• Aucun résultat trouvé

Principle of Minimum Differentiation Revisited

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "Principle of Minimum Differentiation Revisited"

Copied!
28
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

. . . . . .

.

. . . .

. . Principle of Minimum Differentiation Revisited

N. Hanaki 1 , E. Tanimura 2 , N. Vriend 3

1

Aix Marseille University (Aix Marseille School of Economics), GREQAM, IUF

2

CES, Universit ´e Paris 1

3

Queen Mary University of London

Saint Etienne, November 2016

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(2)

What is the question we try to answer?

Does a noisy myopic best reply restore the “principle of minimum

differentiation” in a simple linear location model (a la Hotelling

1929, EJ) ?

(3)

. . . . . .

Background: “Principle of minimum differentiation” in a linear location model

Consumers with a unit demand located over an interval, e.g, [0, 1].

n agents simultaneously choose a location in the interval.

Agents charge the same price.

Consumers buy from the closest agent.

n = 2, under NE, both agents locate at the center Applications:

I

political science : parties locating in an ”ideological space”

I

product differentiation by competing firms

I

(spatial location of competing firms)

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(4)

Background 2: Pure strategy NE when n > 2?

n = 3. Does not exist.

n > 3. Eaton and Lipsey (1975, RES) n = 4

1.0

0 1/4 0.5 3/4

0 1/6 1/2 5/6 1.0

2"agents 2"agents

n = 5

1.0

0 1/4 0.5 3/4

1/8 3/8 5/8 7/8

0 1.0

0 1/6 1/2 5/6 1.0

2"agents 1"agent 2"agents

n = 6 (multiple eq.)

1.0

0 1/4 0.5 3/4

0 1/6 1/2 5/6 1.0

2"agents 2"agents 2"agents 1.0

0 1/4 0.5 3/4

0 1/6 1/2 5/6 1.0

2"agents 1"agent 1"agent 2"agents

(5)

. . . . . .

Background 3: Properties of the equilibrium

It results from the analysis of Eaton and Lipsey (1975) that The extremal agents are at most 1/n from the edges of the interval.

The interior agents are spread out

There is multiplicity: for n > 5 there is an infinite number of equilibria

For n > 3, all equilibria are weak.

We note for later on that in a model with discrete locations, and the possibility of locating in the same position, some details of the

equilibrium analysis are slightly modified but essentially results remain the same.

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(6)

Background 3: Doubly symmetric mixed strategy NE when n > 2?

n = 3. Shaked (1983, JIndE).

n > 3. Ewerhart (2014, mimeo, UZurich)

Prob. density of mixed strategy in NE

the unique solution of the boundary value problem isF(z) =e 2z!12, with ea= 14.

In cases where n " 4, the differential equation (9) becomes more in- volved, so that an explicit solution is not readily available. In particular, there is no obvious substitution that would simplify the equation.9 We also checked that, in general, there is no distribution with a quadratic den- sity function that solves (9). However, the characterization paves the way to a numerical computation of the equilibrium distribution.10

1/4 3/4

(7)

. . . . . .

Background 4: Experimental evidences Part 1

Collins and Shestyuk (2000, Econ Inq):

I

n=3. 35 (un-known) repetitions with re-matching. Cumulative payoff.

Relative frequency of chosen locations

9

were within the predicted range of [25,75] (see table 1). On the individual level, 40 out of 51 subjects chose locations within the central quartiles of the market 25 times or more out of 35 trials. Also, in accordance with the theoretical prediction, the mean and the median locations for all four sessions were very close to 50. The distribution of location choices was only slightly asymmetric, as indicated by a skewness very close to zero.7

Figure 2 Distribution of Locations - Pooled Data

0.00 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.10 0.12

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100 Location

Frequency

Further consideration of figure 2 indicates, however, that in contrast to the theoretical prediction, the distribution of locations in the range [25,75] was not uniform. The distribution appears to be bimodal with one peak at around 40 and the other near 70. (See also the distributions from each session in figure 2A in Appendix 2.) At least to a certain degree, the subjects avoided locations near the center of the market, as well as the edges.

Statistical tests of the similarity between the data and Shaked’s Nash equilibrium prediction motivate the following result.

