• Aucun résultat trouvé

A comparison of structural and non-structural econometric models in the Toronto office market

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "A comparison of structural and non-structural econometric models in the Toronto office market"

Copied!
70
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

A Comparison of Structural and Non-Structural Econometric Models in the Toronto Office Market by

Kimberly Gole

B.S., Mathematics and Statistics and Applied Probability, 2007 University of Alberta

Submitted to the Program in Real Estate Development in Conjunction with the Center for Real Estate in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Science in Real Estate Development

at the

Massachusetts Institute of Technology September, 2014

©2014 Kimberly Gole All rights reserved

The author hereby grants to MIT permission to reproduce and to distribute publicly paper and electronic copies of this thesis document in whole or in part in any medium now known or hereafter created.

Signature of Author_________________________________________________________ Center for Real Estate

July 30, 2014

Certified by_______________________________________________________________ William C. Wheaton

Professor, Department of Economics Thesis Supervisor

Accepted by______________________________________________________________ Albert Saiz

Chair, MSRED Committee, Interdepartmental Degree Program in Real Estate Development

(2)

A Comparison of Structural and Non-Structural Econometric Models in the Toronto Office Market

by Kimberly Gole

Submitted to the Program in Real Estate Development in Conjunction with the Center for Real Estate on July 30, 2014 in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of Master of Science in Real Estate Development

ABSTRACT

This thesis aims to compare five systems of econometric equations to describe the Toronto office market. It compares four structural systems differing in their demand equations and a non-structural system that does not require predefined relationships to exist between variables. Within the structural system of equations the predefined equations require that real rent is estimated solely from vacancy, long-run supply is dependent upon real rent and changes in employment only affect demand. Demand can be estimated either directly by estimating occupied stock and obtaining vacancy through an identity or by estimating vacancy; both occupied stock and vacancy can either be estimated in levels or estimated by an error correction model. Through the analysis of the structural models it is found that real rent shows significant momentum of real rent one year previous. As well the long-run supply curve is rising, while the real rent curve is not rising through the analysis period, as such the long-run supply is estimated in differences as the theoretical relationship between real rent and long run supply in levels cannot be estimated with the correct sign for the Toronto market. The structural demand equations show that error correction terms add value to predictions of demand. The non-structural model is defined as a vector autoregressive model and allows the variables to freely interact between themselves without the restrictions placed in the structural model. When comparing the structural systems to the non-structural system in the back test, the non-structural system produces superior estimates in the system as a whole. The superior results of the VAR agree with the notion that in complicated dynamic systems by placing restrictions on the interactions of the variables poorer forecasts may result.

Thesis Supervisor: William Wheaton Title: Professor of Economics

(3)

Table of Contents

1.  Introduction  ...  5  

2.  Previous  Literature  ...  8  

Research  on  Structural  Econometric  Models  in  Commercial  Rent  Analysis  ...  8  

Research  on  Non-­‐Structural  Econometric  Models  in  Commercial  Rent  Analysis  ...  10  

Research  on  Error  Correction  Models  in  Commercial  Rental  Analysis  ...  10  

Research  on  the  Comparison  of  Structural  versus  Non-­‐Structural  Models  in   Macroeconomics  ...  12  

3.  Exploratory  Data  Analysis  ...  12  

Toronto  Office  Market  Overview  ...  12  

Variable  Descriptions  ...  13  

Economic  Variables  ...  14  

Office  Stock  ...  16  

Rent  and  Vacancy  ...  17  

4.  Structural  Econometric  Model  ...  18  

Structural  Model  Framework  ...  18  

Stationarity  Tests  of  Variables  ...  19  

Cointegration  Tests  ...  20  

Real  Rental  Rate  Equation  ...  21  

Long-­‐Run  Supply  Equation  ...  21  

Demand  Equations  ...  22  

Summary  of  Cointegration  Test  Results  ...  24  

Real  Rental  Rate  Equation  ...  24  

Econometric  Model  ...  25  

Long-­‐Run  Supply  Equation  ...  26  

Econometric  Model  ...  27  

Demand  Equations  ...  29  

Econometric  Model  –  Direct  Demand  in  Levels  ...  31  

Econometric  Model  –  Direct  Demand  as  an  Error  Correction  Model  ...  33  

Econometric  Model  –  Indirect  Demand  in  Levels  ...  34  

Econometric  Model  –  Indirect  Demand  as  an  Error  Correction  Model  ...  36  

5.  Non-­‐Structural  Econometric  Model  ...  37  

Econometric  Model  ...  38  

6.  Comparison  of  the  Structural  and  Non-­‐Structural  Framework  ...  41  

Back-­‐Testing  of  Models  ...  41  

7.  Conclusion  ...  46  

8.  Bibliography  ...  48  

9.  Appendices  ...  50  

Data  as  Provided  by  CBRE  Econometric  Advisors  ...  50  

Stationarity  Tests  Statistical  Output  ...  53  

Business  Services  Employment  ...  53  

Business  Services  Employment  First  Difference  ...  53  

Real  Net  Effective  Rent  ...  54  

Real  Net  Effective  Rent  First  Difference  ...  54  

(4)

Vacancy  Rate  First  Difference  ...  55  

Occupied  Stock  ...  55  

Occupied  Stock  First  Difference  (Net  Absorption)  ...  56  

Office  Stock  ...  56  

Office  Stock  First  Difference  (Net  Completions)  ...  57  

Summary  of  Additional  Stationarity  Tests  ...  57  

Cointegration  Tests  Statistical  Results  ...  58  

Rental  Rate  Equation  Cointegration  Test  Results  ...  58  

Additional  Cointegration  Tests  Explored  for  Rental  Rate  Equation  ...  58  

Supply  Equation  Cointegration  Test  Results  ...  59  

Additional  Cointegration  Tests  Explored  for  Supply  Equation  ...  59  

Direct  Demand  in  Levels  Cointegration  Test  Results  ...  60  

Additional  Cointegration  Tests  Explored  for  Direct  Demand  in  Levels  Equation  ...  61  

Indirect  Demand  in  Levels  Cointegration  Test  Results  ...  61  

Additional  Cointegration  Tests  Explored  for  Indirect  Demand  in  Levels  Equation  ...  62  

Direct  Demand  in  Differences  (ECM)  Cointegration  Test  Results  ...  62  

Additional  Cointegration  Tests  Explored  for  Direct  Demand  in  Differences  (ECM)  Equation  ...  63  

Indirect  Demand  in  Differences  (ECM)  Cointegration  Test  Results  ...  63  

Additional  Cointegration  Tests  Explored  for  Indirect  Demand  in  Differences  (ECM)  Equation  .  64   Structural  System  Econometric  Models  ...  64  

Real  Rental  Rate  Equation  ...  64  

Additional  Models  for  Real  Rental  Rate  Equation  ...  64  

Long-­‐Run  Supply  Equation  ...  65  

Additional  Models  for  Supply  Equation  ...  65  

Direct  Demand  in  Levels  Equation  ...  65  

Additional  Models  for  Direct  Demand  in  Levels  Equation  ...  66  

Direct  Demand  as  an  Error  Correction  Model  Equation  ...  66  

Additional  Models  for  Direct  Demand  as  an  Error  Correction  Model  Equation  ...  66  

Indirect  Demand  in  Levels  Equation  ...  67  

Additional  Models  for  Indirect  Demand  in  Levels  Equation  ...  67  

Indirect  Demand  as  an  Error  Correction  Model  Equation  ...  68  

Additional  Models  for  Indirect  Demand  as  an  Error  Correction  Model  Equation  ...  68  

Non-­‐structural  Econometric  Models  ...  69  

Rental  Rate  Equation  ...  69  

Long-­‐Run  Supply  Equation  ...  69  

(5)

1.  Introduction  

The ability to predict rental rates of a market into the near future is of crucial importance in commercial real estate. The typical proforma analysis of an investment or development relies fundamentally on the future rental forecast to determine if the investment is one that will be financially feasible.

