• Aucun résultat trouvé

Wealth Distribution, Entrepreneurship and Intertemporal Trade

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "Wealth Distribution, Entrepreneurship and Intertemporal Trade"

Copied!
30
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

Montréal

Série Scientifique

Scientific Series

2001s-36

Wealth Distribution,

Entrepreneurship and

Intertemporal Trade

Sanjay Banerji, Ngo Van Long

(2)

CIRANO

Le CIRANO est un organisme sans but lucratif constitué en vertu de la Loi des compagnies du Québec. Le

financement de son infrastructure et de ses activités de recherche provient des cotisations de ses

organisations-membres, d’une subvention d’infrastructure du ministère de la Recherche, de la Science et de la Technologie, de

même que des subventions et mandats obtenus par ses équipes de recherche.

CIRANO is a private non-profit organization incorporated under the Québec Companies Act. Its infrastructure and

research activities are funded through fees paid by member organizations, an infrastructure grant from the

Ministère de la Recherche, de la Science et de la Technologie, and grants and research mandates obtained by its

research teams.

Les organisations-partenaires / The Partner Organizations

•École des Hautes Études Commerciales

•École Polytechnique

•Université Concordia

•Université de Montréal

•Université du Québec à Montréal

•Université Laval

•Université McGill

•MEQ

•MRST

•Alcan inc.

•AXA Canada

•Banque du Canada

•Banque Laurentienne du Canada

•Banque Nationale du Canada

•Banque Royale du Canada

•Bell Québec

•Bombardier

•Bourse de Montréal

•Développement des ressources humaines Canada (DRHC)

•Fédération des caisses populaires Desjardins de Montréal et de l’Ouest-du-Québec

•Hydro-Québec

•Imasco

•Industrie Canada

•Pratt & Whitney Canada Inc.

•Raymond Chabot Grant Thornton

•Ville de Montréal

© 2001 Sanjay Banerji et Ngo Van Long. Tous droits réservés. All rights reserved.

Reproduction partielle permise avec citation du document source, incluant la notice ©.

Short sections may be quoted without explicit permission, if full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.

Ce document est publié dans l’intention de rendre accessibles les résultats préliminaires

de la recherche effectuée au CIRANO, afin de susciter des échanges et des suggestions.

Les idées et les opinions émises sont sous l’unique responsabilité des auteurs, et ne

représentent pas nécessairement les positions du CIRANO ou de ses partenaires.

This paper presents preliminary research carried out at CIRANO and aims at

encouraging discussion and comment. The observations and viewpoints expressed are the

sole responsibility of the authors. They do not necessarily represent positions of CIRANO

or its partners.

(3)

Wealth Distribution, Entrepreneurship

and Intertemporal Trade

*

Sanjay Banerji

, Ngo Van Long

Résumé / Abstract

On étudie les échanges intertemporels entre deux pays ayant des

distributions de richesses différentes. On montre que, à cause du risque moral et

de l'imperfection du marché de capital, les gens très riches ou très pauvres

choississent de ne pas devenir entrepreneurs. À un taux d'intérêt donné, le pays

dont la distribution de richesse est moins égalitaire a une offre d'entrepreneurs

plus élevée, ce qui lui donne, en équilibre d'autarcie, un taux d'intérêt plus élevé.

Par conséquent, quand le commerce international est permis entre deux pays, celui

dont la distribution de richesse est moins égalitaire deviendra le pays créditeur.

Les politiques redistributives peuvent donc influencer le profil du commerce

intertemporel. Par exemple, si le gouvernement d'un pays adopte une politique

d'aide aux entreprises qui font faillite, l'offre d'entrepreneurs de ce pays

augmentera, ce qui, à son tour, haussera le taux d'intérê}t en équilibre d'autarcie.

Un pays créditeur deviendra un pays endetté quand une telle polique est

introduite.

