predicts that the relaxation time diverges instead as共␤−␤c−1. This apparent discrepancy arises in fact because Eqs. 共1兲 consider that the agents have at most two different opinions at the same time, while this number is unlimited in the original model共and in fact diverges withN兲.

Numerical simulations reproducing the two opinions case al- low us to recover the behavior oftconvpredicted from Eq.共1兲 共see Fig.1兲. We have also investigated the case of a finite numbermof opinions available to the agents. The analytical result a= 1 holds also for m= 3 共but analytical analysis for

largermbecomes out of reach兲, whereas preliminary numeri- cal simulations performed for m= 3 , 10 with the largest reachable population size 共N= 106兲 lead to an exponent a⯝0.74– 0.8 共see Fig. 1兲. More extensive and systematic simulations are in order to determine the possible existence of a series of universality classes varying the memory size for the agents. In any case, the models with finite共mopin- ions兲or unlimited memory define at least two clearly differ- ent universality classes for this nonequilibrium phase transi- tion between consensus and polarized states 共see Ref. 关14兴 for similar findings in the framework of nonequilibrium q-state systems兲.

Figure2moreover shows that the transition at␤cis only the first of a series of transitions: when decreasing␤⬍␤c, a system starting from empty initial conditions self-organizes into a fragmented state with an increasing number of opin- ions. In principle, this can be shown analytically considering the mean-field evolution equations for the partial densities whenm⬎2 opinions are present, and studying, as a function of␤, the sign of the eigenvalues of a共2m− 1兲⫻共2m− 1兲sta-

10 10 10

10-3-3-3-3 10101010-2-2-2-2 10101010-1-1-1-1 101010100000 βββ

β----ββββcccc 10

10 10 108888 10 10 10 109999 10 10 10 1010101010 10 10 10 1011111111

ttttconvconvconvconv

y ~ x y ~ x y ~ x y ~ x-0.30-0.30-0.30-0.30 y ~ x y ~ x y ~ x y ~ x-0.91-0.91-0.91-0.91 y ~ x y ~ x y ~ x y ~ x-0.81-0.81-0.81-0.81 y ~ x y ~ x y ~ x y ~ x-0.74-0.74-0.74-0.74

10 10 10

10-3-3-3-3 10101010-2-2-2-2 10101010-1-1-1-1 101010100000 βββ

β----ββββcccc 10

10 10 108888 10 10 10 109999 10 10 10 1010101010 10 10 10 1011111111

ttttconvconvconvconv

invention (N = 10 invention (N = 10 invention (N = 10 invention (N = 105555)))) m = 2 (N = 10 m = 2 (N = 10 m = 2 (N = 10 m = 2 (N = 106666)))) m = 3 (N = 10 m = 3 (N = 10 m = 3 (N = 10 m = 3 (N = 106666)))) m = 10 (N = 10 m = 10 (N = 10 m = 10 (N = 10 m = 10 (N = 106666))))

FIG. 1.共Color online兲Convergence timetconvof the model as a function of␤−␤c 共with ␤c= 1 / 3兲 in the case of a fully connected population of N agents. We show data for the original model 共circles兲with unlimited number of opinions per agent, and for mod- els with a finite numbermof different opinions. Increasingm, the power-law fits give exponents that differ considerably from the value −1.

0.2 0.3 0.4

0.2 0.3 0.4

0.2 0.3 0.4

0.2 ββββ 0.3 0.4

10 10 10 105555 10 10 10 107777 10 10 10 109999

tttt

mmmm

ttt t1111 ttt

t2222 ttt t3333 ttt

t9999 tttt7777 ttt t8888 tttt6666

ttt t5555

ttt t4444

FIG. 2. 共Color online兲 Time tm required to a population on a fully-connected graph to reach a共fragmented兲active stationary state withmdifferent opinions. For everym⬎2, the timetmdiverges at some critical value␤cm兲⬍␤c.

BARONCHELLIet al. PHYSICAL REVIEW E76, 051102共2007兲

051102-2

(3)

bility matrix for the stationary state with m opinions. For increasing values ofm, such a calculation becomes rapidly very demanding, thus we limit our analysis to the numerical insights of Fig.2, from which we also get that the number of residual opinions in the fragmented state follows the expo- nential law m共␤兲⬀exp关共␤c−␤兲/C兴, where C is a constant depending on the initial conditions共not shown兲.