This thesis endeavors to determine which econometric model is a more suitable fit, a structural or a non-structural model. It investigates whether rent is impacted by only vacancy, whether only demand depends upon job growth and whether rent is solely sufficient to generate new supply as required in the structural framework or if the variables exist together with less stringent

requirements on their relationships.

Within the structural framework this thesis endeavors to determine which econometric model of modeling demand is a more suitable fit in the Toronto office market. It investigates whether demand for the amount of space occupied is better estimated by using variables in levels or by using the changes in variables (differences). It also investigates which methodology of

structuring the system of equations to estimate demand produces better results, either by directly estimating demand or indirectly estimating demand.

The structure of the econometric models used to forecast the commercial property market has been dependent upon where the subject city is located. In the United States the research has revolved around the economic theory that the change in real rents is linked exclusively to changes of the vacancy rate from the natural vacancy rate. This change in the vacancy rate from the natural vacancy rate is characterized as a move away from the market equilibrium. The divergence of vacancy from its natural level causes rents to also move away from their equilibrium level, which provides a signal to developer. Development then either increases or decreases in response to the vacancy movement and acts to return the market to equilibrium. This additional development potentially changes the amount of occupied stock, which by definition changes the vacancy observed in the market. The structural model requires that the relationships described above are valid and there hasn’t been faulty inferences made between the variables. The main theory behind the structural model is that rent is determined through vacancy, and changes in the vacancy rate drives changes in the whole system.

In Europe structural models have evolved differently, as these markets have limited vacancy rate data available for analysis. Due to the limited availability of vacancy information reduced form demand-supply equations have been developed. Instead of estimating occupied stock to

determine the market vacancy as their American counterparts, European models tend to estimate vacancy. By estimating vacancy the model does not require the stock information that an

estimate of occupied stock would require. A possible limitation of this framework is that there is no ability to control the vacancy rate within the range of zero to one.

In order to test whether the required variable relationships in the structural system of equations are necessary or if the variables can interact more than allowed in the economic theory, a non-structural model will be analyzed. The non-non-structural model will be predicted using a vector autoregressive model. In this model the three variables are specified as linear functions of a set number of their own lags, and the same number of lags of the other two variables. The

(6)

exogenous variable will be business services employment. The strength of this framework is that it does not assume any of the variables require relationships but is able to look at each one as a function of a lagged value of itself and the other variables.

The following charts summarize the relationships between the variables for the direct demand model, indirect demand model and the non-structural model. In the charts the E represents that the variable is used in the estimation, the I represents that the variable is part of an identity.

Direct Demand Is a Function of:

Variable Completions Real Rent Vacancy Occupied

Stock Stock Employment

Completions E Real Rent E Vacancy I I Occupied Stock E E Stock I I Indirect Demand Is a Function of:

Variable Completions Real Rent Vacancy Occupied

Stock Stock Employment

Completions E Real Rent E Vacancy E E E Occupied Stock I I Stock I I

Vector Autoregressive Model (VAR) Is a Function of: Variable Completions (lagged) Real Rent (lagged) Vacancy (lagged) Occupied Stock Stock Employment Completions E E E E Real Rent E E E Vacancy E E E E Occupied Stock E E Stock I I

A relatively new development in commercial forecasting is the use of error correction models (ECM). These models are dynamic models that allow long-term effects to be separated from short-term effects, and are especially useful in determining whether commercial real estate

(7)

demand is a product of short-term effects or long-run deviations from equilibrium. This type of model requires that the equation it is applied to show cointegration. The error correction

framework will be applied to the direct and indirect demand equations in differences. This will allow investigation into whether short-term effects add significant value in predicting demand. By comparing four systems of structural econometric models and the non-structural econometric for the Toronto office market this thesis aims to determine which method of forecasting provides more accurate results. It aims to determine if the error correction model in differences adds any value to the prediction above that which the typical long-run model in levels does. It also aims to determine if better results are achieved by estimating the demand directly by estimating occupied stock or indirectly by estimating vacancy. Along with variable identities, three equations will be specified to describe the relationships within the structural framework of the variables in the Toronto market. One model with all of the independent variables will be specified as a vector autoregressive model for the non-structural system. Once both model forms are created, the models predictive power will be tested using a portion of the data, from the first quarter of 2008 to the fourth quarter of 2013. As this portion of the data includes both the global recession of 2008-2009 and the recovery it should provide an accurate indication of predictive power. This thesis will be presented in the following format with the chapters outlined below:

• Chapter 1 introduces the topic and provides a description of the econometric models being considered.

• Chapter 2 describes the historical development of commercial forecasting. The previous literature spans several locations and includes research on the development of structural models, reduced form demand-supply models, and error correction models.

• Chapter 3 provides a description on the Toronto office market and includes exploratory analysis of the data used in the thesis.

• Chapter 4 creates the four systems structural econometric equations. It begins by exploring the stationarity of the variables and cointegration between variables. It then explores the real rental rate equation, the long-run supply equation and the four demand equations: direct demand in levels, direct demand as an error correction model, indirect demand in levels, and indirect demand as an error correction model.

• Chapter 5 focuses on the non-structural econometric system. It creates the real rental rate equation, the long-run supply equation and the demand equation without the necessity of theoretical relationships between the variables.

• Chapter 6 compares the systems of equations to one another and the actual observed values through back testing between the first quarter of 2008 to the fourth quarter of 2013.

(8)

2.  Previous  Literature  

Research  on  Structural  Econometric  Models  in  Commercial  Rent  Analysis  

The model of rental adjustment has its origins in labor economics. This model was first applied to rents and vacancy rates in the rental housing market by Blank and Winnick (1953). This research was the first to determine that there is an inverse relationship between rents and vacancy. Following this study several iterations of this idea have been researched.