This paper examines the pattern of intertemporal trade between countries

with different distribution of wealth. We also examine the consequences of

redistribution policies in this framework. The driving force of our model are risk

aversion, capital market imperfections, and costs associated with default. We

show that under capital market imperfections due to moral hazard, the very rich

and the very poor do not undertake any risk and become passive lenders. Only

individuals whose wealth lies within a medium range choose to become

entrepreneurs. At any given rate of interest, a country with with a wealth

distribution that is relatively less skewed to the left will have a greater supply of

entrepreneurs, leading to a higher equilibrium interest rate under autarky. Hence,

when the countries are opened to trade, those economies with highly skewed

distribution (to the left) will become net lenders. Redistributive policies therefore

will have impact on intertemporal trade. For example, if a government adopts a

bail-out policy (a redistribution from successful enterpreneurs to unsuccessful

ones) will increase the supply of enterpreneurs, driving up the autarkic interest

*

Corresponding Author: Ngo Van Long, CIRANO, 2020 University Street, 25

th

floor, Montréal, Qc, Canada

H3A 2A5

Tel.: (514) 985-4020

Fax: (514) 985-4039

email: longn@cirano.qc.ca

We are grateful to Abhijit Banerji, Kwan Choi, Christ Jacobs, Jérôme Detemple, Henry Wan, Jr., and participants at

the Seatle workshop and Queen's University seminar for many heplful comments.

(4)

rate. Consequently, a country which would be a lender if there were no bail-out

policy is a net borrower under the bail-out policy.

Mots Clés :

Échange intertemporel, distributions des richesses, risque moral, prudence,

marché de capital imparfait, entrepreneurship

Keywords:

Intertemporal trade, wealth distribution, moral hazard, prudence, imperfect capital

market, entrepreneurship

(5)

This paper examines the pattern of intertemporal trade between countries

with di erent distributions of wealth. We alsoexamine the consequences of

redistributionpoliciesinthis framework. The drivingforcesofourmodelare

riskaversion,capitalmarketimperfections,andcostsassociatedwithdefault.

We show that under capital market imperfections due to moral hazard, the

very rich and the very poor do not undertake any risk and become passive

lenders. Onlyindividualswhosewealthlieswithinamediumrangechooseto

become entrepreneurs. At any given rate of interest, a country with with a

wealthdistributionthatisrelativelylessskewed totheleftwillhaveagreater

supply of entrepreneurs, leading to a higher equilibrium interest rate under

autarky. Hence, when the countries are opened to trade, those economies

with highlyskewed distribution(to the left)willbecomenet lenders.

Redistributivepoliciesthereforewillhaveimpactsonintertemporaltrade.

Forexample, if agovernmentadopts abail-outpolicy(a redistributionfrom

successfulenterpreneurstounsuccessfulones),thiswillincreasethesupplyof

enterpreneurs, drivingup theautarkicinterestrate. Consequently,acountry

which would be a lender if there were no bail-out policy is a net borrower

under the bail-out policy.

Whilethe literatureon riskaversion and entrepreneurship (see belowfor

abriefsurvey)emphasizesthe roleofthe coeÆcientofriskaversioninaloan

market with perfect information,weshow that itis the concept of prudence

thatplaysanimportantrolewhenrisk-averse individualsborrowinamarket

under imperfect information.

An interesting feature of the paper is the endogenous determination of

occupational choice. Individuals with identical utility functions but

di er-ent wealth endowments self-select to be (ornot to be) entrepreneur. In our

model, the outcome of any investment project depends onthe e ortlevel of

the entrepreneur incharge of the project. This e ortlevelis not observable

by lenders or nancial intermediaries. Contracts are designed to give

en-trepreneursincentivestoexert e ort. Whilethese contracts mitigateagainst

opportunismbyentrepreneurs, theycannotreplicatetheoutcomethatwould

beobtained under symmetric information. An important implicationof our

results isthat, inan extended version ofthe model,a well-designed

redistri-bution of wealth may stimulate risk-taking activities and result in a higher

growth rate.

(6)

capital market imperfections. It is useful to o erhere abrief comparison of

assumptions and results. Kihlstrom and La ont (1979) consider a society

with individuals having utility functions with di erent degrees of risk

aver-sion. They showthatmorerisk-averse individualsbecomeworkers while less

risk-averse onesbecomeentrepreneurs. Inour modelallindividualshavethe

same utility function, but di erent endowments of wealth. It is the

di er-enceininitialwealthsthatcausesindividualstochoosedi erentoccupations.

Kanbur (1979) alsostudies the relationshipbetween risk taking and income

distribution. Heassumesthatindividualshaveidenticalattitudetorisk,but

theirproductionfunctionsareex-postdi erentfromeachotherbecauseof

in-dependent productivity shocks whichare observed before individualsdecide

on becomingentrepreneur or worker.

