• Aucun résultat trouvé

Determinants of insurance adoption among Bulgarian farmers

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "Determinants of insurance adoption among Bulgarian farmers"

Copied!
22
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

Determinants of insurance adoption among Bulgarian farmers: the importance of other risk management decisions on the farm

Marianne Lefebvre*, Dimitre Nikolov**, Sergio Gomez-y-Paloma*, Minka Chopeva**

Accepted for publication in Agricultural Finance Review vol:74, iss:3 (07-Feb-2014)

Abstract:

Purpose – This article aims to analyze the determinants of agricultural insurance adoption in Bulgaria, using a purpose-built survey of 224 farmers interviewed in 2011. The insurance decision is analyzed conjointly with other risk management decisions on the farm such as having contracts with retailers or processors, diversifying farm activities and using irrigation.

Design/methodology/approach – The agricultural insurance sector in Bulgaria is presented in the broader context of the transition to a market-oriented economy and integration of Bulgarian agriculture into the EU Common Agricultural Policy. The recent developments on the determinants of farm insurance adoption in the agricultural economics and finance literature are discussed. A multivariate probit model is used in order to determine the factors explaining the adoption or non- adoption of various risk management tools by the surveyed farmers, including farm insurance.

Findings – We find that farmers with diversified activities, using irrigation or having contracts with retailers or processors, are more likely to adopt insurance, after controlling for farms and farmers' structural characteristics. Additionally, we find that the main characteristics distinguishing farmers who purchase agricultural insurance from non-users are farm size and farm location. The existence of strong regional effect suggests the importance of adapting the insurance products to the different regional contexts in Bulgaria.

Originality/value – This paper contributes to the (limited) literature on agricultural insurance adoption in transition countries, currently shifting from a system where compensation against natural hazards tended to come from a State damage mitigation fund, inherited from the centrally planned governments to private and voluntary agricultural insurance. This research provides a unique data source on the Bulgarian case study.

JEL classification: Q14

Keywords: Agricultural insurance; Bulgaria; Risk management; Common agricultural policy;

Multivariate Probit

Article classification: Research paper

* European Commission, Joint Research Centre (JRC), Institute for Prospective Technological Studies (IPTS), Agrilife Unit, Edificio Expo. c/ Inca Garcilaso, 3, 41092 Seville, Spain

Corresponding author: Marianne.lefebvre@ec.europa.eu

** Institute of Agricultural Economics, Sofia, Bulgaria

(2)

Acknowledgments: The collection of data was funded by the project “Risk Management in Agriculture” (2011-2012), financed by the Bulgarian Agriculture Academy and the Ministry of Agriculture and Food. We would like to thank Anna Atkinson for careful proofreading and Salvador Barrios for helpful comments. The views expressed are purely those of the authors and may not in any circumstances be regarded as stating an official position of the European Commission.

(3)

1. Introduction

Following the break-up of the Soviet Union in 1990, many of the state-owned monopoly of agricultural insurers in Eastern Europe were privatized, and markets were opened up to competition by new private commercial companies providing crop and livestock insurance policies. With the transition towards a market-oriented economy, agricultural reform was characterised by the liquidation of the agricultural industrial complexes, the development of a private agricultural sector composed of a large number of small private farms (producing mainly for self-consumption) and big private production co-operatives, land restitution and price liberalisation (Garnevska et al. 2006).

Farmers now have to decide which crops to grow and how best to grow them by considering potential profits and risks, as well as whether to take out agricultural insurance. An insurance contract implies that the farmer pays a premium to buy the insurance which gives him the right to an indemnity, triggered by specific events (single peril insurance) or by a fall in yields/production below a certain threshold (multi-peril insurance). This paper deals with the determinants of agricultural insurance adoption in Bulgaria. It focuses on the uptake of agricultural insurance, but does not contain any information regarding the type of insurance or coverage provided to the farmer.

Bulgarian agricultural production is affected by many sources of risk beyond the farmer’s control, including natural hazards such as floods, storms, drought, hail, frost and fire. Agricultural insurance was introduced in Bulgaria after the restoration of the Bulgarian state in 1878, following the Russo- Turkish War (1877-1878). The insurance activity was developed through the establishment of insurance co-operative societies which controlled insurance activities until 1935. During the period from 1935 to 1946, agricultural insurance was managed by the Bulgarian Agricultural and Cooperative Bank. In 1946, when Bulgaria became a socialist state, the existing insurance companies were all merged to create a unique State Insurance Institute (DZI). DZI continued to be the only insurance company of the centrally planned Bulgarian economy for 15 years. In 1961, a second state insurance company, Bulstrat, was established.

During the 1980-1991 socialist period, agricultural insurance was compulsory. The DZI insurance scheme was akin to a support to agriculture as the compensation for losses largely exceeded the total premiums paid by the farmers. In 1989 the Communist Party allowed multi-party elections, following which Bulgaria transitioned to democracy and a market-based economy. Private agricultural insurance in Bulgaria dates back to the early years after the fall of the communist system.

In 1992, a voluntary insurance scheme for crops was implemented. Initially it only covered hailstorm and thunderstorm risks. Since then, private companies have started offering insurance products covering a range of farming risks; for crops: hailstorms, thunderstorms, torrential rain, floods, slush, frost, windstorms, tornadoes, fire; for livestock: death or emergency slaughter resulting from fire and natural disasters (providing veterinary requirements are observed, especially regarding vaccinations or prophylactic medicines).

In Bulgaria, the trend is now for the government to promote private agricultural insurance, backed by government financial support. The existence of private insurance schemes requires government support as information asymmetries and the systemic nature of some agricultural risks make private companies unwilling to cover those risks, or the administration and operating costs of offering these insurance policies are too high compared to what farmers are willing to pay (Smith and Glauber 2012). Intervention usually takes the form of either direct premium subsidies to the farmer or indirect subsidies for delivery costs, loss adjustment, or provision of reinsurance (Smith and Glauber 2012).

In the European Union, the different Member States have developed their own policies related to

(4)

production risk in agriculture, for example by subsidising insurance premiums (Mahul and Stutley 2010). Currently these policies are established, implemented and financed at the national level.1 For example, in Bulgaria, since 2010, the State has developed schemes to support the insurance of fruits, vegetables, vines and bee-keeping. Support consists of a subsidy on the insurance premium of 80%.

In the CAP post-2013, a “risk management toolkit” has been created as part of the Rural Development measures under Pillar 2. Under this scheme, national governments of the Member States are allowed to choose from a menu of instruments and receive co-financing from Brussels (EU 2013).2 One of the measures is the co-financing of insurance premium subsidies. Understanding the factors affecting farmers' purchases of agricultural insurance is essential for evaluating the soundness and profitability of insurance programmes and the associated public support (Goodwin and Smith 1995).