Early support of the model structure of relating rents to vacancy rates was provided by Smith (1969) who researched a model of housing starts as a function of the price of houses, the vacancy rate, the construction and land costs and the cost and availability of mortgage credit. The

research was conducted on quarterly data from 1954-1965 of Canadian housing markets. Smith (1974) presented support for the traditional view that vacancy rates are very important in describing housing rents as rents vary inversely with the vacancy rate. Using annual data from 1961-1971 for five Canadian cities, Halifax, Montreal, Toronto, Winnipeg and Vancouver, he regresses the vacancy, lagged vacancy, property tax change, and lagged property tax change to determine the change in rents. It was found that the vacancy rate and the rate of change in property taxes do significantly affect the change in rents. Along with corroborating the original structure presented by Blank and Winnick (1953), the study also was able to calculate the natural vacancy rate for the five cities.

Following similar lines to the Smith (1974) study, Eurbank and Sirmans (1979) study the

structural model using operating expenses and vacancy rates using data from 1967-1974 on four United States cities and four different apartment types. The study found that the operating expenses were more important in predicting changes in rent levels than the vacancy rate. Using data from 17 United States cities Rosen and Smith (1983) confirm that the rental price changes are significantly affected by excess supply or demand in the marketplace. They find that both the vacancy rate and operating expenses are significant in predicting the percentage increase in rents.

Rosen (1984) added an additional variable to the previously completed research. He connected the stock of office space in addition to the vacancy and rent variables previously used. Using these variables and data from San Francisco from 1961-1983, he created three equations to determine the changes in rental rates. The first equation estimated the stock of office space as a function of employment, rent and price. The regression analysis of this equation showed that there was a strong positive relationship between occupied stock and FIRE employment. It also showed a negative relationship between real rents and occupied stock. The second equation estimated the rent as a function of the change in rents, the natural vacancy, the actual vacancy and the change in the overall price level. The regression analysis of this equation confirmed that changes in rent are inversely related to changes in vacancy, and that changes in rent are directly related to changes in the cost of living. The third equation explained occupied office stock as a function of the stock in the previous period and the new office stock completions. Through the regression analysis he found that this equation was not important in determining the supply, only lagged vacancy was significant.

(9)

Further expanding the research on structural econometric models to analyze the office market, Wheaton (1987) undertakes research to determine if there is a national real estate cycle. The national office market is analyzed using five time series: construction, completions, office employment, absorption, and vacancy rate. Three behavioral equations are specified to describe the market process. The first, the absorption equation, is specified as a function of the level of office employment, current real rents, expectations of future space needs, rate of employment growth, and amount of demand realized each year. The second equation describes supply as a function of the cost of construction, the cost to finance construction, current rent, current

vacancy, future expectations upon project completion and rate of employment growth. The final equation describes the rent adjustment process using current rent and vacancy, the previous period’s realized rent and the natural vacancy level. In addition, three identities are specified: net absorption which is the difference between the occupied stock this period and last period, the occupied stock which is the total office stock multiplied by the percentage of occupancy (1-vacancy rate), and the total office stock which is made up of the previous period’s office stock plus the completions in the previous period. Using this system of six equations he is able to forecast the real estate cycle ahead and finds in the immediate future the oversupply will not clear as fast as it has in previous cycles.

Schilling, et al. (1987) applied the structural econometric model to 17 United States cities to determine if the unoccupied space has an impact on what landlords are able to charge for rent in the local office market. Using the pooled approach on the office data, they find that the operating expenses are significant in explaining changes in rent in only four of the cities, while vacancy rate is significant in eleven of the cities. The study finds unrealistic values for the natural vacancy rates in the cities.

Gabriel and Nothaft (1987) apply the structural model to rental housing in 16 United States cities using data from 1981-1985. They confirm that the vacancy rate is important in explaining the rental rate adjustment process in rental housing.

The research on the relationship between vacancy and rental rates is further studied by Wheaton and Torto (1988) with the examination of the relationship between excess vacancy and changes in rent. Excess vacancy is defined as the difference between the natural vacancy rate and the actual vacancy rate. The research finds that the natural vacancy is increasing over time. It also finds that the relationship between excess vacancy and real rents is statistically significant and quantitatively meaningful.

Silver and Goode (1990) determined rents for retail properties in Britain derived as a reduced form equation from supply, demand and equilibrium equations. They find that demand for retail space is determined to be a function of rents charged, current expenditures in retail outlets, and an asset demand (investor demand) component.

Wheaton et al. (1997) estimate three structural equations for the London office market using data from 1970-1995. The three structural equations for office space demand, new supply and rental movements are accompanied by two identities to determine the stock and vacancy. They find the increase in construction can be explained with the traditional model but only as long as the

(10)

previous boom is taken into consideration. The movements in demand and rent are explained by the office employment growth. Finally, they find that rents react to changes in the vacancy rates and to leasing activity.

Research  on  Non-­‐Structural  Econometric  Models  in  Commercial  Rent  Analysis  

Dobson and Goddard (1992) relate prices, rents and exogenous economic variables in industrial, retail and office properties in a British time series from 1972-1987. They recognize that

commercial property is a factor of production as well as an asset with stored value. The models developed take into account this feature of commercial property as well as distinctions between different types of property users and different types of property owners. The research concludes that prices and rents are sensitive to employment rates, interest rates and residential property values.

Using a reduced form demand-supply model D’Arcy, et al. (1997) study 22 European cities with data from 1982-1994 to explore the impact of national economic conditions, market size,

measures of office growth and changes in the city economy to explain fluctuations in office rents. They find that national GDP and short-term interest rates are important predictors of office rent, while market size and city economic growth have an insignificant impact on office rent. D’Arcy, et al. (1999) expands on their research with the addition of available supply side data in the Dublin office market. Dublin presented a substantial challenge as it is a small market and with that large swings in supply can occur in any year due to new completions. Rent is specified as a function of service sector employment, GDP, and stock of office floor space. They find that real GDP lagged one period, and changes in office space lagged three periods are significant determinants of rental rates.

Thompson and Tsolacos (1999) use the reduced form demand-supply model to analyze the industrial market in the United Kingdom. They specify real rent as a function of lagged changes in GDP, industrial vacancy rates and lagged values of rental rate changes. They find that real rent changes are related positively to real GDP and inversely affected by absorption rates.

Taking a global approach De Wit and van Dijk (2003) research the determinants of office returns for 46 major markets in Asia, Europe and the United States. They find that GDP, inflation, unemployment, vacancy rate and available office stock all have an impact on real estate returns. Research  on  Error  Correction  Models  in  Commercial  Rental  Analysis  

Research starting in the early 2000’s has explored error correction models (ECM) as a way to estimate long-run equilibrium relationships and short-term dynamic corrections of commercial real estate. Error correction models do not require the variables to be stationary, however it does require that they be cointegrated.

(11)

Hendershott, et al. (2002a) use London data to estimate both the long-run relationship and the short-run adjustment equation. The error correction model they specify has been widely used in the literature that has followed. They conclude that the ECM model has many advantages over the vacancy gap model. The coefficients in the ECM have useful economic interpretations, the price and income elasticities of demand. As well it does not require estimates of real interest rates and risk, and it can be used in studies where vacancy data is unavailable.

 

Following the research described above Hendershott, et al. (2002b) continues with analysis using the error correction model framework by examining London retail and office properties. The Hendershott, et al. (2002b) study concludes that economic drivers may vary, there is no evidence of differences in the operation of property markets outside of London and they find that

elasticities for retail and office properties are similar. The final models presented support the use of an error correction model framework.