Galor and Ziera (1993) consider a model with irreversible investment

involving xed costs. They assume that agents borrow to nance their

in-vestmentinskillacquisition,andbequeathsomeoftheirwealth. Thelending

rateishigherthantheborrowingrate,andthecostofborrowingishigherfor

borrowers with low initial wealth. The amounts these borrowers bequeath

are also smaller. The authors show that agents whose wealth lies below a

threshold level nd it optimal to choose unskilled jobs, with low wages. As

a result, their descendents will also choose to be unskilled workers due to

their low level of inherited wealth. A similar model is studied by Banerjee

and Newman (1993) who assume that borrowers need to o er collaterals to

lenders. Children ofpoorindividualsdonot inheritmuch,andtherefore

can-not o er suÆcient collaterals to potential lenders. They are thus forced to

choose not to be entrepreneurs. de Meza and Webb (1999) show that lack

of information on the part of banks may lead to an over-provision of loans

that encourages entry into entrepreneurship. If the associated incentive

ef-fects are strong, then there will be a positive relationship between wealth

and entrepreneurial activities.

Aghion and Bolton (1997) formulate a model similar to ours, but they

assumethatallagentsarerisk-neutral. Theprobabilityofsuccessofaproject

is dependent on the e ortlevelchosen by the entrepreneur. In their model,

individualsintheright-handtailofthewealthdistributionareentrepreneurs

who do not borrow, while individuals in the middle section of the wealth

distribution need to borrow to be entrepreneurs, because they do not have

suÆcientwealthtopayforthelumpyinvestment. Thisisinmarkedcontrast

(7)

aversion (b) partial collateral, and (b) bankruptcy cost, while Aghion and

Boltonassumeriskneutrality andstrictly limitedliability(zero paymentsto

banks inthe event of project failure).

Newman(1995)assumesriskaversion,and ndthat,undermoralhazard,

the poorer individuals tend to be risk-takers and the wealthier individuals

are risk-averters. This may beexplained asfollows. Optimalcontract under

moral hazard serve to resolve the tension between consumption-smoothing

across states of nature, and eÆcient deployment of e ort. We know that

wealthier individuals tend to need less insurance at the margin. Optimal

contractspromptthemtobearmoreriskatanygivene ortlevel. Individuals

with greater wealth nd it too costly (in terms of e ort) to bear risks, as

designed inthe contracts.

All the models cited above share a common assumption: there is no

transfer of resources from the entrepreneurs to the lenders in the event of

projectfailure. Thismay becalledthe\stronglimitedliability"assumption.

Our modelallowaweakerversionoflimitedliability: weassumethatpartof

an entrepreneur's private savings must be used topay debts in the event of

projectfailure. In addition,weassume theexistence of asmallreal resource

cost in the settling of a bankruptcy case. These twin assumptions play an

important role in our model. We nd that the very poor do not take risks,

because the marginal utilty of wealth in the event of bankruptcy is very

high. We also nd that the very rich do not become entrepreneurs, because

the e ort isvery costly.

The papers cited above deal with closed economies, and most authors

consider only a partial equilibriumsetting. Grossman (1984) addressed the

issue ofthe relationshipbetween internationaltradeand theformationof an

entrepreneurial class. He showed that in a free trade equilibrium, there is

a tendency to over-specialize in the non-risky sector and under-specializein

risk-taking activities. However, in his model, there was no risk sharing

ar-rangements. Thenon-existenceof nancialmarketwasexogenouslyimposed.

As Dixit(1987) pointed out, once the incentive compatibility conditions are

explicitly introduced, the market outcome is arguably a Pareto optimum.

That is, once the sources of marketimperfections are speci ed, risk-sharing

arrangementswill incorporate those features in incentive compatibility

con-ditions, and it would be impossible to improve upon the market by means

of public provisionof insurance etc. Grossman and Maggi(2000) consider a

(8)

diverse workforceexports the goodfor whichindividualsuccess ismore

im-portantthanteamproduction. Adverse selectiontendstocreateamismatch

of talents which tend to be exacerbated under free trade. While Grossman

and Maggiplaceemphasis ontheinteraction between distributionoftalents,

adverseselectioninthelabormarket,and trade,ourpaperisconcernedwith

interactions between wealth distributions, moral hazard, and imperfections

in the credit market, in the contextof a tradingworld.