We now extend our analysis to more general interactions topologies, in which agents are placed on the vertices of a network, and the edges define the possible interaction pat- terns. When the network is a homogeneous random one 关Erdös-Rényi 共ER兲 graph 关15兴兴, the degree distribution is peaked around a typical value具k典, and the evolution equa- tions for the densities when only two opinions are present provide the same transition value␤c= 1 / 3 and the same ex- ponent −1 for the divergence oftconvas in MF. Figure3also shows that the exponent is also the MF one when the number of opinions is not limited.

Since any real negotiation process takes place on social groups, whose topology is generally far from being homoge- neous, we have simulated the model on various uncorrelated heterogeneous networks 关using the uncorrelated configura- tion model 共UCM兲 关16兴兴, with power-law degree distribu- tionsP共k兲⬃k−␥with exponents␥= 2.5 and␥= 3.

Very interestingly, the model still presents a consensus- polarization transition, in contrast with other opinion- dynamics models, such as for instance, the Axelrod model 关17兴, for which the transition disappears for heterogeneous networks in the thermodynamic limit. Moreover, Fig. 3 re- ports the convergence timetconvvs共␤−␤c−a, showing that at least two different universality classes are again present, one for the case with a finite共m= 2兲 number of opinions共a= 1兲 and one for the case with unlimited memory共a⯝0.3兲. The exponents measured are in each case compatible 共up to the numerical precision兲 with the corresponding MF exponents 共see Fig.3兲.

To understand these numerical results, we analyze, as for the fully connected case, the evolution equations for the case

of two possible opinions. Such equations can be written for general correlated complex networks whose topology is completely defined by the degree distribution P共k兲, i.e., the probability that a node has degree k, and by the degree- degree conditional probabilityP共k

k兲that a node of degree k

is connected to a node of degreek共Markovian networks兲.

Using partial densities nAk=NAk/Nk, nBk=NBk/Nk, and nABk =NABk /Nk, i.e., the densities on classes of degree k, one derives mean-field type equations in analogy with epidemic models. Let us consider for definiteness the neutral pair se- lection strategy, the equation fornAk is in this case

dnAk dt = −knAk

具k典

k

P共k

兩k兲nB k⬘− knAk

2具k典

k

P共k

兩k兲nAB k

+3␤knAB k

2具k典

k

Pk

knAk+␤knAB k

具k典

k

Pk

knABk,

共2兲 and similar equations hold for nBk and nABk . The first term corresponds to the situation in which an agent of degreek

and opinionBchooses as second actor an agent of degreek with opinionA. The second term corresponds to the case in which an agent of degreek

with opinionsA andB chooses the opinion B, interacting with an agent of degree k and opinion A. The third term is the sum of two contributions coming from the complementary interaction; while the last term accounts for the increase of agents of degree k and opinionA due to the interaction of pairs of agents withAB opinion in which the first agent chooses the opinionA.

Let us define ⌰i=兺kP共k

k兲ni

k⬘, for i=A,B,AB. Under the uncorrelation hypothesis for the degrees of neighboring nodes, i.e. Pk

k兲=k

Pk

兲/具k典, we get the following rela- tion for the total densitiesni=兺kPknik,

d共nAnB

dt =3␤− 1

2 ⌰AB共⌰A−⌰B兲. 共3兲 If we consider a small perturbation around the consensus state nA= 1, with nAknBk for all k, we can argue that

A−⌰B=兺kkP共k兲共nA

knBk兲/具k典 is still positive, i.e., the con- sensus state is stable only for ␤⬎1 / 3. In other words, the transition point does not change in heterogeneous topologies when the neutral strategy is assumed. This is in agreement with our numerical simulations, and in contrast with the other selection strategies. Figure4displays indeed the values of the critical parameter␤c共␥兲as a function of the exponent

␥as computed from the evolution equations of the densities nik关that can be derived similarly to Eqs.共2兲兴, and as obtained from numerical simulations. In such topologies, the phase transition is shifted towards lower values of␤, both for direct and reverse strategies, revealing that a preferential bias in the choice of the role played by hubs has a strong effect on the negotiation process. Reducing the skewness ofP共k兲 共increas- ing␥兲, the critical value of ␤converges to 1 / 3.