De Francesco (2008) uses the error correction model framework to analyze the Sydney and Melbourne office markets. Within the framework vacancy and the work-space ratio are allowed to be endogenously determined. The research looks at the rental adjustment mechanism and the demand-employment relationship. In addition whether office market determinants have a permanent or transitional effect is studied. With the rental adjustment model he finds that in Sydney the vacancy rate and the real interest rate are long-term determinants, while in

Melbourne only vacancy is a long-term determinant. In the demand-employment relationship he finds that a variety of macroeconomic factors have a transitory influence while real rent and real interest are long-term demand drivers only in Sydney.

Using 15 United State’s metropolitan statistical areas, Brounen and Jennen (2009a) adapt the Hendershott, et al model above to test the asymmetry in rent response to positive changes in office employment. They find that rents adjust positively with a rise in office employment and lagged rent rate changes. They also find that office rents react stronger to changes in employment when the vacancy rate has deviated from the natural level.

Brounen and Jennen (2009b) use the Hendershott, et al. model specified above to determine whether the long run relationships between premier and second tier cities are similar in ten European markets. This is to test whether local and national markets move in sync; if they do not move in sync then a local model based on national economics would be inaccurate. They find that national and local changes in economic variables to a large extent move in tandem. The results do not provide evidence that the economic variables defined at the local or national level produce better estimates.

Again using the Hendershott, et al model above, Ibanez (2013) investigates how rental rates evolve over time across four different property types, office, industrial, flex and retail. The study focuses on the speed at which rents move back to equilibrium and it’s found that the office market is the slowest to return to equilibrium levels.

(12)

Research  on  the  Comparison  of  Structural  versus  Non-­‐Structural  Models  in   Macroeconomics  

Sims (1980) advocates an alternative class of model, one which there is the opportunity to drop standard economic assumptions while retaining the ability to test meaningful hypothesis. He suggests that the vector autoregressive model could be the alternate class of model as it can still capture the rich inter-relationship between variables in the time series analysis. He comes to the conclusion that it is unlikely that macroeconomic models have been over identified.

Sims (1989) theorizes that an ideal model is made up of three important features. The model contains an interpretation of the behavioral interactions for all of the included parameters. It also connects to the data in detail and takes into account the inherent uncertainty of behavioral hypothesis. He recommends experimenting with simple behavioral models before moving into a vector autoregressive model as a safeguard to ensure that interpretations of the vector

autoregressive model are theatrically valid. In the research he uses interest rates, money stock, output and price level to show how useful interpreting evidence from a vector autoregressive model can be.

Clements and Mizon (1991) analyze structural and non-structural models by using a vector autoregressive model to assess the merits of the structural model. They present the two models in a complementary (as opposed to competing) format and suggest using the vector autoregressive model to suggest an efficient model development strategy.

3.  Exploratory  Data  Analysis  

Toronto  Office  Market  Overview  

Toronto is the capital city of the province of Ontario, and is Canada’s largest city. According to the 2011 Canadian census, the population of the greater Toronto area is approximately 5.5 million and the population within the city of Toronto is approximately 2.6 million1. Toronto is the largest Canadian office market with over 150 million total square feet of office stock as of the fourth quarter of 20132. The key industries occupying office space in Toronto include business and professional services, financial services, design services, fashion and apparel services, film and television services, music services, life sciences and tourism.

Toronto is the financial center of Canada and is the location of the Toronto Stock Exchange. As well the financial district is centered on Bay Street, the Canadian equivalent to Wall Street. The big five Canadian banks, the Bank of Montreal, Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce, Toronto-Dominion Bank, Royal Bank of Canada, and the Bank of Nova Scotia all have their headquarters in Toronto.

Many large Canadian corporations have their headquarters in Toronto; eighteen of Canada’s fifty most profitable companies have their headquarters in Toronto. Global headquarters in Toronto include Brookfield Asset Management, Fairmont Hotels and Resorts, Manulife Financial, Nortel,

1 Census information can be accessed through: http://www12.statcan.gc.ca/census-recensement/2011/as-sa/fogs-spg/Facts-cma-eng.cfm?LANG=Eng&GK=CMA&GC=535

(13)

the Hudson’s Bay Company, Bell Media and Rogers Corporation. Canadian operation corporate headquarters located in Toronto include McDonald’s Canada, Coca-Cola Company, Sirius Canada, and Marriott International. In addition to being the center of the Canadian financial industry, Toronto is also the center of the Canadian media industry. Focus in the fashion, film and music industry has given aided in business services occupying a significant portion of the Toronto marketplace.

Variable  Descriptions  

The dataset is provided by the CBRE Econometric Advisors Canadian Office, and contains quarterly observations for the Toronto office market. The dataset contains nine variables as described below:

1. Year – Observation year and quarter

2. FIRE Emp. (Jobs x 1000) – Finance, insurance, and real estate services employment sector

3. Business Svc. Emp. (Jobs x 1000) – Business services employment sector 4. Office Stock (SF x 1000) – Total office space square footage

5. Completions (SF x 1000) – Office space completions during the observation year and quarter

6. Net Absorption (SF x 100) – Office space absorbed by market during the observation year and quarter

7. Vacancy Rate (%) – Vacancy rate

8. Net Effective Rent ($) – Nominal rental rate

9. Net Effective Rent (2013 $) – Real rental rate expressed in 2013 values

The variables used in the final analysis are: Year, Business Svc. Emp., Office Stock, Vacancy Rate, Net Effective Rent (2013 $). Using these variables the following additional variables have been computed:

1. Occupied Stock = (1-Vacancy Rate) * Office Stock

2. Occupied Stock First Difference (Computed Net Absorption) = Occupied Stockt – Occupied Stockt-1

3. Office Stock First Difference (Net Completions) = Office Stockt – Office Stockt-1 4. Real Net Effective Rent First Difference = Real Net Effective Rentt – Real Net Effective

Rentt-1

5. Year-Over-Year Completions = Office Stockt-4 – Office Stockt

6. Year-Over-Year Employment Growth = Business Services Employmentt-4 – Business Services Employmentt

7. Year-Over-Year Absorption = Occupied Stockt-4 – Occupied Stockt

8. Year-Over-Year Rent Growth = Real Net Effective Rentt-4 –Real Net Effective Rentt Note that while completions are available in the dataset, a net completions has been computed using the first difference of occupied stock. Due to redevelopment happening in the office space market, net completions takes into account the fact that some buildings may have been

demolished and new buildings built in their place. The completions variable available in the dataset is gross completions and does not take into account this reduction in stock due to demolition.