The plan of the paper is as follows. In section 2, we develop a modelof

a closed economy, and state the assumptions and notation. In Section 3,we

characterize equilibrium loan contracts under moral hazard, and show how

the equilibrium riskless rate of interest and the occupational choice are

de-termined. Section4considers atwo-country worldand shows howacountry

with a more skewed distribution of wealth tends to be the net lender. We

also consider some extensions of the model, such as the implications of a

bail-out policy. Some concludingremarks are o ered insection 5.

2 The Autarkic Equilibrium

2.1 Assumptions and Notations

Webegin by consideringamodelof aclosedeconomy. There isacontinuum

of individualsinthiseconomy. Theydi erintheirinitialwealth,denoted by

w. The(cumulative)distributionofinitialwealthisF(w),andf(w)denotes

the corresponding density function. It is assumed that there is a closed

interval [w L

;w H

] over which f(w)is strictly positive,and that f(w)=0 for

all w outsidethis interval. We assume0<w L <w H . Then Z w H w L f(w)dw=1

and the percapita wealth is

 w= Z w H w L wf(w)dw:

Thereare onlytwo periods. For simplicity,we assumethat consumption

takes place only in period two 1

. In period one, each individual may choose

1

ThisassumptionisalsomadebyGertlerandRogo (1990),butintheirmodel,unlike

ours, entrepreneurship is not endogenous. Aghion and Bolton (1997) also assume that

(9)

activity, using part of his own wealth, plus some additional borrowing, to

nance hisinvestment project), or he may choose not tobe anentrepreneur

(in which case he would keep all his wealth in the form of a deposit in a

nancialinstitution,whicho ers himthe risklessgross rateof returnr>1).

The endogenous determinationof r willbe explainedin due course.

We assume that wealth, in its physical form, cannot be stored 2

. It

fol-lows that all wealth must eventually be lent (via the nancial institutions)

to entrepreneurs, who use them as input in their investment projects. We

adopt the standard assumption that nancial institutions are risk neutral

and perfectlycompetitive,so that their expected pro tsare zero.

Each entrepreneur can carry out only one investment project. Each

projectrequires 

k units of wealth. We assume that

 k>w

H

(1)

so that all entrepreneurs need external nancing. A project can turn out to

bea success or a failure. In the case of success, the pay-o of the project is

a > 

k. In the case of failure, the pay-o is zero. The probability of success

is denoted by (e), where e is the e ort level of the entrepreneur, which is

not observableby themarket. Forsimplicity,weassumethatecantakeonly

two possible values, 0 or 1. We write p = (1) > q = (0). This indicates

that the model exhibits the moral hazard property: the entrepreneur, who

is a net borrower, may have an incentive to work at an e ort level that is

lowerthanwhatwouldbeeÆcientinaworld ofperfectinformation. Inwhat

follows, unless otherwise stated, we assume that p q is suÆciently great,

sothat the equilibriumcontractshavethe followingproperty: entrepreneurs

are suÆciently rewarded forsuccess that they havean incentivetoset e =1

even though e isnot observable.

Since each entrepreneur needs 

k units of capital as input, the

assump-tion that  k > w

H

implies that in equilibrium, the endogenous number of

entrepreneurs, N, isless thanthenumberofindividualsinthiseconomy,M.

Eachindividual has the followingutility function

U =U(y;e)=v(y) e

2

An alternative assumption is that wealth can be stored but the rate of return on

(10)

is a positive parameter. Weset =1 by normalization 3

. The function v(y)

is increasing and strictly concave, with

v 0

(0)=1:

This property implies that each individual will invest some wealth in the

riskless asset (i.e., lending to a nancial institution), to avoid having zero

wealth in period 2.

Whiletheoutcomeofanygivenprojectisuncertain,weassumethe

proba-bilityofsuccessofanygivenprojectisindependentofthoseofotherprojects,

andthatthe numberofprojectsislargeenoughsothatthelawoflarge

num-ber applies. Thus, for the economy as a whole, if all entrepreneurs choose

e=1,aggregate outputis paN whereN isthe measure ofthe set of

individ-uals who,in equilibrium,choose tobe entrepreneur.