7 The skewness for the pooled data was –0.012 with a standard error of 0.058. The null hypothesis that the skewness is zero cannot be rejected at the 5% level with a test statistic of –0.17 compared to the critical value of – 1.96. Similarly, the null hypothesis cannot be rejected for each session (the standard errors of skewness by session are 0.119, 0.137, 0.097 and 0.119).

(Source: Collins and Shestyuk 2000, Fig 2. T=1785 (35 × 51))

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(8)

Background 5: Experimental evidences Part 2

Huck et al (2002, Econ Inq):

I

n=4. 50 repetitions. Cumulative payoff (24 subjects)

I

The relative frequency of chosen locations is not well explained by pure nor mixed Nash equilibrium.

I

Over time, subjects play central locations more frequently.

I

Neither pure strategy NE nor doubly symmetric mixed strategy NE does good job of explaining the experimental results.

I

A noisy myopic best response seems to explain the observed

behavior quite well (Huck et al 2002).

(9)

. . . . . .

To summarize

Observations:

High multiplicity of equilibria gives low predictive value.

All equilibria are weak.

In experiments, test subjects do not easily find (one of the) Nash equilibria but instead tend to pick locations in the center.

Our question: Does a noisy myopic best reply restore the “principle of minimum differentiation” in a simple linear location model?

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(10)

To summarize

Observations:

High multiplicity of equilibria gives low predictive value.

All equilibria are weak.

In experiments, test subjects do not easily find (one of the) Nash equilibria but instead tend to pick locations in the center.

Our question:

Does a noisy myopic best reply restore the “principle of

minimum differentiation” in a simple linear location model?

(11)

. . . . . .

To summarize

Observations:

High multiplicity of equilibria gives low predictive value.

All equilibria are weak.

In experiments, test subjects do not easily find (one of the) Nash equilibria but instead tend to pick locations in the center.

Our question: Does a noisy myopic best reply restore the “principle of minimum differentiation” in a simple linear location model?

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(12)

Approach

Numerical simulations : allows us to verify the robustness of the results when some aspects of the model vary : sequential moves, inertia, players with preferences for close locations

Analytical proof for n = 3, letting the level of random noise go to zero.

Analytical proof for n = 4, letting random noise go to zero and the number of locations grow to infinity.

Some results and comments about the general case n > 4.

(13)

. . . . . .

Numerical simulations: set up

n agents, initially randomly located.

Discretize the interval into N (uneven) locations.

All the agents move simultaneously according to a noisy myopic best reply.

I

Assume others stay in the same location.

I

With prob. 1 ε pick the location that maximizes the payoff.

Randomize in case of a tie.

I

With prob ε = 0.001 choose a location uniformly randomly from all the possible locations.

Drop the result from the first 10,000,000 steps.

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(14)

Results: Time series n ∈ { 3, 4, 5, 6 } , N = 3001

n = 3 n = 4

0 200 400 600 800 1000t

1450 1500 1550 1600 Loc

0 200 400 600 800 1000t

1450 1500 1550 1600 Loc

n = 5 n = 6

1450 1500 1550 1600 Loc

1450 1500 1550 1600 Loc

(15)

. . . . . .

Results: Time series n ∈ { 7.8 } , N = 3001

200 locations around the center

n = 7 n = 8

0 200 400 600 800 1000t

1450 1500 1550 1600 Loc

0 200 400 600 800 1000t

1450 1500 1550 1600 Loc

1000 locations around the center

n = 7 n = 8

0 200 400 600 800 1000t

1200 1400 1600 1800 2000 Loc

0 200 400 600 800 1000t

1200 1400 1600 1800 2000 Loc

1000 steps (after 10,000,000 initial steps).

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(16)

Results: Distribution of frequencies of realization with mean distance of agents from the center

Mean distance less than 15 locations from the center.

N=3001 N=30001 N=300001

3

3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3

4 4

4 4

4

4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4

5 5

5 5

5 5

5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6

7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7

8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14Dist

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 CDF

3

3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3

4 4

4 4

4

4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4

5 5

5 5

5 5

5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6

7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7

8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14Dist

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 CDF

3

3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3

4 4

4 4

4

4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4

5 5

5 5

5 5

5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5

6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6

7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7

8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8 8

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14Dist

0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 CDF

Out of of 100,000,000 steps (after dropping initial 10,000,000 steps).

