• Aucun résultat trouvé

Paths and Limits of Agricultural Growth

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "Paths and Limits of Agricultural Growth"

Copied!
5
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

12th Congress of the European Association of Agricultural Economists – EAAE 2008

12

th

Congress of the European Association of Agricultural Economists – EAAE 2008. Ghent Belgium

Paths and Limits of Agricultural Growth

Dorin B.

1

, Benoit-Cattin M.

2

1

CIRAD, UMR CIRED, Montpellier, F-34398, France 2

CIRAD, UMR MOISA, Montpellier, F-34398, France

Abstract — The growth of agriculture and its ability

to feed growing populations rests on land and labour productivities. We estimated these partial productivities in food kilocalories for most countries of the world, and discussed their evolution over the past 40 years. Very contrasted productivity paths are shown between the 6 macro-regions of the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment.

Keywords — Agricultural productivity, Food policy,

International development

I. INTRODUCTION

How a decreasing share of the active population will continue to provide food for a growing number of people? with limited terrestrial endowment in mineral reserves and natural resources (land, water, petroleum, phosphates…)? without degrading further ecosystems and jeopardizing the services they can provide for future generations [1]?

Faced with this complex issue, we highlight here that past decades of world agricultural growth rested on very contrasted regional evolutions of land and labour productivities, and that these past regional productivity routes help to better identify questions, deadlocks and opportunities for the future.

To characterize and analyze these different productivity routes, we combined national annual statistics on land-use, on populations and on all vegetal food productions whose annual volumes in tonnes [2] have been converted into calories and aggregated, as explained in part II (Data and Methodology). Part III presents the results in a synthetic graphical way, on a 43-year period

(1961-2003), at the geographical scale of the six regions of the Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (MEA), and according to a simple tautological relationship between land and labour partial productivities: Production/Ha * Ha/Worker = Production/Worker.

This analysis confirms, updates or extends some works carried out by P. Bairoch [3], Y. Hayami and V.W. Ruttan [4], L. Malassis [5]. It differs from usual literature on agricultural development where productivity challenges are rarely quantified, or for few countries only, or where land productivity is measured through yield changes of some selected commodities (mainly wheat), and labour productivity through added value per worker.

II. DATA AND METHODOLOGY

Our historical analysis of world agricultural productivity is based on a 3-step work.

Firstly, FAO annual country-level statistical series [2] on land-use, populations and agricultural productions were bulk-downloaded, merged and checked on a 43-year period, i.e. from 1961 to 2003. During the process, many islands or micro-States had to be removed for missing or erratic statistical information, along with few bigger States such as Afghanistan, Iraq and Somalia. The output database kept ~150 geographical entities out of the ~250 appearing in the FAO databases all along the period, which account for more than 98% of the 2000 world population and of the world land area without Antarctica.

Secondly, an aggregated vegetal food production (AP) were estimated as follow: APr = ∑i (Pir * Ci),

(2)

biomass listed in the statistical series "Commodity Balances" and edible in its primary form (cereal grains, oilseeds, pulses, fruit, vegetables, etc., regardless the final use as food, feed or something else), P the volume of production in metric tonnes of product line i, and C its food calorie content per tonne according to the FAO [6]. The regions r considered hereafter are those of the Millennium Ecosystems Assessment [1], i.e. Asia (ASIA), Former Soviet Union (FSU), Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), Middle East and North Africa (MENA), Latin America (LAM) and most OECD country-members in 1990 (OECD) (Fig. 1).

Thirdly, we estimated regional partial land productivities (production per hectare) and work productivities (production per worker) by dividing respectively our APr in kilocalories (kcal) with the

regional net area under temporary or permanent crops (hectares), and with the regional total economically active population in agriculture (workers) as estimated by the FAO. Land and labour partial productivities can be interestingly linked and analyzed through a tautological relationships using the “land availability” (ha/worker): Kcal/Ha * Ha/Worker = Kcal/Worker

Fig. 1 The six MEA regions

III. RESULTS

A. Global trends

Between 1961 and 2003, the world population has been multiplied by 2 and the urban one by 3; whereas active people involved in agriculture have increased by only 60%. Consequently, the number of persons nourished by an agricultural worker has increased from 3.6 to 4.7 on global average (+ 31%). This was

made possible by an increase of production per worker (+53%) as well as per cultivated hectare (+123%). But because of land constraints, the cultivated area per worker has fallen from 1.45 to around 1 ha.