Since the expected return on a project is pa and entrepreneurs have to

incur e ort cost,itis thecase that the risklessrate of interestr must satisfy

the condition that

r 

k <pa+(1 p)0 (2)

2.2 A Benchmark Case: Observable E ort and No

Bankruptcy Cost

If the e ort level of each entrepreneur is observable, and if there is no

bankruptcy cost, thenwe are inthe rst-best world. Since thereisa

contin-uum ofindividualsandacontinuumof investmentprojects, inthe aggregate

there is no risk, and a perfect insurance market implies that all individuals

are perfectly insured, given that their function v(y) is strictly concave. We

focus on the case where p=q is suÆciently great, so that optimal contracts

specify that entrepreneurs must exercise full e ort(e=1).

Given the rate of interest r;competitive nancial institutions o er

con-tracts that specify, for any given w, the amount 

k k(w) to be lent to the

entrepreneur with wealth w, and the payments R s

(w) and R f

(w) that he

must make in the events of success and failure respectively. Here k(w)

de-notes the amount of equity that the entrepreneur puts in his project. The

3

An entrepreneurcan choosee tobe0or1. Non-entrepreneursneed notexpend any

(11)

to zero expected pro t for the nancialinstitutions: maxpv[ (w k)r+a R s ]+(1 p)v[ (w k)r R f ] 1 subjectto pR s +(1 p)R f =r(  k k)

The solution yieldsconstant utility across statesof nature

(w k)r+a R s =(w k)r R f At the optimum,R s +rk and R f +rk are determinedby R s +rk =(1 p)a+r  k R f +rk =R s +rk a

Thus, given r, the expected utility of an entrepreneur with initial wealth w

who accepts a contract that stipulates e =1, is

EV e (w;1;r)=v h wr+pa r  k i 1 (3)

Similarly,azero-expected-pro tcontractthat maximizesthe expected

u-tilityofanentrepreneurwithinitialwealthw,giventhathise ortisspeci ed

to be e=0, yieldsthe net utility

EV e (w;0;r)=v h wr+qa r  k i 0 (4)

De ne the function

(w;r)EV e (w;1;r) EV e (w;0;r)=v h wr+pa r  k i 1 v h wr+qa r  k i (5)

This function measures, for an individual with wealth w; the relative

at-tractivenes of being an entrepreneur with e = 1 (rather than being an

en-trepreneur with e = 0). It is decreasing in w for any given r:  w

< 0.We

assume that, for all r < pa= 

k, (w;r) > 0 for w = w L

and (w;r) < 0

for w suÆciently great. Then there exists a \criticalvalue" w c

(r) such that

individuals with wealth w < w c

(r) will prefer being an entrepreneur with

e=1 tobeing one with e=0. Since (w;r)is increasing inr forall w<  k,

(12)

if w (r) < w H

(which is less than 

k by assumption), an increase in r will

increase w c : dw c dr =  r  w = fv 0 h wr+pa r  k i v 0 h wr+qa r  k i g(w  k)  w >0

A pure lender,on the other hand, obtainsthe utilityv(wr):If r>qa=  k,

[respectively, if r < qa= 

k] the strategy of being a pure lender dominates

[respectively, is dominated by] that of being an entrepreneur who exerts no

e ort. We assume that q is so smallthat in equilibrium, r > qa=  k. Let us de ne (w;r)=EV e (w;1;r) 1 v(wr)

This functionmeasures, for anindividualwithwealth w; therelative

attrac-tivenesofbeinganentrepreneurwithe=1(ratherthanbeingapurelender.)

Then,forallrintheinterval[qa=  k;pa=  k], (w;r)isdecreasinginw: w <0.

There exists a value w b

(r)such that (w b

(r);r)=0. Given the assumption

that r >qa= 

k,we can deduce that w b (r)<w c (r), and dw b dr = r w = v 0 h wr+pa r  k i (w  k) v 0 (wr)w v 0 h wr+pa r  k i r v 0 [wr]r <0

Thus, in this economy, under perfect information (i.e., e ort is

observ-able), the demand forloans is

B(r)= Z w b (r) w L (  k w)f(w)dw

and the supply of loans is

L(r)= Z W H w b (r) wf(w)dw Since B 0 (r) = (  k w b )f(w b ) dw b dr < 0 and L 0 (r) = w b f(w b ) dw b dr > 0, the

demand curve isdownward sloping,and the supply curve isupward sloping.