(17)

. . . . . .

Results: Mean distance of agents from the center

Mean distance under which the simulation spend 99% of the 100,000,000 steps (after 10,000,000 initial steps).

n=3 n=4 n=5 n=6 n=7 n=8

N = 3001 2.0 15.0 65.9 139.9 247.4 409.3

(0.0) (0.0) (0.35) (0.25) (0.82) (1.44)

NE 540 (90%) 750 850 666.67 803.57 750

N = 30001 2.0 15.0 67.2 152.0 291.5 481.9

(0.0) (0.0) (0.38) (0.45) (1.38) (2.37)

NE 5393 (90%) 7500 8500 6667 8035.7 7500

N = 300001 2.0 15.0 67.9 154.0 302.0 525.6

(0.0) (0.0) (0.31) (0.45) (1.40) (3.76) NE 53918 (90%) 75000 85000 66667 80357 75000 Based on 30 simulations.

Note the difference in the scaling property between the NEs and model simulation

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(18)

Summary of what is observed in the simulations

When n = 3 agents spend most of their time around the center.

As n increase, agents spend more time away from the center.

But the mean distance (compared to the total number of locations)

decreases very quickly.

(19)

. . . . . .

Asymptotic analysis: the model

The model is essentially the same as in the simulations:

N = 2M + 1 locations.

Agents move simultaneously according to a noisy myopic best reply, assuming others stay in their previous location.

With prob. 1 ε pick a best reply. If it is not unique, each best reply is chosen according to a uniform probability.

With prob ε choose a location uniformly at random among all the possible locations.

The agents’ locations evolve according to an ergodic Markov chain whose long run behavior is described by an invariant measure µ ε,N

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(20)

Asymptotic analysis: cases

It is standard to analyze the states on which the system concentrates as the noise becomes vanishingly small, i.e. the support of lim ε 0 µ ε . These states belong to the long run

stochastically stable set (henceforth LRSS). This can be used as a form of equilibrium selection (which equilibria can be learned by boundedly rational players) e.g. Kandori et al (1993), Ellison (2000)

Only states that belong to a recurrent class in the Markov chain without noise can belong to the long run stochastically stable set.

Being weak, the Nash equilibria are not recurrent classes.

In the hotelling model with n > 2, there are cycles that are

recurrent classes : Let C k be the union of two states:

(21)

. . . . . .

Asymptotic analysis: case n=3

. Proposition .

.

. . . .

.

.

When n = 3, the long run stochastically stable set consists only of states whose distance to the center is at most 3.

We apply a result by Ellison (2000) characterizing LRSS based on the

”radius” and ”coradius” of a recurrent class.

Coradius of S : number of mutations required to reach S from outside the basin of attraction of S.

Radius of S: mutations required to leave basin of attraction of S.

. Theorem .

.

. . . .

.

.

In a model of evolution with noise, letbe a union of limit states. If R(Ω) > CR(Ω) the long run stochastically stable set is contained in(Ellison, 2000, RES)

Agents are close to the center in a strong sense: For any N, agents concentrate at locations at most 3 steps from center as noise vanishes.

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(22)

Asymptotic analysis: case n=4

As before the Nash equilibria are not recurrent classes (nor in fact included in a recurrent class). (also true for for n > 4)

The cycles (C k ) are recurrent classes. (also true for for n > 4)

It does not appear to be true (although we have no proof of the

contrary) that lim ε 0 µ ε concentrates only on the cycles close to

the center (in the sense of putting zero weight on distant locations)

However we can show that when the number of locations is large

agents spend most of their time close to the center in a weaker

sense: We consider lim N →∞ µ N,ε(N) , imposing a condition on the

speed that ε(N) goes to zero. The limit invariant measure is

(23)

. . . . . .

The case n = 4

. Theorem .

.

. . . .

.

.