(14)

Descriptive Statistics

Variable Mean Median Std. Dev. Min Max

FIRE Emp 228.8581 214.8 44.03406 169 321.6

Bus Svc Emp 296.4382 279.3 109.5947 135.2 488.9

Office Stock 117,389.7 127,284 28,424.08 56,370 151,440

Real Net Effective Rent 19.86919 17.515 8.73251 4.42 39.01

Vacancy Rate 0.12367 0.117 0.04392 0.066 0.227

Occupied Stock 102,810.5 107,109.5 25,915.61 51,522.18 138,086.5

Occupied Stock First Difference

(Computed Net Absorption) 634.6849 598.9375 808.31 -1,644.71 3,549.828

Office Stock First Difference

(Computed Net Completions) 704.2222 490 750.0381 0 4,515

Real Net Effective Rent First

Difference -0.04022 0.15999 1.07785 -3.83 3.49

Year-Over-Year Completions 2799.795 1822.5 2495.91 0 8733

Year-Over-Year Employment

Growth 10.4197 8.7 14.97133 -24.3 46.3

Year-Over-Year Absorption 2541.654 2412.439 2285.881 -3145.61 7090.33

Year-Over-Year Rent Growth -0.20667 0.30 3.6165 -15.09 6.3100

Economic  Variables  

The dataset presents two economic indicator variables, FIRE employment and business services employment. From the above descriptive statistics we can see that while business services employment starts lower than FIRE employment it ends significantly higher. The following graph illustrates the patterns in the economic variables from quarter one of 1980 to quarter four of 2013.

(15)

Both series show an increasing trend until the late 1980’s and then a stagnant period in the early 1990s during the 1990-1991 recession. The FIRE employment stays stagnant for a considerably longer period after the recession than business services employment. The business services series shows a much stronger increase throughout the late 1990s until present than does the FIRE employment series. Business service employment also shows a stronger recover from the 2008-2009 global recession.

(16)

Office  Stock  

The office stock series shows a large increase in stock from 1980 to the early 1990’s. The gain in stock exhibited during this period is more than the total increase in stock from the end of the building boom until present. Incorporating the knowledge of the 1990-1991 recession, the conclusion that the decrease in building output occurs a few years after the recession is consistent with developers taking building signals from the current economic state. However, given that office buildings are a product with a long-term build schedule, the additional stock coming onto the market is consistent with buildings that were started previous to the recession.

(17)

Rent  and  Vacancy  

The real net effective rent peaks at a value of $39.01 in the fourth quarter of 1989. Following this peak, the rent falls to a low of $4.42 in the fourth quarter of 1993. From this point the rent does not recover to it’s previous high; the highest real net effective rent achieved after the low is $23.61 in the first quarter of 2001.

This type of real rental rate pattern is similar to that of cities with significant ability access to new supply. This is more typical of cities that have weak constraints on supply, either

geographical or political, than Toronto, which is typically considered land constrained. This is pattern of real rental rates is also characterized by rents that show less sensitivity to vacancy rates.

(18)

The two main peaks, the rental high in 1989 and the rental rate low in 1993, correspond to the same two peaks in the vacancy rate. As vacancy and rents typically have an inverse relationship to one another the rental high corresponds to a low in the vacancy rate, and the rental low corresponds to a high in the vacancy rate. The two series exhibit this inverse relationship until the early 2000s. After this point they both appear to level out and the relationship doesn’t look to be as strong.

4.  Structural  Econometric  Model  

Structural  Model  Framework  

The economic theory of the structural econometric model is defined by the following relationships when demand is estimated directly:

1. Rent is determined exclusively through vacancy: Rent = F(Vacancy)

2. Long-run supply curve is determined by the real rental rate: Supply = F(Rent)

3. Demand (occupied stock) is determined through the employment variable as an economic indicator and the rental rate

Occupied Stock = F(Employment, Rent) 4. The vacancy rate is determined as:

(19)

Vacancy = 1 – (Occupied Stock/Stock)

When demand is estimated indirectly the structural econometric model is estimated through the following system of equations:

1. Rent is determined exclusively through vacancy: Rent = F(Vacancy)

2. Long-run supply curve is determined by the real rental rate: Supply = F(Rent)

3. Demand is determined through estimating vacancy as a function of the employment variable as an economic indicator, the rental rate, and the total office stock

Vacancy = F(Employment, Rent, Stock)

In addition, to complete the structural model framework two further identities are required: 1. Occupied Stockt = Total Stockt-1 + Absorptiont-1

2. Total Stockt = Total Stockt-1 + Constructiont-1

The following variables required for the structural model have been computed in the dataset as: Occupied Stockt = (1 - Vacancy Ratet) * Office Stockt

Net Absorptiont = Occupied Stockt – Occupied Stockt-1 Completionst = Office Stockt – Office Stockt-1

When appropriate the structural model is constructed using the variables in levels (using only the actual variables and the lagged versions of themselves). However, the equations can also be specified in differences and in the ECM framework, the equations will be specified in

differences. In order to specify any of the equations in levels the variables must be stationary, if they are not an ordinary least squares regression is not appropriate. If the variables do not show stationarity and the series are cointegrated, then an error correction model can be used to estimate the relationships.

Stationarity  Tests  of  Variables  

To decide if the structural equations can be specified, as preferred by the economic theory, in levels the variables are tested to determine if they are stationary. The stationarity test results will provide a starting point to creating the general framework for the econometric equations.

Dickey and Fuller (1979) developed the procedure to test whether a variable has a unit root. The original test was further developed to allow lags into the autoregressive process by Said and Dickey (1984). The augmented Dickey-Fuller test has the null hypothesis that the series has a unit root; the alternative hypothesis is that a stationary process generates the series. The augmented Dickey-Fuller test fits a model of the form:

Δxt = α + βxt-1 + ζ1Δxt-1 + ζ2Δxt-2 +…+ ζnΔxt-n + εt

where n is the number of lags specified for the test. The augmented Dickey-Fuller tests whether β=0, which is equivalent to xt having a unit root.

To test for stationarity of the variables, the augmented Dickey-Fuller test is used for each of the variables. As the test is very sensitive to the number of lags used, the optimal number of lags will be selected for each variable using the Akaike’s Information Criterion (AIC), and the augmented Dickey-Fuller test explored for this optimal number of lags. The summary chart below shows the results of the tests for stationarity:

(20)

Stationarity Results – Dickey-Fuller and Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Results

Variable Optimum Lag

(AIC)

Test Statistic (optimum lag)

MacKinnon p-value (optimum lag)

Business Service Employment 6 0.259 0.9754

Business Service Employment First Difference

5 -4.512 0.0002

Net Effective Rent (Real) 5 -2.658 0.0815

Net Effective Rent (Real) First Difference

4 -2.845 0.0521

Vacancy 4 -2.612 0.0905

Vacancy First Difference 2 -3.510 0.0077

Occupied Stock 2 -1.939 0.3140

Occupied Stock First Difference (Net Absorption)

1 -5.547 0.0000

Office Stock 4 -2.010 0.2824

Office Stock First Difference (Net Completions)

4 -2.361 0.1531

The time series for the economic variable, business services employment, is not stationary series. However, when the first difference the series is stationary at a 1% significance level3. Real net effective rent and the vacancy rate are stationary at the 10% level for their optimum number of lags. The occupied stock series is stationary without any lags and the first difference of the occupied stock series, net absorption, is stationary at the 1% level for without lags and the optimum number of lags. The total office stock series and its first difference, net completions, are stationary without any lags.

