• Aucun résultat trouvé

P. Burnod, S. Mercandalli, A. Reys, W. Anseeuw, M. Giger, B. Kiteme and T. Ralandison (see affiliation infra)

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "P. Burnod, S. Mercandalli, A. Reys, W. Anseeuw, M. Giger, B. Kiteme and T. Ralandison (see affiliation infra)"

Copied!
4
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

Conference : Conference on Land policy in Africa, Abidjan, 2019

Title: Nuancing Narratives On Labor Market Effects of Large Agriculture Investments in Sub Saharan Africa

Event Category: Conference paper

Sub themes: 5. Land Based investments, inclusive economic growth and environmental sustainability;

Key words : land based investment, labor, impact, Kenya, Madagascar, Mozambique

Authors : P. Burnod, S. Mercandalli, A. Reys, W. Anseeuw, M. Giger, B. Kiteme and T. Ralandison (see affiliation infra)

Extended Abstract

Context and literature review

Employment creation is key to Sub Saharan Africa. Currently, the region labor markets are not sizing the increasing needs for new jobs as economic transition and industrialisation are lagging. As a result of these low diversified economies, in 2015, the rural and agricultural sectors still employ the most of the active population and more than half of the active youth (Losch et al., 2016).

In view of these challenges, the pro-investment discourse emphasizes the employment opportunities associated with the development of large-scale agricultural enterprises (eg Collier and Dercon, 2014). Since the beginning of the 2000 ‘s, there has been a resurgence of plantations and large-scale estates that mimic (or in some cases revive) large colonial estates and state farms (Hall et al. 2015; Anseeuw et al.2012; White et al. 2012). The difference is that the large-scale estates intervene in a context radically different (no more subventions from the State except from low cost access to land) and companies no longer jointly seek access to land and labor (Baglioni and Gibbon, 2013). They rather access to the former in order to deploy large capital intensive agricultural activities and trigger lots of questions and debates about effective employment impacts (Deininger et al., 2011; Li, 2011, Anseeuw et al., 2012)

Research question

Feeding this ongoing debates, Hall and Scoones (2017) and Smalley (2013) points the need to look at LAIs labor impacts. Few research focus on the LAI job creation (Nolte Ostermeier 2017, Deininger et Xia, 2016 ; Deininger et al., 2011), that is companies labour supply side when more analyze the workers profiles that is the demand side (McCulloh and Ota, 2002, Maertens et Swinnen, 2009, Burnod et Medernach, 2014 ; Ahlerup & Tengstam, 2015).

To contribute to limited literature that overcomes simplistic narratives on LSAI socio economic impacts, while complementing supply or demand centered analyses, the general research questions are: What jobs are created (number and quality)? Who get the jobs and why? How these outcomes differ according to companies and more specifically according to technical models? And what lessons can be learned in terms of public policies in the context of Sub-Saharan Africa contemporary labor markets?

(2)

The paper focuses on plantations and compare different companies according to their production models. In addition, it presents some small-scale farming results to put large-scale farming performances into perspective. Finally, this paper offer original contribution as it analyses both supply and demand sides on the labor market.

The research is anchored in and fueled by a variety of cases studies relative to large-scale farming enterprises in Kenya, Mozambique and Madagascar. The countries and study areas have been selected to reflect the contrasting socio-economic and agrarian contexts, trajectories and levels and maturity/age of large scale agricultural investment.

This paper uses a common methodology for the three countries deployed around three sources of data: (i) qualitative and in-depth interviews at local and company level, (ii) the production of detailed lists of all investments, successful or not, in the studied zones and their related companies' juridical, economic and production characteristics, and (iii) primary data that were collected through an ad hoc households livelihoods survey that has been conducted in 2017 among 1,650 households – from 500 to 600 per country. In each country and studied zones, households were randomly selected in impacted areas (buffer zones around farming enterprises) and in counterfactual zones.

Main results On the supply side:

• number of jobs created on average per company are important (from 95 to 150 permanent jobs and 50 to 300 temporary jobs), notably in rural areas where formal job opportunities are rare. Similar to work carried out in Africa (Ali et al., 2017; Deininger and Xia, 2016; Nolte and Ostermeir, 2017), results show that the direct gross employment creation of the enterprises are heterogeneous: vegetables farms create in average 2 full time jobs per hectare whereas cereal and soja farms create in average 1 full time job for 15 to 33 cultivated hectares. This contrasted results depend, beyond the institutional national and local settings: on the technical models of the enterprises, meaning the crops produced and, in particular, the intensity of labor requirements;

• comparing small and large-scale farming, when production and processing are difficult to mechanize (horticulture), the jobs created per hectare are higher or similar than those generated by family farming. Job creation performance is much reduced when crops are mechanized or little labor intensive (cereals and perennial crops) and lower than family farming;

• results on quality of job created show important national and regional disparities (permanent / short-term job, level of remuneration). The permanent jobs created represent most of the created jobs in Kenya, half of them in Mozambique and one third in Madagascar reflecting the logics of specific technical model.