The Bulgarian farming sector comprises a large number of small, family-owned farms that have little access to credit, making a financial shock damaging and lasting. In such small farms, farmers first rely on risk management strategies on-farm to reduce revenues variability, rather than purchase insurance. Some risk management strategies (such as diversification) reduce risk within the farm’s operation, others (such as production contracting) transfer risk outside the farm (Harwood et al.

1999). But with the entry of Bulgaria into the European Union in 2007, the economic, financial and institutional framework of Bulgarian agriculture is rapidly evolving. The variability in input and output prices associated with free markets as well as the support received by farmers from the CAP both affect the financial viability of Bulgarian farms. Notwithstanding effective management of risks has an increased importance in this context, the current state of agricultural insurance uptake in Bulgaria is unknown. The latest available figures date from 2005 (Agrostatistic, Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry Annual report). According to the 2005 figures, about 250000 farms took out agricultural insurance annually, corresponding to 46.8% of the farms and less than 20% of arable land. The total insurance premium paid was 6.6 million Euros in 2005, whereas the sum of the compensations received by the Bulgarian farms amounted to 4.7 million Euros. Given the important changes in the Bulgarian agricultural sector since 2005 (especially the introduction of the Single Area Payment Scheme of the Common Agricultural Policy), updated information is necessary.

The Bulgarian case is particularly interesting to complement previous studies on the analysis of the determinants of insurance adoption as this country is currently shifting from a system where compensation comes from a State damage mitigation fund, inherited from the centrally planned regime, to private insurance. The decision to voluntarily purchase an insurance policy is certainly impacted by farmers' previous experience with compulsory insurance during times of the planning economy. The possibility of extrapolation of results from research on the determinants of insurance adoption in other countries may therefore be limited. Prior research on the determinants of insurance adoption refers mainly to the United States (Goodwin 1993; Smith and Baquet 1996b; Smith and Baquet 1996a; Smith and Goodwin 1996; Mishra and Goodwin 2003; Serra 2003; Velandia et al.

2009). The United States represent a peculiar example as agricultural insurance is now well-

1 They must, though, respect EU rules on state aid so as to avoid distortion of competition in the common market. For example, national subsidies granted to premiums paid in agricultural insurance schemes are limited to a maximum percentage of the costs of insurance premiums (Tangermann 2011).

2More precisely, under Article 37, Support under this measure shall cover: (a) financial contributions, to premiums for crop, animal and plant insurance against economic losses to farmers caused by adverse climatic events, and animal or plant diseases, pest infestation, or an environmental incident; (b) financial contributions to mutual funds to pay financial compensations to farmers, for economic losses caused by adverse climatic events or by the outbreak of an animal or plant disease or pest infestation or an environmental incident; (c) an income stabilisation tool, in the form of financial contributions to mutual funds, providing compensation to farmers for a severe drop in their income.

(5)

developed and insurance premium subsidies now represent the largest source of farm assistance (Zulauf and Orden 2012). Targeted research into the specificity of EU countries and the EU agricultural insurance market is required to inform policy makers. Among the few papers analyzing EU farmers' adoption of insurance schemes, Garrido and Zilberman (2008) analysed 52000 Spanish farmers’ insurance outcomes over 12 years, to explain their participation in insurance schemes.

Enjolras and Sentis (2011) analysed 3514 French farms from the European Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) database. Enjolras, Capitanio et al. (2012) compared the factors explaining farmers' adoption of insurance in France and Italy.

There is almost no evidence on the adoption of insurance by farmers from the new entrant countries in the European Union (EU-N12) although they represent 56% of the agricultural holdings in Europe (Eurostat FSS 2010) and nearly 20% of CAP expenditures (EC 2011). Information on the penetration rate of agricultural insurance in new EU countries was collected by the Joint Research Centre of the European Commission, after consultation with an expert and consultant in each Member State (Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al. 2009). According to this source, the penetration rate of agricultural insurance is 52% in Bulgaria and Hungary, 35% in Czech Republic and 12% in Romania. To our knowledge, the only available study with farm-level data is Sporri, Baráth et al. (2012), who used FADN data on 5398 Hungarian farms between 2001 and 2009 to assess the impact of insurance use on the economic performance of farms. In their sample, 40% of the farmers had adopted insurance.

The general goal of this study is to analyse Bulgarian farmers' agricultural insurance decisions, on the basis of data collected in a purpose-built survey carried out in Bulgaria in 2011. Different farmers confront different situations and structural characteristics, and their preferences toward risk and their risk-return trade-offs have a major effect on their decision to manage agricultural risk. More specifically, we examine what the determinants of insurance decisions are. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the data used and the justification for the selection of variables as suggested by prior studies. The econometric model is presented in section 3, while results are presented in section 4. Section 5 provides concluding remarks.

2. Data and variables

The European Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) was introduced in Bulgaria in 2003 during the pre-accession period. Since then, the sample size has increased to 2000 farms (2009) and it is being constantly enriched with new variables in order to reach the European Commission requirements. However, it does not yet collect any information regarding the use of agricultural insurance. Moreover, information from other public statistical sources as well as from insurance agencies is not available in Bulgaria, including for research purposes. The only information available dates from the 2005 Agrostatistic report by the Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry of Bulgaria. In this context, the only opportunity available to investigate agricultural insurance decisions was to use the interview method. This paper is based on data from a questionnaire-based survey, which was carried out through structured face-to-face interviews in 224 farms in Bulgaria in 2011. Data were collected on the farm characteristics and farmers' experiences and preferences with regards to risk management in general and insurance in particular.

The sample was selected through a non-probability sampling procedure, based on a proportional stratified sample rationale complemented with expert judgment. The sample includes farms of four types of specialisation: crop production (121 farms), livestock (20 farms), perennial (31 farms) and mixed production (52 farms). Between 33 and 46 farmers were interviewed in each of the six NUTS 2 regions.

(6)

In the following, we describe the factors identified in the literature as potential determinants of insurance adoption, as well as the variables used in the paper (name in parenthesis and italic).

1. The use of risk management tools

For those 224 interviewed farmers, we know whether they adopted insurance or not in 2011.