The variables stationary in levels are real net effective rent and vacancy. All of the variables are stationary in differences, including the employment variable.

Note that while total employment, FIRE employment and their respective first differences are not used in the final analysis, they were explored as options for the economic indicator variable when selecting the optimum variable set. As such they have been included in the stationarity analysis and the results of these tests are summarized in the Appendix.

A direct regression with non-stationary series would be problematic, as such going forward the stationarity results as summarized above will be important in defining the econometric equations. Cointegration  Tests  

Two series are cointegrated if they tend to move together through time, sharing a stochastic drift. The error correction model framework approach requires that the variables exhibit cointegration. Engle and Granger (1987) suggest a two-step process to determine cointegration. Using an ordinary least squares (OLS) a regression equation is first determined between the two variables. The augmented Dickey-Fuller test is used to test the stationarity of the residuals from this

regression. The augmented Dickey-Fuller test has the null hypothesis that the residuals are nonstationary. As such a statistically significant result produces the conclusion that the residuals

3 For the Augmented Dickey-Fuller tests the following critical values from MacKinnon (1996) are used: 1% -3.49, 5% -2.89, 10% -2.58, 20% -2.21.

(21)

are stationary and the series are cointegrated. This process will be used to determine

cointegrating relationships for the rental equation, the supply equation, and the four demand equations in the structural framework. As with the stationary tests the results are sensitive to the number of lags used, as such the AIC has been used to select the optimum number of lags. The cointegration tests that were explored for the econometric equations are summarized below4.

Real  Rental  Rate  Equation  

Starting the cointegration tests with the relationship between rent and vacancy, it is determined that real net effective rent is not cointegrated with vacancy nor with vacancy lagged four, eight or twelve periods for the optimum number of lags. A summary table of the statistical results is provided below:

Cointegration with Real Net Effective Rent

Variable R2 Regression Optimum Lag (AIC) ADF Test Statistic (Optimum Lag) MacKinnon p-value (Optimum Lag) Vacancy 0.0896 6 -2.164 0.2194

Vacancy- 4 period lag 0.2379 2 -1.070 0.7269 Vacancy- 8 period lag 0.2985 2 -1.479 0.5439 Vacancy- 12 period lag 0.2580 5 -2.194 0.2083

The relationship between vacancy and the real net effective rental rate is not cointegrated at any statistical level, even when lagged vacancy has been introduced. As such, the equation where the rental rate level is determined solely by the vacancy rate cannot be specified as an error

correction model.

The relationship between vacancy and the first difference of the real net effective rental rate (change in rent) was also explored. The quarterly change in rent shows cointegration with the vacancy series at 1% when the AIC optimum one lag is included5.

Long-­‐Run  Supply  Equation  

Moving into the supply equation and starting with single variable cointegration tests with total office stock it is determined that none of the employment relationships exhibit cointegration even at a very generous 20% level.

As the econometric equation specified for supply equation can be multivariate, testing various combinations of independent variables with dependent variable total office stock have been included. Using the results from the AIC determination of the optimum lag in the residuals, the only combinations that do not show cointegration are the two combinations with the rental and vacancy rate lagged one and four periods and the combination with only business services employment and real net effective rent. From these results it is determined that the best

4 For the sake of brevity, only the full statistical outputs for the final econometric equations are included in the Appendix. As well summary charts for the cointegration tests for variable combinations that ultimately were not selected for the econometric models are also available in the Appendix.

5 For the Augmented Dickey-Fuller tests the following critical values from MacKinnon (1996) are used: 1% -3.49, 5% -2.89, 10% -2.58, 20% -2.21.

(22)

combination of cointegrating relationships with total office stock is with business services, real net effective rent lagged one period and the vacancy rate lagged one period.

The supply equation can also be specified as a change in stock instead of using total office stock as the dependent variable. As such the cointegrating relationships with the first difference of office stock (net completions) will also be explored. The following chart shows the results of the cointegration between net completions and real net effective rent, the variables used in

specifying the supply equation.

Cointegration with Total Office Stock First Difference (Net Completions)

Variable R2 Regression Optimum Lag (AIC) ADF Test Statistic (Optimum Lag) MacKinnon p-value (Optimum Lag) Real Net Effective Rent 0.4033 1 -5.827 0.0000

Net completions show cointegration with business services employment and total employment in addition to real net effective rent at the 10% level6. Similar to total office stock, the supply equation can be specified as a multivariate regression with net completions as the dependent variable. All of the tested combinations of independent variables show cointegration with net completions at the 10% for the augmented Dickey-Fuller test with the optimum number of lags as selected using AIC. Net completions show very significant cointegration with all the

combinations of independent variables at the optimum lag length. The only set of variables that is less significant, business services employment and vacancy rate, are still significant at the 10% level.

Based on the cointegration relationships of the independent variables with office stock both in levels and in differences, it is likely that the final choice of variables for the supply equation in the structural model will be cointegrated. If the final model shows cointegration an error correction model can be specified for this equation.

Demand  Equations  

The demand variable can be specified either directly or indirectly and either in levels or in differences; as such four separate combinations of cointegration relationships will be explored. The first is for the direct specification of demand in levels and will test potential cointegrating relationships with occupied stock.

The following chart shows the results of the cointegration between occupied stock and the multivariate selection real net effective rent and business services employment, the variables used when specifying the demand equation in levels. Occupied stock doesn’t exhibit

cointegration with any of the multivariate combinations of series explored, nor does it exhibit cointegration individual with real net effective rent, business services employment, FIRE employment or total employment.

6 For the Augmented Dickey-Fuller tests the following critical values from MacKinnon (1996) are used: 1% -3.49, 5% -2.89, 10% -2.58, 20% -2.21.

(23)

Multivariate Cointegration with Occupied Stock Variable R2 Regression Optimum Lag (AIC) ADF Test Statistic (Optimum Lag) MacKinnon p-value (Optimum Lag) Real Net Effective Rent, Business

Services Employment 0.9493 6 -2.087 0.2497

The demand equation can also be indirectly specified in levels by using vacancy as the dependent variable, and the changes in office stock and business services as explanatory

variables. All of the multivariate combinations tested show cointegration with vacancy, as do the employment variables; the following table summarizes the results of the cointegration tests for the combination of variables used in specifying the indirect demand equation in levels:

Multivariate Cointegration with Vacancy

Variable R2 Regression Optimum Lag (AIC) ADF Test Statistic (Optimum Lag) MacKinnon p-value (Optimum Lag) Business Services Employment,

Office Stock, and Real Net Effective Rent

0.7988 6 -4.324 0.0004

Demand can also be specified both directly and indirectly using differences. These models will specified with net absorption and the change in vacancy as the dependent variables. Starting with the relationships with net absorption, all of the variables and variable combinations show

significant cointegration with the net absorption series. The following table summarizes the results of the cointegration tests for the combination of variables used in specifying the direct demand equation in differences:

Multivariate Cointegration with Occupied Stock First Difference (Net Absorption)