B. Highest land productivity in Asia

In the early 1960’s, land productivities ranged between 5,000 to 11,000 kcal/ha/day (Fig. 2). The dispersion was wider in the early 2000’s as yields have meanwhile been multiplied by 2 or more, except in FSU. From 1985 onwards, land productivity is the highest in ASIA where credit, irrigation, fertilizers and high-yielding varieties boosted wheat and rice yield as well as the number of crops per year. But there is an apparent levelling off since 1995, as in OECD. On the contrary, land productivity is accelerating in LAM, closing the gap with OECD just at the end of the period. In MENA, land productivity has been multiplied by 3 which is the highest growth rate, whereas it was only by 2 in SSA where no Green Revolution took place as in ASIA.

Fig. 2 Food Veg. Production per Cultivated Hectare

0 5 000 10 000 15 000 20 000 25 000 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 d a ily k c a l / h a

OECD SSA FSU ASIA LAM MENA

C. A labour productivity boom in OECD

The contrast between OECD and non-OECD countries is very impressive as far as the per-worker productivity is concerned (Fig. 3).

This “North/South agricultural divide” is due to motorization (and related fossil fuel use for traction, water pumping, harvest and post-harvest work…), as our proxy “number of tractors” per hectare or per agricultural worker suggests it (Table 1 and Fig. 4

,

.

t

(3)

12th Congress of the European Association of Agricultural Economists – EAAE 2008

using à log scale and showing everywhere a declining growth).

Fig. 3 Food Veg. Production per Active Agri. Worker

0 50 000 100 000 150 000 200 000 250 000 300 000 350 000 400 000 450 000 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 d a ily k c a l / w o rk e r

OECD SSA FSU ASIA LAM MENA

Table 1 Motorization (year 2000)

OECD FSU LAM MENA ASIA SSA

Tract / 100 Wkrs 72.0 7.5 4.0 3.8 0.4 0.1 Tract / 100 Ha 4.1 0.77 1.1 2.0 0.9 0.1

Fig. 4 Tractors per Active Agricultural Worker

0% 0% 1% 10% 100% 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 tr a c to r( s ) / w o rk e r

OECD SSA FSU ASIA LAM MENA

The labour productivity of motorized FSU agriculture is quite unstable, and a zoom on less labour-productive zones (Fig. 5) shows an exponential growth in LAM, resulting mainly from a land productivity growth. Finally and surprisingly, ASIA and SSA show similar low performances in term of labour productivity despite large differences in land productivities: land availability has also to be taken into consideration.

Fig. 5 Food Veg. Production per Active Agri. Worker

0 10 000 20 000 30 000 40 000 50 000 60 000 70 000 80 000 90 000 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 d a ily k c a l / w o rk e r

SSA ASIA LAM MENA

D. Large disparities in land availability

The average (net) cultivated area per agricultural worker is another illustration of the agricultural divide (Fig. 6). It is the result of non related evolutions of active population (Fig. 7) and cultivated land (Fig. 8). In ASIA, active population in agriculture seems to stabilize around 1 billion people, whereas it is still increasing in SSA. Elsewhere, this population is either stable or declining. As far as area under cultivation is concerned, it has increased only in ASIA, LAM and SSA, but at the expense of two carbon and biodiversity pools, forests or permanent pastures.