According to the survey results, in 2011, the percentage of farms which took out insurance was 26.5% (61 of the surveyed farmers took it out, 163 did not).3 We also have information on the number of risks covered. Among those who purchased insurance, 60% are insured for the five main risks, namely frost, rain, hail, storm and fire. After multi-risk insurance, the second most common product is hail insurance, purchased by 20% of the surveyed farmers. An obvious limitation of the database is that we have no information on the level of coverage (in terms of premium paid and surface concerned). Insurance use is relatively heterogeneous across farming systems: one third of the crop and livestock farmers were insured in 2011 but only 25% of the mixed farms and 3% of the perennial growers. Meanwhile in terms of regions 37% of the farms are insured in the North (and up to 61% in the North West), while only 3% in the South are insured.

Most farms use a variety of tools to mitigate and manage risk. Tools for risk management in agriculture can be either on-farm strategies (diversification of farm and farmer's activities, irrigation, etc.) (O’Donoghue et al. 2009; Bachev 2012; Foudi and Erdlenbruch 2012), either risk-sharing strategies like marketing contracts, production contracts, hedging on futures markets, or the participation in insurance (Mishra and El-Osta 2002; Velandia et al. 2009). The survey includes information on the use of some of these risk management tools: 58 of the farmers interviewed use irrigation, with on average 80% of their land irrigated. 123 farmers have signed contracts with processors, wholesalers or retailers. 139 farmers have more than one type of productions on the farm.

These non-insurance risk management tools can be seen as a substitute strategy to insurance. On the other hand, it can be argued that producers who adopt one kind of risk management instrument tend to be highly risk-averse or have more ability in farming in general, and are therefore also more likely to adopt other risk management tools (Velandia et al. 2009). Given the multiplicity of the risk management solutions and situations, there is no unambiguous conclusion on the relations between the different risk management instruments.

Our database offers the opportunity to take into account the possibility of simultaneous utilization of multiple risk management instruments (including insurance) and the potential correlations among these decisions. The econometric model used to account for these effects is described in section 3.

2. Potential determinants of insurance adoption

In theory, new tools for farming are adopted when the expected net benefits are positive, i.e. when the costs are lower than the expected returns from insurance. For insurance adoption, Just, Calvin et al. (1999) proposed to separate the risk aversion incentive (the gain in risk premium due to the reduced variance of income) from the expected revenue incentive (the difference between the

3 This figure seems rather low compared to the 2005 figures provided by the Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry (46.8%) and the 2009 JRC report (52%) (Bulgarian Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry 2005; Bielza Diaz-Caneja et al.

2009). One possible reason is the introduction of the Single Area Payment Scheme in 2007. While direct payments are not generally viewed as risk management programmes per se, by adding a fixed income stream to the farm’s total income stream, they reduce the coefficient of variation for the farm’s total income stream (Goodwin and Smith 1995). Therefore, farmers may view this payment as a substitute to private insurance and this could explain the reduction in insurance subscription between 2005 and 2011. Our database does not allow evaluating this effect. Differences in the sampling plan can also not be excluded.

(7)

premium paid and the expected value of indemnity payments, calculated on the basis of farmers' subjective probabilities). Despite the importance of these factors in the insurance theory, almost no empirical studies use insurance outcomes, such as individual loss ratios, indemnities or expected returns from insurance, to explain farmers' insurance decisions (Garrido and Zilberman 2008). Just, Calvin et al. (1999) rely on the comparison between stated yield percentiles and insurance premiums, but do not include indemnities received. Garrido and Zilberman (2008) use a dataset including a complete characterisation of each farm's insurance strategy, premiums paid, premium subsidies, and collected indemnities. They found that the variability of returns from insurance (variance and third moment of indemnity patterns, in amount and frequency) have far more positive influence than the expected benefits on the decision to purchase insurance. Unfortunately, our database does not include such variables in the case of Bulgaria and does not therefore permit the analysis of the impact of these factors. Therefore, we have to rely on other variables as proxies for the expected benefits from insurance. We classify these variables into four categories: farm structural characteristics, risk exposure of the farm, financial situation of the farm and "behavioural" drivers.

Farm structural characteristics

In the absence of data on the expected returns from insurance, variables capturing farm structural characteristics can be used as proxies to explain insurance adoption patterns. Indeed, the characteristics of the farm and production system impact the risk exposure and the expected losses in case of damage, as well as the capacity to cope with risk.

Farm size: Farmers operating larger acreages are more likely to have a larger asset base from which to draw resources, either to purchase insurance or to cope with the damages caused by natural hazards (Velandia et al. 2009). Larger operations also benefit from economies of scale and better managerial capacities that can affect risk attitudes (Sherrick et al. 2004). In light of these characteristics, the relationship between farm size and adoption of agricultural insurance appears ambiguous, and possibly not linear. Farm size is very heterogeneous in Bulgaria, reinforcing the need to control for this factor. The small farms (less than 2 ha of Utilized Agricultural Area (UAA)) represent 83.2% of the total number of farms but only manage 3.9% of the total UAA. In contrast, large farms with a UAA of over 100 ha represent only 1.43% of the number of farms but account for 78.17% of the total utilized agricultural land (MAF 2011). To avoid correlation between farm size in hectares and the number of hectares of rented land, we create categories for farm size: small farms are defined in the study as having less than 2 ha of UAA (small_D); medium size farms have between 2 and 20 ha (medium_D); large farms have more than 20 ha.4 The large farm category is treated as the indicator. This means that we observe the probability that small and medium farms use insurance compare to large farms.

Land ownership: A larger proportion of owned acres provides greater wealth, greater stability of land control and a larger asset base, therefore stronger risk-bearing capacities (Velandia et al. 2009).

Thus, a high ratio of owned acres to total acres is likely to be associated with non-use of insurance and greater reliance on self-insurance relative to financial insurance (Sherrick et al. 2004). Part- owners and tenants may be less aware of the land characteristics and thus may face higher production uncertainty, leading to more frequent adoption of insurance (Mishra and Goodwin 2003). Moreover, farmers who rent land are expected to buy more insurance because they are more leveraged and they may be subject to the insurance requirements of creditors (Gardner and Kramer 1996; Wu 1999).

Mishra and Goodwin (2003) confirmed these intuitions and found that part-owners and tenants are

4 Given the limited number of very large farms (>100ha) in the sample, we use a different definition of large farms compare to MAF (2011).

(8)

more likely to buy insurance compared to full owners. In Bulgaria about 80% of UAA is rented or leased (MAF 2011). In the model, we include the number of hectares of rented land to capture this effect (rentedland).

Specialisation: Variables accounting for farm specialization must be taken into account as they determine the risk exposure and the type of coverage needed. The adoption of insurance will also depend on whether insurance products adapted to the farm activities are available on the market.