Variable R2 Regression Optimum Lag (AIC) ADF Test Statistic (Optimum Lag) MacKinnon p-value (Optimum Lag) Real Net Effective Rent, Business

Services Employment 0.0704 1 -5.942 0.0000

The final specification of demand for the structural systems will be using the change in vacancy. This is the indirect demand equation specified in differences. Similar to the net absorption series, all of the variables and variable combinations explored show cointegration with the change in vacancy series. The following table summarizes the results of the cointegration tests for the combination of variables used in specifying the indirect demand equation in differences:

Multivariate Cointegration with Vacancy First Difference

Variable R2 Regression Optimum Lag (AIC) ADF Test Statistic (Optimum Lag) MacKinnon p-value (Optimum Lag) Real Net Effective Rent, Business

Services Employment, and Office Stock

(24)

Both the direct demand and the indirect equations show a stronger cointegrating relationship with business services employment than they do with total employment. Based on the

cointegration relationships of the independent variables when demand is specified both directly and indirectly, it is likely that the final choice of variables for the demand equation in the

structural model will be cointegrated. If the final models for demand show cointegration an error correction model can be specified for the equation.

Summary  of  Cointegration  Test  Results  

For the rental rate equation the series does not show cointegration with the vacancy rate series. As such an error correction model cannot be specified for this relationship. However, since the series are individually stationary a regular ordinary least squares regression can be used to estimate their relationship.

The supply equation explored using net completions shows cointegrating relationships with the majority of the combinations of independent variables. Once the final equation has been

determined it is likely that an error correction model will be able to be specified, however, a final check on the cointegration of the specified series will be tested to ensure the error correction framework is appropriate.

The only demand equation that does not show a cointegration relationship is that with occupied stock (direct demand in levels). The remaining three options for demand to complete the system of equations in the structural framework show cointegrating relationships. Both of the equations specified in differences show strong cointegration, which will be particularly important, as these equations will be specified as error correction models.

Real  Rental  Rate  Equation  

The structural model assumes that changes in rent are determined exclusively through deviations in the vacancy rate from the natural vacancy rate. As office properties tend to have long-term leases, rents will tend to be slow to adjust to changes in the vacancy rates. While the strength of the inverse relationship between the change in real rental rates and the vacancy rate in the Toronto dataset depletes in the early 2000s the series does show the typical relationship: low (high) vacancy rates correspond to high (low) real rental rates.

Vacancy is the state through which space passes through while waiting to be leased. It can be quite cumbersome for a tenant to find appropriate space for their needs as vacant space can come in very different sizes and spatial arrangements. Once an appropriate space has been found owners and tenants can begin bargaining over the lease agreements, including the rental rate. Owners set a minimum reserve price for the space at which they are indifferent between renting the space to the tenant and leaving it vacant. The longer the anticipated lease up time the lower the reservation price will be. Tenants similarly set a maximum reserve price for the space, the price at which they are indifferent between leasing the space and continuing to search for a different vacant space. When there is ample available vacant space and few tenants in the

market, it is easier for the tenant to find space and the maximum reserve price will be lower. The final agreed upon price should lie between the owner’s reservation price and the tenant’s

reservation price, Wheaton, et al. (1997). Both the owner’s and the tenant’s reservation price move inversely with vacancy, Wheaton (1990).

(25)

The modern theory of search and bargaining specifies that a given level of vacancy, either above or below the natural rate, does not cause rents to rise or fall continuously, Wheaton and Torto (1993). This deviation from the natural vacancy rate leads to a stable level of rent reflective of the rental rate that would be an acceptable outcome of bargaining.

Reflecting that rents do not fall or rise continuously for a given level of vacancy, the relationship between the real rental rate and vacancy will be specified generally as:

Real Rentt = a + b*Vacancy Ratet + c* Real Rentt-n Econometric  Model  

From the stationarity tests results, we know that both rent and vacancy are stationary series. As well from the cointegration it was determined that the two series are not cointegrated. An error correction model cannot be specified for this equation, however, since both series are stationary an ordinary least squares regression analysis can be specified for the relationship between the two variables. As such, the econometric model for the real rent at time t will be specified as (where n≥0):

Real Rentt = a – b*Vacancy Ratet-n + c*Real Rentt-n

Models that were investigated but subsequently discarded are summarized in the Appendix. The real rent equation as specified using yearly lags using the Toronto data yields7:

Real Rentt = 8.29371 – 43.5531*Vacancy Ratet-4 + 0.8467268*Real Rentt-4

(6.85) (-6.77) (26.38)

Adjusted R2 = 0.8799; N = 132; F(2,129) = 480.91

The coefficients on the vacancy rate and the lagged real rent are in the correct direction. The model suggests that rent would have a stable value of approximately $20 using a vacancy of 12% (the average vacancy rate between 1980-2013 for Toronto). As shown through the vacancy rate coefficient, vacancy has an inverse relationship with the rental rate. This result is consistent with conclusions drawn from previous research on the relationship between the vacancy rate and rent. The coefficient on the lagged real rent of 0.85 is consistent with the rental rate being sticky and having a slow speed of adjustment to changes in the vacancy rate. The market would move towards an equilibrium rent at 15% per year. This slow rate of adjustment is expected, as office leases are generally long-term. As well, the slow rate of adjustment reflects the fact that real rent and vacancy are poorly correlated and not cointegrated. The model with only vacancy as the

independent variable has an R2 of only 0.0896, and without the series being cointegrated this

relationship cannot be improved upon without additional variables being specified to the model.

(26)

The above graph depicts the dynamic forecast based on the model with the coefficients as

specified above. The lagged rent variable is endogenous while the remaining variables are treated as exogenous to the equation for the purposes of this graph. The predicted rental values show the

same general pattern as the actual rental rates, which are expected with the high R2 of the model

and the lagged rent variable being present in the model. However, the dynamic forecast provides much more extreme swings in movement than the actual rental rates experienced. The

predictions exhibit overcorrections, most notably becoming negative in the mid-1990s and a large increase after 2005.

Long-­‐Run  Supply  Equation  

The long-run supply is measured as the net completions added to the previous periods total office stock. New office space is developed when the value of developing the space exceeds the cost to develop it. The value of an office space asset is directly correlated to the rent that it can generate. The net effective rental income is used to measure the value typically along with a capitalization rate. It follows from the asset value calculation that the amount of completions should be related to the real net effective rent.

The graph below compares the movement of the real rental rate over time and the net

completions delivered to the market. The peak in net completions occurs shortly after the peak in the rental rate, which would be due to the long-term construction in delivering new office space into the market. The decision to develop space occurs long before the space is actually delivered

(27)

to the market suggesting that the completions delivered to the market are dependent on a lagged rental rate.

The supply equation is specified as a change in supply because the real rental rate does not show an increasing trend. Supply has an increasing trend throughout the dataset even though the real rental rate is not increasing. As such it will not be possible to have a correctly signed equation, which according to economic theory would be increase in supply is due to an increase in real rent, using supply and real rent.