In conclusion, we have proposed a new model of opinion dynamics based on agents negotiation in which instead memory and feedback are the essential ingredients. We have shown that a nontrivial consensus-polarization-fragmentation

10 10 10

10-3-3-3-3 10101010-2-2-2-2 10101010-1-1-1-1 βββ

β----ββββcccc 10

10 10 108888 10 10 10 109999

ttttconvconvconvconv

UCM ( UCM ( UCM ( UCM (γγγγ= 3.0)= 3.0)= 3.0)= 3.0) UCM ( UCM ( UCM ( UCM (γγγγ= 2.5)= 2.5)= 2.5)= 2.5) ER ER ER ER y ~ x y ~ x y ~ x y ~ x-0.34-0.34-0.34-0.34

10 10 10

10-3-3-3-3 10101010-2-2-2-2 10101010-1-1-1-1 βββ

β----ββββcccc 10

10 10 108888 10 10 10 109999

ttttconvconvconvconv

UCM 2w (3.0) UCM 2w (3.0) UCM 2w (3.0) UCM 2w (3.0) UCM 2w (2.5) UCM 2w (2.5) UCM 2w (2.5) UCM 2w (2.5) ER 2w ER 2w ER 2w ER 2w eqs.

eqs.

eqs.

eqs.γγγγ= 2.5= 2.5= 2.5= 2.5 eqs.

eqs.

eqs.

eqs.γγγγ= 3.0= 3.0= 3.0= 3.0

FIG. 3.共Color online兲Convergence timetconvof the model as a function of␤−␤con networks with different topological properties:

the UCM networks with degree distributionsPk兲⬃k,␥= 2.5, and

␥= 3, and the ER homogeneous random graphs. Simulations are shown for networks ofN= 105nodes and average degree 具k典= 10, both form= 2 共“2w,” open symbols兲 and the original model with unlimited memory共filled symbols兲. The numerical integration of Eqs.共2兲is in good agreement with the simulations.

NONEQUILIBRIUM PHASE TRANSITION IN… PHYSICAL REVIEW E76, 051102共2007兲

051102-3

(4)

phase transition is observed in terms of a control parameter representing the efficiency of the negotiation process. We have elucidated the mean-field dynamics, on the fully con- nected graph as well as on homogeneous and heterogeneous complex networks, using a simple continuous approach. We

have shown that the model presents a discontinuous phase transition between consensus and polarized states featuring at least two different universality classes, one for the case withm= 2 opinions and one for the case with an unlimited number of opinions. In both cases we have measured the critical exponent describing the divergence of the conver- gence time and shown that they do not seem to depend on the specific interaction topology. We argue that systems with any finite numbermof opinions should fall in them= 2 class.

Although this point clearly deserves a deeper numerical in- vestigation, we expect that the behavior of the model with initial invention共unlimited memory兲may be due to the dif- ferent spatial and temporal organization of opinions in the inventories. It would also be interesting to study the more realistic scenario in which the “irresolute attitude” of the agents is modeled as a quenched disorder rather than a global external parameter.

The authors wish to thank V.D.P. Servedio for an impor- tant observation concerning Eq. 共1兲. A. Baronchelli and V.

Loreto were partially supported by the EU under Contract No. IST-1940共ECAgents兲and IST-34721共TAGora兲. A. Bar- rat and L. Dall’Asta were partially supported by the EU un- der Contract No. 001907共DELIS兲. A. Baronchelli acknowl- edges support from the DURSI, Generalitat de Catalunya 共Spain兲 and from Spanish MEC 共FEDER兲 through Project No. FIS 2007–66485–CO2–01.

关1兴Modeling Cooperative Behavior in the Social Sciences: Eighth Granada Lectures on Modeling Cooperative Behavior in the Social Sciences, edited by P. L. Garridoet al., AIP Conf. Proc.

No. 779共AIP, Melville, 2005兲; W. Weidlich,Sociodynamics; A Systematic Approach to Mathematical Modelling in Social Sci- ences共Harwood, New York, 2000兲; D. Staufferet al.,Biology, Sociology, Geology by Computational Physicists 共Elsevier, Amsterdam, 2006兲.

关2兴H. Föllmer, J. Math. Econ. 1, 51共1974兲; C. Chamley,Rational Herds: Economic Models of Social Learning共Cambridge Uni- versity Press, Cambridge, 2003兲.

关3兴R. J. Glauber, J. Math. Phys. 4, 294 共1963兲; S. Galam, Y.

Gefen, and Y. Shapir, J. Am. Math. Soc. 9, 1 共1982兲; P. L.

Krapivsky and S. Redner, Phys. Rev. Lett. 90, 238701共2003兲. 关4兴P. L. Krapivsky, Phys. Rev. A 45, 1067 共1992兲; L. Frache- bourg and P. L. Krapivsky, Phys. Rev. E 53, R3009共1996兲; T.