Growers of perennial crops are, for example, more exposed to risk if the natural hazards provoke irreversible damage to trees and will therefore have long-run effects on their yields and income. In the econometric model, the specialization taken as the reference is mixed, i.e. we analyze the impact of being specialised in crop (spe_crop_D), livestock (spe_livestock_D) or perennial farming (spe_perennial_D) on the probability to use insurance, compared to being a farm with mixed activities.

Legal status: If the farm is operated by one farmer alone, the farmer may be more risk-averse and therefore willing to purchase insurance (Enjolras and Sentis 2011). However, cooperative and limited company farms may have greater managerial capacities, which is likely to explain their willingness to innovate and the adoption of modern risk management instruments such as insurance. The dual agricultural system in Bulgaria, with highly heterogeneous structure and performances between individual farms and corporate farms, further justifies controlling for the farm legal status. In 2010 98% of all agricultural holdings were owned by individuals, followed by those owned by commercial companies (1%), sole traders (0.6%), cooperatives (0.3%) and other holdings (0.1%) (MAF 2011). In the econometric model, we analyze the impact of being an individual farmer (individual_D) on the probability to use insurance, compared to having another legal status.

Location: Bulgaria features notable diversity in terms of agricultural systems and exposure to extreme climatic conditions. The barrier effect of the Balkan Mountains is felt throughout the country: Northern Bulgaria has a continental climate, i.e. it is cooler and receives more rain than the lowlands of Southern Bulgaria, which has a Mediterranean climate. The country is divided into six NUTS 2 regions (Figure 1).

The South-West region benefits from a generally Mediterranean climate. It is characterised by various soil and climatic conditions, and therefore a great variety of crops are produced there (cereals, vegetables, tobacco, vineyards, etc.). The South-West, which includes the capital Sofia, is the richest region, contributing to 45% of Bulgaria’s GDP with about a third of the population.

At the other end of the spectrum, the regions with the loWest GDP and GDP per capita are the North-West and North-central regions. The Danubian Plain in the North is a big agricultural region.

The North-West is the first agricultural region in terms of UAA and the North-central is in third place. Agricultural land is mainly occupied by arable crops (mainly sunflowers, wheat and maize).

Livestock production is also developed. In the North-East region, arable land occupies 95% of the UAA.

The South-East region is the second agricultural region in terms of UAA. Horticulture has developed thanks to favourable climatic conditions due to the influence of the Black sea, with a reduced number of frosts in winter and more days of sun. Grapes, vegetable, tobacco, wheat and livestock are also important productions of the region.

The South-central region is the largest producer of vegetables, grapes and tobacco in Bulgaria - 48%

of the total area of vegetables, 33% of the vineyards and 55% of the tobacco are grown in the South- central region. Favourable soil and climatic conditions of the region permit the cultivation of crops that are not grown in other areas such as peaNUTS, rice, rye, cotton, damask rose, lavender, mint and more. The South-central region is also an important cattle producer.

(9)

Location variables are important to capture unobservable effects due to local characteristics such as the profitability of agricultural production and the risk exposure. We use dummies corresponding to the six NUTS 2 regions of Bulgaria to take into account regional peculiarities (NorthCentral_D, NorthEast_D, SouthEast_D, SouthWest_D, SouthCentral_D). The region taken as reference is the North-West region, which is both the main agricultural region in terms of UAA and the poorest region in terms of GDP per inhabitant.

Risx exposure and perception

Climatic variables: The most high-risk farms in terms of weather exposure should be more likely to take out insurance. Usual proxies for climate risk exposure are meteorological data such as mean temperature, cumulated precipitation, hours of sun, days of frost, days of strong wind, and number of storm events (Blank and McDonald 1996; Van Asseldonk et al. 2002). The meteorological data used here are: the number of days of precipitation, taken as proxy for rainfall and drought risk (y0710_dayprecip), number of days of thunderstorm, used as proxy for hail risk (y0710_daythunderstorms), and number of days of snow, a proxy for frost risk (y0710_daysnow).

These data are available at NUTS3 level.

Risk perception: Farmers were asked the number of times they have been affected by a natural phenomenon in each of the previous four years (2007-2010). We use the average number of times the farm has declared itself affected by a natural phenomenon in a year (risk events_avg) as a proxy for risk perception. While we do not know whether farmers' declarations are accurate, the declaration of a higher number of natural phenomenons reflects higher perceived risk exposure. Producers with higher perceived risks may have more incentives to adopt risk management tools.

Access to information: We can also expect access to information on risk exposure to play a key role in determining perception of risk exposure (Just et al. 2003). Our database includes data on whether the farmer receives information regarding risk management, as well as the nature and total number of sources used (publications, electronic media, internet, information agencies, state administration, other). We use a dummy variable equals to one if the farmer declared having access to information on risk management (inforisk_D).

Financial dimension

Insurance adoption is ultimately a financial decision. In the absence of fully efficient financial markets, the financial situation of the farm can be an important driver of insurance adoption.

According to the literature, financial variables are expected to impact insurance decisions through two channels: their impact on the affordability of insurance and on risk aversion. Smith and Baquet (1996a) and Smith and Goodwin (1996) both found a farmer's net wealth significantly explains lower insurance adoption. However, in the presence of financial constraints, a positive relationship between income and insurance adoption can be expected (Spörri et al. 2012). Unfortunately, financial information on income is limited in the survey. We only know whether the farmer uses credit and whether he receives compensation after a natural catastrophe in the recent years.

Debt and liquidity constraints: Debt and liquidity constraints are also strongly expected to affect insurance through their impact on farmers' ability to face a sudden drop in yields and revenue. More liquidity constrained farmers are expected to insure more (Enjolras and Sentis 2011). Greater debt- to-asset ratios indicate greater financial risk and a stronger demand for more comprehensive insurance products (Blank and McDonald 1996; Van Asseldonk et al. 2002; Mishra and Goodwin 2003). We use a dummy variable indicating whether the farm has on-going credits, as an indicator of the debt constraint of the farm (credit_D).

(10)

Compensation after a natural event (not insurance indemnity payment): Disaster aid programmes have long been recognized to have an impact on crop insurance programmes. The history of compensation received after a disaster has both positive and negative impacts on insurance demand.

On the one hand, ad hoc disaster programmes can be viewed as free crop and livestock insurance by farmers, albeit with indemnities that are somewhat unpredictable (Smith and Glauber 2012). Ex-post compensation is in this case a disincentive to take out insurance. On the other hand, receiving compensation payments may reflect higher returns to insurance because historically yields have been more variable, therefore leading to a positive effect on insurance demand (Smith and Baquet 1996b).