Reflecting that the decision to deliver office stock based on the prevailing market rental rate occurs before the completions are delivered to the market, the relationship for the long-run office supply will be specified generally as:

Net Completionst = a + b* Real Rentt-n Econometric  Model  

From the stationarity tests results, we know that both net completions and vacancy are stationary series. As both series are stationary an ordinary least squares regression analysis can be specified for the relationship between the two variables. As such, the econometric model for the net

completions at time t will be specified as (where n≥0): Net Completionst = a + b* Real Rentt-n

(28)

Models that were investigated but subsequently discarded are summarized in the Appendix. The year-over-year net completions equation as specified using yearly lags using the Toronto data yields8:

Net CompletionsYoY = -1838.373 + 231.9822*Real Rentt-4 (-5.95) (16.41)

Adjusted R2 = 0.6718; N = 132; F(1,130) = 269.13

The coefficient on the lagged rental value is positive, as expected. Rent increases act as a signal to developers to increase development resulting in more net completions in one-year time. With the last observed rent, $15.56, in the dataset (the fourth quarter of 2013) we can anticipate that there will be approximately 1.85 million square feet of office space added to the market by the end of 2014. As well the equation suggests that real rent would have to fall to $7.92 in real dollars in order for development to completely cease.

  The above graph shows the predicted values for the yearly changes in supply and the actual yearly changes in supply. The predicted values follow a much smoother course for reasons including a smoothing effect. Actual supply tends to be delivered in large amounts when large buildings are completed and the predicted values do not reflect the times when an atypical

(29)

amount of supply is delivered due to a large development’s completion. The predicted values also unrealistically have negative values. This is a short-coming of the predicted values as in reality, when real rent decreases space is not demolished to return the system to equilibrium, rather developments not yet completed are completed and new developments are not started until market conditions improve.

Demand  Equations  

Previous research indicates that the primary office demand driver is employment in select economic sectors, DiPasquale and Wheaton (1995). These economic sectors are the main users of office space and growth in their workforces translates into a need for more office space. Studies of the economic sectors in the United States submit that greater than 75% of the space in larger buildings is occupied by the FIRE or the business service sector of the economy, Wheaton (1987).

Given that the demand depends on the number of space users it follows that it would also be related to the stock of space. The availability of space and the total supply of space also impact the demand of space. If every office worker in Toronto were to use the exact same amount of space a comparison between the change in occupied stock and employment change should follow the same path, increases in office workers should lead to a proportionate increase in space to the number of workers added. The graph below shows the relationship between the amount of occupied stock and the amount of business services employment throughout the data series. When the absorption and change in office workers diverge the amount of office space per worker is changing.

(30)

DiPasquale and Wheaton (1995) attribute the difference in changes in office space and changes in employment to two explanations. The first is that as the makeup of the workforce changes so too does the space the changing workforce will occupy. Their example to illustrate this theory is that clerical services will use less office space than management services will, and if technology is eliminating clerical jobs then it would be expected that the space per worker would rise over time. The second explanation for the differing changes in office spaces and changes in

employment are predicated on the fact that office space is a factor of production. Similar to other factors of production, the amount of space used per worker should vary with the cost of

providing that space. As such, when office space costs rise it is expected that employers will reduce the amount of space per employee to reduce their costs, and conversely, when office space costs fall employers will provide more office space per employee.

At this point in the structural system of equations demand can be specified in one of two ways, directly or indirectly. When estimated directly occupied stock is estimated and then vacancy is created as an identity based off of this estimation. When estimated indirectly vacancy is

estimated directly and the occupied stock estimation is not necessary. Due to the lack of supply information in many European countries estimating demand indirectly is preferred. In the US the preferred estimation of demand is directly with the creation of vacancy through an identity. The direct demand equation will reflect the impacts that changes in employment, rent and the stock of space have on the amount of space occupied in the marketplace. The dependent variable

(31)

will be occupied stock and once estimated, vacancy will be derived using the estimation. This equation can be specified in both levels and differences. When estimated in levels, the actual occupied stock is estimated; when estimated in differences, the net absorption is estimated and occupied stock can then be calculated. The following equations show the general format for the direct demand equation in levels and then in differences:

Direct Demand Equation – Levels

Occupied Stockt = a + b*Employmentt + c*Real Net Effective Rentt-n Direct Demand Equation – Differences (Error Correction Model)

Net Absoprtiont = a + b*Employmentt + c*Real Net Effective Rentt-n + d*Occupied Stockt-n + e*Change in Employmentt + f*Change in Real Rentt

The indirect demand equation will reflect the impact that the above discussion of the impact of office space drivers has on the demand for office space. Vacancy will be used as the dependent variable in the equation as when vacancy rises it suggests that demand has lessened for the product. Reflecting that rental rates are solely dependent upon vacancy rates in the structural framework, lagged vacancy will be included to capture the change in demand for office space as a factor of production due to changes in cost. Changes in office space and employment are also included to reflect the change in demand due to increases in the stock of space and changes in the number of users of space. Similarly to the direct demand equations, the indirect demand

equations will be estimated both in levels (dependent variable is vacancy) and differences (dependent variable is change in vacancy).

The general form of the equations will be: Indirect Demand Equation – Levels

Vacancyt = a + b*Real Net Effective Rentt-n + c*Employmentt + d*Office Stockt Indirect Demand Equation – Differences (Error Correction Model)

Change in Vacancyt = a + b*Real Net Effective Rentt-n + c*Employmentt + d*Office Stockt + e*Vacancyt-n + f*Change in Employmentt + g*Change in Real Rentt + h*Change in Supplyt

Econometric  Model  –  Direct  Demand  in  Levels  

The cointegration test results showed that occupied stock series is not cointegrated with business services employment and the real net effective rent. Using the ordinary least squares analysis the following model has been estimated for the long-run direct demand equation (where n≥0):

Occupied Stockt = a + b*Business Services Employmentt + c*Real Net Effective Rentt-n Models that were explored but were not used for the direct demand equation in levels are

summarized in the Appendix. The occupied stock equation as specified using yearly lags using the Toronto data yields9:

Références

Documents relatifs

We could also have tested the impact of observable variables reflecting institutional characteristics of the goods and labour markets (trade union membership, replacement ratio,

To assess the robustness of our estimates, we control for unobserved state specific heterogeneity by including state effects, we evaluate the sensitivity of our results by

On sait d’autre part que l’´etat de contraintes des mat´eriaux magn´etiques au sein d’une machine tournant `a grande vitesse est multiaxial et que les modifications du

- Establish an internal cost structure that is more favourable than that of competitors: in order to improve productivity, prescribers will seek to implement

Once the time-varying degree of market integration becomes available, we test for structural breaks.. The estimation method developed by Bai and Perron (1998) is based on the

We use the autoregressive productivity shock and simulate three different models: (i) the stan- dard Walrasian real business cycle model (RBC), (ii) the model with frictions in

Sim- ilar to these models, ours allows to study the effects of early retirement transfers and aging on labor force participation but we find that these two shocks are insufficient

Table 5 reports the mean and the standard deviation scores of the variation of intensity for textual (∆ text ) and structural (∆ struct ) code smells, collected for Blob, Feature