On the demand side of labor market :

• literature stresses that part time jobs of day laborers or seasonal workers offered by large scale agricultural enterprises often benefit the most vulnerable segments of the population: poor households, migrants, youth and / or women (Mc Culloch and Ota, 2002, Maertens and Swinnen, 2009, Ahlerup & Tengstam, 2015, Li 2011). This trend is partly confirmed in the three countries studied where young people and migrants are the most frequently recruited for temporary and casual labor. These jobs remain largely open to women who, unlike men, find it difficult to find employment in other sectors of the rural economy (masonry, transport, etc.). This can be seen as an advantage in terms of poverty reduction (Maertens and Swinnen, 2009)

(3)

or critically considered as the direct result of the absence of alternatives for the most vulnerable and their inability to deny low wages, difficult schedules or repetitive work (Li, 2011). However, when looking at permanent jobs, this age and gender dynamic of LAI labor effects do not prevail everywhere and LSAI jobs also benefit other segments of the population as elder workers accessing stable and decent opportunities.

Implications in terms of public choices and broad base development strategies

The quantification and qualification of the jobs created by large-scale agricultural enterprises and their comparison according to the business models makes it possible to better illuminate the choices in terms of promotion of inclusive investments for different segments of the population of small holders and anticipated spillover effects on the local economy.

Subsidizing large-scale agricultural investments (notably by making available cheap land) does not automatically yield higher value benefits because spillover effects (labor creation, yield productivity, technology transfers) do not materialize (Ali et al., 2017). In particular comparing the performances of large-scale farming with that of family farming underlines that the large-cale plantation model performances in terms of net job creation are not that high, especially when the soil and rain fall conditions are good. This information, depending on land contexts and land density levels, can reinforce the argument of the lack of economic relevance of expelling farmers, even if they are squatters (Nolte and Ostermeier 2017). Finally, the analysis of employee household socio economic profiles and the effects of LAIs off farm incomes on poverty reduction offers the opportunity to discuss the quality of the jobs created and their effect on a possible exit from poverty.

Institutional affiliation

Name: Perrine BURNOD

Institutional affiliation: Malgasy Land Observatory & CIRAD Email Address: perrine.burnod@cirad.fr

Name : Sara MERCANDALLI

Institutional affiliation: University of Pretoria / Cirad Email Address: sara.mercandalli@cirad.fr

Name: Aurélien REYS

Institutionnal affiliation : Independent / ex Cirad Email Address: aurelienreys@gmail.com

Name: Ward ANSEEUW

Institutional affiliation: International Land Coalition Email Address: w.anseeuw@landcoalition.org

(4)

Name: Markus GIGER

Institutional affiliation: CDE – University of Bern Email Address: Markus.Giger@cde.unibe.ch

Name: Tsilavo Ralandison

Institutional affiliation : University of Kyoto Email Address: <tsilavo@econ.kyoto-u.ac.jp>

Name: Kiteme Boniface

Institutional affiliation : CETRAD

Références

Documents relatifs

In Handbook of Regional and Urban Economics (Vol. On the origins of land use regulations: theory and evidence from US metro areas. The impact of supply constraints on house prices in

However, by my lights, Sankey is mistaken that his most recently proposed view avoids Grzankowski’s second objection, since believing that p is true isn’t logically distinct

The centre will carry out research into problems and policies of health development and relationships between and among various social, economic, environmental and demographic

In EcoLexicon, every terminological entry contains meaningful data categories (ISO 12620:1999) providing (a) linguistic information (definitions, synonyms, equivalents in

Besides the unavoidable uncertainty for the firm to estimate the real de- mand curve, thus necessitating a suite of contingencies that we can call the supply curve. We note

VOL 46: OCTOBER • OCTOBRE 2000 ❖ Canadian Family Physician • Le Médecin de famille canadien 1969.. Letters

Future collaborations between the different stakeholders involved in agricultural policy and researchers will be vital to ensure that economic experiments can find their place in

A single Transmit command contains, as part of the command-specific parame- ters, the destination address and length field for the transmitted frame along with a