The net impact will depend on farmers' preferences regarding the opportunity to receive an uncertain public support in case of disaster (decided ex-post) versus buying insurance to guarantee indemnity is received after damage. In Bulgaria, the state fund is used for compensation of small risks not covered by insurance and for support after catastrophic risks. The funds distributed each year are highly variable as they depend on the occurrence of natural hazards: 11 million Euros and 5225 beneficiaries in 2008 but only 0.6 million and 245 beneficiaries in 2011. In our database, the three farmers that have received State compensation after a natural disaster between 2007 and 2011 took out insurance in 2011. Therefore, the dummy variable indicating whether the farmer received ex-post compensation will be dropped from subsequent analysis to avoid a separation issue. Given the small number of farmers concerned, we do not think dropping this variable has an important effect on the model.

Characteristics of the farmer

Farmers' attitudes towards risk and uncertainty can explain deviation from insurance purchase even if the expected returns are positive. However, we often have to rely on proxies to capture the effects risk aversion. The age and the level of education of the farmer are likely to explain insurance behaviour as they can be used as a proxy for risk aversion (Goodwin 1993; Smith and Baquet 1996b;

Wu 1999). In general, it is hypothesized that older and less educated producers are more risk-averse, and therefore more likely to adopt risk management tools. However, previous studies have found mixed results in terms of the effect of age and education on risk management tool adoption (Mishra and El-Osta 2002). Smith and Baquet (1996b) and Mishra and Goodwin (2003) found that farmers' education level proved significant for the decision to purchase insurance, and for the level of coverage. Sherrick, Barry et al. (2004) found that younger and better educated farmers are more responsive to modern approaches of risk management like insurance. Assuming insurance is part of the toolbox of modern farming, this can be explained by the results of the innovation adoption literature. This literature suggests that early adopters are likely to be younger producers with the highest level of education. Overall, age (Age) and education have an ambiguous effect, depending on the relative weight of the two channels through which they can impact insurance adoption: risk aversion and willingness to innovate. To account for potential non-linear effect, education has been included in the model though two dummies corresponding to no or primary education only (education1_D) and secondary education (education2_D). The education level taken as reference is higher education. We have tried alternative specification including the squared value of age as well but it did not improve the performance of the model.

Descriptive statistics for these variables are presented in Table 1 both for the full sample and for the two groups of users and non-users of insurance.

3. Econometric model

This section describes the econometric approach to obtain estimates of the effect of various variables on insurance adoption by Bulgarian farmers.

(11)

Most previous studies on insurance adoption analyse factors influencing the adoption of insurance only, rather than considering the possibility of simultaneous adoption and the potential correlation between the adoption decisions. Our database offers the opportunity to examine the drivers of several decisions influencing the level of risk born by the farmer, while taking into account the possibility of simultaneous utilization of multiple risk management instruments. We focus on insurance and on- farm traditional risk management tools such as production contracting, irrigation and diversification of farm productions.

We follow the same approach as Velandia et al. (2009), who studied the factors affecting US farmers' simultaneous utilization of crop insurance, forward contracting and spreading sales (corn and maize farmers in Illinois, Iowa and Indiana). The empirical model chosen is the multivariate probit (MVP).

The MVP allows for the possible correlation in the different decisions. This specification is useful since we do not observe how the different risk management tools interact to affect the net return of the farmer, and these effects are therefore subsumed in the error terms. Moreover, unobservable individual heterogeneity (risk aversion, ability …) can influence at the same time two of the risk management decisions made by the respondent.

The model is specified as a system of four equations, with Y1 the decision to purchase insurance, Y2

the existence of marketing and/or production contracts, Y3 the use of irrigation and Y4 the existence of diversified farm activities (more than one).

Yij*

j Xij +

ε

ij, j=1,…,4 Yij =1 ifYij*

>0, and 0 otherwise

ε

ij ~ Nj [0,R], j=1,…,4

where Yij represents the decision to adopt a risk management instrument j by the farmer i. Xij is a vectorof observed variables of farmer i that affects the risk management decision j. We use the same set of explanatory variables for all equations (Xij= Xi).5 The error terms are distributed as multivariate normal, each with a mean of zero, and variance-covariance matrix R, with 1 on the main diagonal values and correlations ρjk= ρkj in off-diagonal values.

The system of equations is estimated using the mprobit program in NLOGIT 4.0. It uses Geweke- Hajivassilou-Keane (GHK) simulator for probabilities and a maximum simulated likelihood procedure. Since the procedure used involves simulation, one of the key choices the researcher must make is about the number of draws to consider. The maximum simulated likelihood estimator is asymptotically equivalent to the true maximum likelihood estimator as the ratio of the square root of the sample size to the number of draws tends to zero. For moderate to large sample sizes, setting the number of draws equal to an integer approximately equal to the square root of the sample size is considered appropriate (Cappellari and Jenkins 2003). Therefore, each model was run with 15 draws.

There were only small differences in the results under alternative choices of the number of draws.

For comparison, we also report the parameter estimates and marginal effects from an individual probit explaining the insurance decision. In the individual probit model, we use the robust option to

5 The choice of these variables has been made mostly on the basis of the review of the determinants of insurance adoption (section 2), since this is the main focus of the article. Therefore, we do not expect the predictive power of these variables to be very high for the production contracting, irrigation and diversification decisions.

(12)

obtain heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors. The marginal effects are calculated as the variation of the estimated probability to adopt insurance with respect to a marginal variation in the regressors (or a discrete change in case of binary variables). In the MVP, the marginal effects are calculated as the impact of an explanatory variable on the probability of adopting insurance (Y1 =1), conditional on all other risk management tools also being adopted (Y1= Y2= Y3 =1) (see Velandia et al. (2009) for more detailed information on the estimation of marginal effects). Standards errors for these marginal effects are obtained using the delta method and a bootstrapping procedure (Greene 2007). In both models, the marginal effects are computed at the means of the explanatory variables.

4. Results

We present the results of the different models and analyse the determinants of insurance adoption.

The parameter estimates from the multivariate probit and individual probits for estimating the factors affecting insurance adoption, as well as on-farm risk management tools are presented in table 3. The marginal effects are presented in table 4.

1. Correlation between the different risk management decisions

In order to get first insights on the relationship between insurance and other on-farm risk management decisions, we use Pearson Chi-squared tests (Table 2). The tests confirm the existence of strong correlation between the decision to purchase insurance and the existence of marketing and production contracts, and between insurance and the fact that the farm has diversified activities (significant at the 1% level). The correlation coefficient between insurance and irrigation is significant only at the 10% level. Overall, these tests suggest that it is important to take into account the possibility of simultaneous utilization of multiple risk management instruments when analysing the determinants of their adoption.