M. Liggett,Interacting Particle Systems共Springer, New York, 1985兲.

关5兴G. Odor, Rev. Mod. Phys. 76, 663共2004兲.

关6兴G. Deffuant, D. Neau, F. Amblard, and G. Weisbuch, Adv.

Complex Syst. 3, 87共2000兲.

关7兴R. Hegselmann and U. Krause, J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 5共3兲, paper 2共2002兲.

关8兴R. Axelrod, J. Conflict Resolut. 41, 203共1997兲.

关9兴E. Ben-Naim, P. L. Krapivsky, and S. Redner, Physica D 183, 190共2003兲.

关10兴C. Castellano, M. Marsili, and A. Vespignani, Phys. Rev. Lett.

85, 3536共2000兲.

关11兴N. E. Friedkin, Soc. Networks 12, 239共1990兲.

关12兴A. Baronchelli, M. Felici, V. Loreto, E. Caglioti, and L. Stells, J. Stat. Mech.: Theory Exp. 2006, P06014.

关13兴C. Castellano, in Ref.关1兴, p. 114.

关14兴A. Crisanti and P. Grassberger, J. Phys. A 27, 6955共1994兲. 关15兴P. Erdös and A. Rényi, Publ. Math.共Debrecen兲 6, 290共1959兲. 关16兴M. Catanzaro, M. Boguñá, and R. Pastor-Satorras, Phys. Rev.

E 71, 027103共2005兲.

关17兴K. Klemm, V. M. Eguiluz, R. Toral, and M. San Miguel, Phys.

Rev. E 67, 026120共2003兲.

关18兴The low value ofa, which moreover slightly decreases as the system size increases, does not allow us to exclude a logarith- mic divergence. This issue deserves more investigations that we leave for future work.

0.15 0.15 0.15 0.15 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.25 0.25 0.25 0.25 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3

ββββ cccc((((γγγγ))))

2 4

2 4

2 4

2 4 γγγγ 6666 8888

direct strat.

direct strat.

direct strat.

direct strat.

reverse strat.

reverse strat.

reverse strat.

reverse strat.

βββ βcccc= 1/3= 1/3= 1/3= 1/3

0.28 0.28 0.28 0.28 0.29 0.29 0.29 0.29 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.3 0.31 0.31 0.31 0.31 0.32 0.32 0.32 0.32

ββββ cccc((((γγγγ))))

2.0 2.2 2.4 2.6 2.8 3.0

2.0 2.2 2.4 2.6 2.8 3.0

2.0 2.2 2.4 2.6 2.8 3.0

2.0 2.2 2.4 γγγγ 2.6 2.8 3.0

direct - simul.

direct - simul.

direct - simul.

direct - simul.

direct - theory direct - theory direct - theory direct - theory reverse - simul.

reverse - simul.

reverse - simul.

reverse - simul.

reverse - theory reverse - theory reverse - theory reverse - theory

FIG. 4. 共Color online兲 Behavior of the critical value ␤c as a function of the exponent␥of the degree distributionPk兲⬃k, as obtained from the numerical solution of the evolution equations for nik, for both direct共black circles兲 and reverse共red squares兲strate- gies. Bottom: comparison between the values of ␤c共␥兲 obtained from the equations and from numerical simulations on UCM net- works ofN= 103agents, for direct共open symbols兲and reverse共full symbols兲strategies.

BARONCHELLIet al. PHYSICAL REVIEW E76, 051102共2007兲

051102-4

Références

Documents relatifs

We show first that the second sound overdamping leads to much longer relaxation times, as observed by ultrasonic measurements.. We show then that the technique used

- Final configurations of binary alloy at low-temperature 0.08To with (a) Lennard-Jones potential, (b) Lennard-Jones potential supplemented by orientational three body

The estimated Tc of the Penrose (dual Penrose) lattice is higher (lower) than that of the square lattice, although the average coordination numbers of these three

Extensive computer simulation studies in 2D Showed that the Steady states in this model present a nonequilibrium phase transition, which is characterized by a highly anisotropic

these localised states and in general the electronic structure near the interface have some influence on. the electrical properties of the

2014 A model based on second rank tensor orientational properties of smectic phases is developed.. The model predicts a second order smectic A-smectic C phase transition

on elastic interaction, recalling that its average energy is proportional to 1 /r per unit length of straight and parallel edge dislocations. Simple considerations

Nous analysons ensuite comment la nature des transitions (continues ou discontinues) et la nature des phases obtenues (états de valence pure ou mixte) sont affectées par