Fig. 6 Cultivated Hectare per Active Agri. Worker

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 h a / w o rk e r

(4)

Fig. 7 Active Agricultural Workers 0 200 400 600 800 1 000 1 200 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 W o rk e rs ( m ill io n h e a d s )

OECD SSA FSU Asia LAM MENA

Fig. 8 Cultivated areas

0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350 400 450 500 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 h e c ta re s ( m ill io n )

OECD SSA FSU Asia LAM MENA

IV. IS THERE A SUSTAINABLE AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTIVITY PATH? Thanks to a million data from FAO, we can provide a very synthetic view of the past 40-year agricultural productivity routes of 6 world macro-regions. As shown in Fig. 9, each of these regions followed a specific path, resulting from limitations in land availability (X axis) and ability to increase land yields (Y axis). Despite a fantastic OECD’s growth in terms of labour productivity due to motorization and quite

easy rural-urban migrations, the world average agricultural productivity path remain rather close to the ASIA one based, above all, on a yield boost. This land productivity is high in ASIA as well as in OECD, but in both cases, seems now to level off for various reasons (low market or political incentives, increasing prices of fossil energies and of other agricultural inputs, water stress, soil or biodiversity erosion…). Future important yield growth may take place in FSU where both land and labour productivities seem still rather easy to improve. In LAM where the last two productivities are already significantly high, the extension of the cultivated area may be the first challenge and problem (erosion of global carbon and biodiversity pools…), while in SSA, peaceful land access remains a key question, along with mechanisation and yields improvement.

REFERENCES

[1] MEA, 2005. Ecosystems and Human Well-being: Synthesis, Millennium Ecosystem Assessment, World Resources Institute, Whashington D.C., 155 p. and www.millenniumassessment.org/documents/document.774. aspx.pdf

[2] FAO, 2006. Faostat, Web portal and database as on 30/06/2006, http://faostat.fao.org/site/395/default.aspx [3] Bairoch, P., 1999. L'agriculture des pays développés - 1800 à nos jours - Production, Productivité, Rendements, Paris, Economica, 191 p.

[4] Ruttan, V.W., 2002. "Productivity Growth in World Agriculture: Sources and Constraints", Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(4), pp. 161–184.

[5] Malassis, L., 1998. “Préface à l’édition française”, in Hayami Y. and Ruttan V.W., Agriculture et développement : une approche internationale, INRA, Paris, 1998, 600 p.

[6] FAO, 2001. Food Balance Sheets - A handbook, FAO, Rome,www.fao.org/documents

(5)

12th Congress of the European Association of Agricultural Economists – EAAE 2008 Fig. 9. Regional Agricultural Productivity Paths (1961-2003)

0 5 000 10 000 15 000 20 000 25 000 30 000 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Cultivated area (ha) per Active agricultural worker

D ai ly veg etal f oo d pr od uctio n ( kcal ) pe r C ul ti vated area (ha ) 12 500 50 000 kcal / worker 25 000 100 000 kcal / worker 400 000 kcal / worker 200 000 kcal / worker 6 250 LAM OECD MENA SSA ASIA FSU World

Références

Documents relatifs

Despite a fantastic OECD's growth in terms of labour productivity due to motorization and quite easy rural-urban migrations, the world average agricultural productivity path

As for the improper water and land use structure and difficulty in bringing the system into maximum performance, this research takes the Sanjiang Branch

TALeUR, M., On the growth of subharmonic functions on asymptotic paths, Proc.. TALPUR, M., A subharmonic analogue of Iverson's theorem,

To achieve its goal, I-Spinlock introduces a new metric (associated with each vCPU) called lock completion capa- bility (lock cap for short) which indicates the capability of its

Après cela, nous avons comparé les competence structure générées par les deux approches : celle en partant du modèle de domaine (figure 4) générée comme expliqué dans

In response to international agreements and the influence of environ- mental movements, Brazil has implemented measures to protect the Amazon rainforest including the regulation

As an introductio n , Pr ob lems of Agricultural Development will be di scussed with a vi ew t o ascertaining the main lim~ting fact ors t o ag ri cul tural

At the beginning of the growth process, the level of capital is low, and technological progress increases with the size of the population.. Then, as the technological