Moreover, in the multivariate probit model, we observe that the pairwise correlation coefficients related to the insurance equation (ρ12 ρ13 ρ14) are all positive and significantly different from zero (Table 3). These coefficients measure the correlation between the four risk management decisions, after the influence of the observed factors has been accounted for. This support our hypothesis that the error terms in the insurance and other risk management tools are correlated, and a multivariate probit approach is appropriate.

Moreover, the positive signs of the correlation coefficient (ρ12 ρ13 ρ14) suggest that a farmer adopting insurance is more likely to adopt another risk management tool and vice-versa. Concerning contracts (ρ12=0.352), we confirm the results of Mishra and Goodwin (2003) and Velandia et al. (2009), who highlighted the complementarities between insurance and contracts, given that insurance covers production risk while contracts cover price risk. For the two other instruments (irrigation and diversification), we do not confirm the previous results found in the literature.

We find that the correlation of the error terms of the insurance and irrigation equations is positive and significant (ρ13=0.551), while previous researches had suggested that irrigation is a possible substitute to insurance since it allows to stabilize yields (Dalton et al. 2004; Foudi and Erdlenbruch 2012). We can find two explanations to our result. First, since irrigation usually concerns high-value crops (fruit trees, vineyards…), geographic zones with large irrigated areas may receive more attention from private insurers and extension services and this contributes to higher take-off of insurance in these regions. Moreover, it is likely that in regions with sufficient rainfall irrigation is not used and farms are less exposed to drought risk, therefore reducing the need to get insured.

(13)

Moreover, we find a positive correlation (ρ14=0.714) between diversification of farm activities and insurance, while evidence in the literature is mixed. Previous researches have concluded that irrigation is a risk-reducing input and is a possible substitute to insurance since it allows to stabilize yields (Dalton et al. 2004; Foudi and Erdlenbruch 2012). Mishra and Goodwin (2003) found that farmers with production and/or marketing contracts are more likely to purchase crop and revenue insurance. Empirical evidence on the impact of the diversification of farm activities is mixed. Di Falco, Capitanio et al. (2011) found that farms that have diversified crops are more likely to adopt financial insurance, suggesting that crop diversification acts as a complement for financial insurance and not as a substitute. Enjolras, Capitanio et al. (2012) found that traditional hedging practices such as growing different crops have a positive effect on insurance in France (complement), whereas they have a negative impact on insurance adoption in Italy (substitute). O'Donoghue, Roberts et al. (2009) found that farm specialization, measured as the inverse of crop diversification, modestly increased with the diffusion of insurance in the US, suggesting a small substitution effect between insurance and crop diversification.

Irrigation and crop and animal diversification within an agricultural holding are production decisions not primarily driven by risk management motives. The characteristics of the different parcels (climate, soil…), the constraints on the quantities of each crop/animal that can be sell on the market…are unobservable characteristics likely to explain these decisions. Unfortunately, our results do not allow distinguishing whether the positive correlation observed is due to complementarities between the different instruments with regard to risk management, or other unobserved characteristics related to the farmer (risk aversion, ability), the production or the local context.

Nevertheless, since we observe that the error terms in the insurance and other risk management tools are correlated, in the next section, we analyse the results of the multivariate probit in order to analyse the factors driving insurance adoption.

2. The determinants of insurance adoption

The interpretation of the drivers of insurance adoption is made on the basis of the results of the MVP.

The signs and significant variables in the multivariate and individual probit approaches are largely similar. The reader can find the results for the individual probit in the tables. Moreover, as the main focus of the article is to explain insurance adoption, we do not describe the results of the other decisions. Indeed, since the explanatory variables have not been chosen to explain the other risk management decisions, the performance of the model to explain contracting, irrigation and diversification is low (Table 3: lower percentage of correct classification and very few significant variables in (2)(3)(4) compare to (1)).

The interpretations below refer to the marginal effects of the MVP (Table 4 (1)), defined as the effect of a marginal change in a variable on the probability of adopting insurance (Y1 =1), conditional on all other risk management tools also being adopted (Y1= Y2= Y3 =1), evaluated at the mean of the variable. We know, as in Velandia et al. (2009), that the marginal effects from the MVP ("conditional" marginal effect) tend to be lower than the marginal effects from the individual probits.

It suggests that the effect of an observed factor on the probability to adopt a risk management tool is reduced when another risk management tool is already being used.

We find that the main characteristics distinguishing farmers who purchase agricultural insurance from non-users are farm size and farm location. Small farms and medium farms (to a lower extent) are less likely to get insured compared to large farms. Regional effects (captured by the NUTS2 dummy) also explain an important part of the differences in insurance adoption. We observe that farmers in North-West Bulgaria (used as the reference category) are far more likely to adopt

(14)

insurance than those in any other region (for the South East and South Central regions, effects are not significant). The simplest explanation is that the North-West region is the main agricultural region in Bulgaria, and may therefore receive more attention from private insurers and extension services and this contributes to higher take-off of insurance in this region.

Most of the other variables are significant in the estimation of the marginal effects (Table 4) but not in the estimation of the parameters (Table 3). While there are no differences between arable crops, livestock and mixed farms, farms producing permanent crops are less likely to get insured than mixed farms. The legal status also has an importance since individual farms are less likely to purchase insurance. Farmers with more hectares of rented land are more often insured, which is consistent with the assumptions drawn in section 2.

We find a non-linear effect of education since there is no significant difference between farmers having received no or only primary education and those who have received higher education. The absence of significant differences between low and highly educated farmers may be due to the fact that very few farmers are in the first group in our sample. However, we find that farmers having received secondary education are less likely to get insured than more educated farmers. This is consistent with the hypothesis that better educated farmers are more responsive to modern approaches of risk management like insurance. Older farmers are more likely to get insured but the marginal effect is small.

While more liquidity constrained farmers are expected to insure more, we find a negative impact of having on-going credits on the probability to get insured. One possible explanation is that indebted farmers face financial constraints and cannot face the extra costs of insurance. However, the validity of this interpretation may be limited given that having on-going credit is not necessarily the best indicator for financial constraints.

Higher risk exposure (higher number of days of snow and thuderstorms) and higher perception of risk (higher number of natural phenomenon having impacted the farm declared) significantly increase the probability to get insurance. However, more days of precipitations in the NUTS3 region reduces the probability to get insured. This may be due to the fact that more rainfall reduces drought risk and therefore the need to get insured.

5. Conclusion

Through analysis of the results of a purpose-built survey conducted in 224 farms in Bulgaria, we have shown that the interest of Bulgarian farmers in insurance as a means to cope with natural hazards is currently low: only 27% of the interviewed farmers purchased insurance in 2011.