In the Hotelling model with N locations, let I N = [M l N , M + l N be an interval centered at M, of length 2l N . Let S N be a subset of locations such that ω S N ⇐⇒ ω [M 3, M + 3] ∪

l AC

N

/2 I N . Let B N be any set of states B N I c such that card(B N ) card(S N ). Suppose that the Condition ?? below is verified, then lim N →∞ µ

N

(B

N

)

µ

N

(S

N

) = 0.

. Condition .

.

. . . .

.

.

There exist constants α ]0, 1 7 [, β M < and N 0 such that for every N N 0 , l N = N α and the level of random noise ε N verifies ε N = N β , where β [1, β M ].

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(24)

Outline of Proof

We use the fact that the invariant distribution of a Markov chain verifies:

µ(S) = µ(b)E[V (S, b, b)], where V (S, b, b) is a random variable that counts the number of times that the process reaches an element in S before it reaches b, starting from state b. To bound the expectation

we compute a lower bound on the probability of returning to S starting from S (main part of proof). This part can be generalized to n > 4.

a lower bound on the probability of reaching S from a state

outside of S (consists in checking a number of cases). Difficult (or at least tedious) to check for n > 4

Outline of ideas for obtaining the first bound: With high probability

(25)

. . . . . .

Outline of Proof - cntd

. .

1

. either best reply brings agents closer to the center in some steps (”contraction”)

. .

2

. IF a state is such that with positive probability best reply moves (at most one step) farther from the center, THEN, also positive

probability that all agents en up on the same side (triggering a return to the center)

. .

3

. We can also reach an absorbing class: we need to analyze what happens when we exit the absorbing class. In fact this is similar to the case 2.

Moving away from the center requires passing through states of type 2 a large number of times. The probability of doing so without ever having all agents end up on the same side becomes very small.

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(26)

Outline of Proof - cntd

. .

1

. either best reply brings agents closer to the center in some steps (”contraction”)

. .

2

. IF a state is such that with positive probability best reply moves (at most one step) farther from the center, THEN, also positive

probability that all agents en up on the same side (triggering a return to the center)

. .

3

. We can also reach an absorbing class: we need to analyze what happens when we exit the absorbing class. In fact this is similar to the case 2.

Moving away from the center requires passing through states of type 2

(27)

. . . . . .

Concluding remarks

Research question: Does a noisy myopic best reply restore the

“principle of minimum differentiation” in a simple linear location model?

Method: simulation and analytical proof Results:

I

The weak Nash equilibria do not survive selection by long run stochastic stability

I

Instead the invariant measure focuses on some other recurrent classes

I

for n = 3, these classes contain only states close to the center.

I

For n = 4 the measure concentrates on central states in a weaker sense as the number of locations grows.

I

For n > 4: we conjecture behavior similar to n = 4.

Thus this work suggests that in some sense the “Principle of minimum differentiation” is restored for n > 2 agents under a noisy myopic best reply. Simulations show that this results seems robust to varying details of the model.

Hanaki,Tanimura,Vriend Adaptive agents in Hotelling’s model

(28)

THANK YOU VERY MUCH

Références

Documents relatifs

Application of Steenbeck’s principle to the arc channel model amounts to finding a state with a minimum electric field among states with different channel radii and with the same

The quantum Lefschetz formula explains how virtual fundamental classes (or structure sheaves) of moduli stacks of stable maps behave when passing from an ambient target scheme to

De même, 50 % des hommes étran- gers se disent exposés à des fumées ou des poussières dans leur travail, contre 41 % des immigrés français et 44 % des non-immigrés : mais «

Our second result establishes that any process of economic evolution cov- ered by our assumptions selects a unique stochastically stable state where both …rms di¤erentiate minimally

In an essential and quite general setup, based on networks, we identify Schnakenberg’s observables as the constraints that prevent a system from relaxing to equilibrium, showing

Index Terms— Watershed, minimum spanning forest, mini- mum spanning tree, graph, mathematical morphology, image segmentation..

The main result of this section (Th. 10) states that a graph cut is induced by a minimum spanning forest relative to the minima of a map if and only if it is a water- shed of this

As the wall friction coefficient, confinement pressure has a strong effect on velocity pro- files: for negligible wall friction, increasing the normal force widens the top