We find that the main characteristics distinguishing farmers who purchase agricultural insurance from non-users are farm size and farm location. In terms of practical recommendations, it suggests that a closer tailoring of insurance premiums to producer attributes, especially in serving the needs of small and medium farms could increase adoption. Policies should also aim to stimulate insurance companies to service the market segment of smaller farms (Sherrick et al. 2004). Moreover, the importance of regional effects underlines the importance of adapting insurance products to local needs, and make sure all farmers receive information on insurance (from public extension services or private insurers) even if they are not in the main agricultural region.

Beyond the analysis of the profile of insured farmers, the main contribution of the paper is to take into account the potential for simultaneous adoption and correlation among the adoption decisions of different risk management strategies, using a multivariate probit approach. We have replicated the

(15)

approach proposed by Velandia et al. (2009) for corn and soybean US farmers and applied it to Bulgaria agriculture. This approach is especially relevant in the Bulgarian context where farmers has for long used on farm risk-management strategies, even when insurance was compulsory during the socialist period. The article has focused on contracting, irrigation and diversification of farm productions as potential risk management strategies. We find, after controlling for farms and farmers' structural characteristics, that farmers with diversified activities, using irrigation or contracts are more likely to adopt insurance (and vice-versa). This result also suggests that many farms neither use insurance, nor other on-farm risk management strategies. Advisory services should further focus on those farms not managing risk and work on defining their optimal mix of risk management tools.

The dynamic pattern of the insurance market (how insurance use evolves over time) should also be analyzed further. The current survey only concerns decisions for 2011, as such it does not allow us to study the dynamics of insurance adoption. One question nevertheless enabled us to obtain some information on the intention to purchase insurance for 2012. For 2012, 97 out of the 224 farmers expressed their intention to take out insurance, of which 47 were insured in 2011. Among the 127 who indicated that they would not purchase insurance in 2012, 113 were not insured in 2011 either, but 14 were. Further research should examine what influences farmers' willingness to continue to take out insurance or not (Cabas et al. 2008). The development of the Bulgarian FADN panel dataset is a promising advance for such deeper analysis of agricultural decisions in new EU countries.

Inclusion of risk information in the FADN will facilitate comparative analysis with other Member States in the EU.

(16)

References

Blank, S. C. and J. McDonald (1996). Preferences for crop insurance when farmers are diversified.

Agribusiness 12(6): 583-592.

Cabas, J. H., A. J. Leiva and A. Weersink (2008). Modeling Exit and Entry of Farmers in a Crop Insurance Program. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 37(1): 92-105.

Cappellari, L. and S. P. Jenkins (2003). Multivariate probit regression using simulated maximum likelihood. The Stata Journal 3(3): 278-294.

Dalton, T., G. A. Porter and G. A. Winslow (2004). Risk management strategies in humid production regions: A comparison of supplemental irrigation and crop insurance. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 33: 220–232.

Di Falco, S., F. Capitanio and F. Adinolfi (2011). Natural Vs Financial Insurance in the Management of Weather Risk Exposure in the Italian Agriculture. 2011 International Congress, August 30-September 2, 2011, Zurich, Switzerland, European Association of Agricultural Economists.

Enjolras, G., F. Capitanio and F. Adinolfi (2012). The demand for crop insurance: Combined approaches for France and Italy. Agricultural Economics Review 13(1).

Enjolras, G. and P. Sentis (2011). Crop insurance policies and purchases in France. Agricultural Economics 42: 475–486.

EU (2013). Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on support for rural development by the European Agricultural Fund for Rural development (EAFRD) - Consolidated draft regulation. http://register.consilium.europa.eu/pdf/en/13/st13/st13349- re01.en13.pdf

Foudi, S. and K. Erdlenbruch (2012). The role of irrigation in farmer’s risk management strategies in France. European Review of Agricultural Economics 39(3): 439-457.

Gardner, B. L. and R. A. Kramer (1996). Experience with Crop Insurance Programs in the United States. Crop Insurance for Agricultural Development: Issues and Experience. P. Hazell, C.

Pomareda and A. Valdes. Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press.

Garnevska, E., J. Edwards and D. Vaughan (2006). Farm diversification opportunities in Bulgaria – the perceptions of farmers in the Plovdiv region – a preliminary analysis. Journal of International Farm Management 3(2): 1-14.

Garrido, A. and D. Zilberman (2008). Revisiting the demand of agricultural insurance: The case of Spain. Agricultural finance review 68(1): 43-66.

Goodwin, B. K. (1993). An empirical analysis of the demand for multiple peril crop insurance.

American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75: 425–434.

Goodwin, B. K. and V. H. Smith (1995). The economics of crop insurance and disaster aid.

Greene, W. H. (2007). NLOGIT version 4.0 Reference guide. Plainview, N.Y.

(17)

Just, D. R., S. Wolf and D. Zilberman (2003). Principles of risk management service relations in agriculture. Agricultural Systems 75(2-3): 199-213.

Just, R. E., L. Calvin and J. Quiggin (1999). Adverse Selection in Crop Insurance: Actuarial and Asymmetric Information Incentives. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 81(4): 834- 849.

Mishra, A. K. and H. S. El-Osta (2002). Managing risk in agriculture through hedging and crop insurance: what does a national survey reveal? Agricultural Finance Review 62(2): 135 - 148.

Mishra, A. K. and B. K. Goodwin (2003). Adoption of crop versus revenue insurance: A farm-level analysis. Agricultural Finance Review 63(2): 143-155.

O’Donoghue, E. J., M. J. Roberts and N. Key (2009). Did the Federal Crop Insurance Reform Act Alter Farm Enterprise Diversification? Journal of Agricultural Economics 60(1): 80-104.

Serra, T., Goodwin, B.G. and Featherstone, A.M. (2003). Modeling changes in the U.S. demand for crop insurance during the 1990s. Agricultural finance review Fall(109-125).

Sherrick, B. J., P. J. Barry, P. N. Ellinger and G. Schnitkey (2004). Factors influencing farmers’

crop insurance decisions. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86(1): 103– 114.

Smith, V. H. and A. E. Baquet (1996a). Demand for Multiple Peril Crop Insurance: Evidence from Montana Wheat Farms. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78(1).

Smith, V. H. and A. E. Baquet (1996b). The demand for multiple peril crop insurance: Evidence from Montana wheat farms. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78(189-201).

Smith, V. H. and J. W. Glauber (2012). Agricultural Insurance in Developed Countries: Where Have We Been and Where Are We Going? Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy 34(3): 363- 390.

Smith, V. H. and B. K. Goodwin (1996). Crop insurance, moral hazard, and agricultural chemical use. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78: 428– 438.

Spörri, M., L. Baráth and I. Fertö (2012). The Impact of Crop Insurance on the Economic Performance of Hungarian Cropping Farms. 123rd EAAE Seminar, Dublin, February 23-24.

Van Asseldonk, M., M. Meuwissen and R. Huirne (2002). Belief in disaster relief and the demand for a public-private insurance program. Review of agricultural economics 24(1): 196-207.

Velandia, M., R. M. Rejesus, T. O. Knight and B. J. Sherrick (2009). Factors Affecting Farmers’

Utilization of Agricultural Risk Management Tools: The Case of Crop Insurance, Forward Contracting, and Spreading Sales. Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 41(1):

107-123.

Wu, J. (1999). Crop insurance, acreage decisions, and nonpoint-source pollution. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 81: 305–320.

(18)

Figure 1: Bulgaria

(19)

Table 1: Respondent characteristics

Full sample Insured Non insured

Variable name description mean sd mean sd mean sd

Risk management

Insurance =1 if the farmer was insured in

2011 0.27 0.45

Irrigation =1 if the irrigated area is

positive 0.26 0.44 0.29 0.45 0.18 0.39 *

Diversification =1 if the number of activities

on the farm is higher than one 0.62 0.49 0.54 0.50 0.84 0.37 ***

Contract =1 if the farmer has signed at least one contract with a processor, a wholesaler or a

retailer 0.55 0.50 0.47 0.50 0.75 0.43 ***

Farm structure

Individual_D =1 if the legal status of the farm

is an individual farm 0.90 0.30 0.96 0.19 0.72 0.45 ***

spe_crop_D =1 if the main source of income

of the farm is arable crops 0.54 0.50 0.49 0.50 0.67 0.47 **

spe_livestock_D =1 if the main source of income

of the farm is livestock farming 0.09 0.29 0.09 0.28 0.10 0.30 spe_perennial_D =1 if the main source of income

of the farm is perennial crops 0.14 0.35 0.18 0.39 0.02 0.13 ***

spe_mixed_D =1 if the income of the farm comes from both livestock and

arable crops 0.23 0.42 0.24 0.43 0.21 0.41

Small_D =1 if the farm UAA is < 2ha

0.36 0.48 0.45 0.50 0.11 0.32 ***

Medium_D =1 if the farm UAA is ≥ 2ha

and <20ha 0.38 0.49 0.42 0.50 0.26 0.44 **

Large_D =1 if the farm UAA is ≥ 20ha

0.26 0.44 0.13 0.34 0.62 0.49 ***

RentedLand Number of hectares of the

UAA rented 123.21 386.72 22.99 164.34 391.00 618.64 ***

Farm location

NorthWest_D =1 if the farm is located in the

North West of Bulgaria 0.21 0.40 0.11 0.31 0.46 0.50 ***

NorthCentral_D =1 if the farm is located in

North Central of Bulgaria 0.19 0.39 0.21 0.41 0.15 0.36

NorthEast_D =1 if the farm is located in the

North East of Bulgaria 0.15 0.36 0.13 0.34 0.20 0.40

SouthEast_D =1 if the farm is located in the

South East of Bulgaria 0.16 0.37 0.16 0.37 0.16 0.37

SouthWest_D =1 if the farm is located in the

South West of Bulgaria 0.14 0.35 0.19 0.39 0.02 0.13 ***

SouthCentral_D =1 if the farm is located in

South Central Bulgaria 0.15 0.36 0.20 0.40 0.02 0.13 ***

Climate and risk perception

Day_snow Number of days of snow per

year (average 2007-2010) 33.30 18.36 32.32 19.60 35.93 14.34 Day_precip Number of days of

precipitations per year (average

2007-2010) 105.69 24.94 108.21 26.74 98.93 17.86

Day_storm Number of days with

thunderstorm per year (average

2007-2010) 21.80 8.81 22.92 9.24 18.80 6.76

Riskevents_avg Number of risky events per year as declared by the farmer

(average 2007-2010) 0.54 0.86 0.46 0.75 0.75 1.08

**

Inforisk_D =1 if the farmer receives information regarding risk

management 0.42 0.50 0.41 0.49 0.46 0.50

(20)

Farmer characteristics

Education1_D =1 if the farmer has received no

or only primary education 0.06 0.23 0.06 0.23 0.07 0.25

Education2_D =1 if the farmer has received

secondary education 0.63 0.49 0.65 0.48 0.56 0.50

Education3_D =1 if the farmer has received

tertiary education 0.32 0.47 0.29 0.46 0.38 0.49

Age Age at the date of the interview 41.88 13.38 40.04 12.45 46.79 14.60 ***

Financial characteristics

Credit_D =1 if the farmer has on-going

credits 0.24 0.43 0.19 0.39 0.38 0.49 ***

N 224 61 163

The last column presents the results of non-parametric tests (Mann Witney rank sum test for continuous variables or Chi2 for binary variables) comparing two groups: the users and the non-users of insurance (*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1)

Table 2: Number of farmers using the different risk management tools

Insured Non-insured

Use of irrigation 11

(18%)

47 (28.8%)

Pearson chi-sq=2.69 Pr = 0.10 Diversified farm activities (more than 1) 51

(83.6%)

88 (54%)

Pearson chi-sq=16.54 Pr = 0.00

Existence of contracts 46 (75.4%) 77 (47.2%)

Pearson chi-sq=14.23 Pr = 0.00

Total 61 Total 163

Références

Documents relatifs

L’accès à ce site Web et l’utilisation de son contenu sont assujettis aux conditions présentées dans le site LISEZ CES CONDITIONS ATTENTIVEMENT AVANT D’UTILISER CE SITE WEB.

Hôpital Européen Georges Pompidou, APHP, Paris, France; 2 INSERM, UMRS 1138, CRC, Équipe 22, Paris, France; 3 Université Paris Descartes, Sorbonne Paris Cité, Paris, France; 4

Tables 1 and 2 show some descriptive statistics of important characteristics by income group: i) the percentage of workers with temporary contracts are higher among low income

Once taken into account the variables which explain their innovative nature, several internal characteristics of the firms produce a positive impact on their choice to

Impact of the CAP Single Farm / Area Payments on farmers’ decisions: Preliminary results of a farm-level survey 31 sector, of changing their land area, and of changing the.. type

weighted household post- government income, individual net income, corrected monthly household income, and household net income from wages) on subjective health were compared in

From the second stage of the process, that of possession, the importance of cognitive factors such as education (literacy and the number of years of schooling) as well as income

Figure 4 Income share relative to population share by family size: 1 member solid black line with circle; 2 members solid grey line with circle; 3 members dashed black line with