Theirintersectiondeterminestheequilibriuminterestrate,r  . Atr  ,demand equals supply, B(r  )=L(r  ),implying  k Z w b (r  ) w L f(w)dw= Z w H w L wf(w)dw=w

(13)

w  w b (r  )

and let F(w)denote the cumulativedistribution of wealth:

F(w) Z w w L f(z)dz then F(w  )=  w  k

Tosummarize,underperfectinformation,thefraction ofpopulationwho

are entrepreneurs in equilibriumis w= 

k, and only individualswhose wealth

is smallerthan w  F 1 (w= 

k)will choose to be entrepreneurs.

2.3 The Moral Hazard Case: Unobservable E ort

Now we turn to the case of unobservable e ort levels. We continue to

as-sumethateachentrepreneur'swealthisknowntothe nancialintermediaries.

This,and theassumptionthat individualshavethe sameutilityfunctionand

identicalabilitymeansthatthereisnoadverseselectionproblem: noonecan

lieabouthiswealthorhisutilityfunction. Theonlyproblemismoralhazard:

if how much an entrepreneur must pay back to the nancial intermediaries

is independent of his e ortlevel,then he may have an incentiveto exert no

e ort. Contracts must therefore be designed to provide suÆcient incentive

for enterpreneurstochoose e=1(Thisisof coursebased onthe assumption

that p q is suÆciently great tojustify the choice e=1:)

We now describe a contract for an entrepreneur with wealth level w.

Recall that we assumed w H

< 

k. The contract says that \if your wealth is

w and youcontributeanamountk wasyour \equity"inyour investment

project(sothat your borrowing fromyour nancialinstitution is 

k k 0)

andyoudeposittheremainingw kata nancialinstitution,thenyoumust

pay back toyour lender(the nancialinstitution, orFIforshort)anamount

which depends onthe outcome of your project. Ifthe outcome is \success",

your investment yields the gross return a, and you must pay an amount R

toyour FI;if youroutcome is\failure"(the investmentyieldsa grossreturn

of zero), then, with your periodtwo wealth (w k)r, you must pay back to

the FI anamount ( 

k k)>0". (In what follows, we assume <r.) The

assumption that > 0 is meant to capture the fact that most real world

(14)

to be very small.

It follows that if the entrepreneur exerts e ort (i.e., e = 1), then his

expectedutility is pv[(w k)r+a R ]+(1 p)v h (w k)r (  k k) i 1G(w;k;R ;1)

and if he does not exert e ort(i.e., e=0), then hisexpected utility is

qv[(w k)r+a R ]+(1 q)v h (w k)r (  k k) i G(w;k;R ;0)

We assume also that when a bankrupt entrepreneur pays the amount

( 

k k)>0tohisFI,the latteronlygets afraction of it:Inother words,

the FI incurs a real cost (1 ) ( 

k k) in collecting ( 

k k) from the

failed entrepreneur. Bankruptcy costs are cost associated with the transfer

ofresources fromthe debtortothecreditorinthe badstateofnature. These

costs consist of legal fees, delay costs, etc. Several studies have shown that

suchcosts canhaveanimpactonthe valueof claimsownedbycreditors and

are re ected inthe pricing of loans.

Thus an FI that lends the amount 

k k to an entrepreneur who does

exert e ortcan expect toget

pR+(1 p) (  k k)

Ontheotherhand,theFItakesrasgiven,andmustpaytheamountr(  k k)

to depositors. In equilibrium, we have the following zero expected pro t

condition (if e=1): pR+(1 p) (  k k)=r(  k k) (6)

Competition among the FIs imply that, for given r, the FIs will o er

to any entrepreneur with wealth w a contract that maximizes his expected

utility,subjecttothezeropro tcondition. Wealsoassumethatthecontract

provides enoughincentive for the entrepreneur to exert e ort(e=1). More

formally,FIj willo ertothe entrepreneurwith wealth wa pairof

number-s (R ;k) that maximizes G(w;k;R ;1) subject to the incentive compatibility

constraint

G(w;k;R ;1)G(w;k;R ;0) (7)

(15)

Wenowturntoafullercharacterizationofequilibriumcontracts. Weproceed

as follows. First, we take the interest rate r as given, and show how the

incentive compatibility constraint and the zero pro t condition determine

the contract for entrepreneurs at each wealth level. Then we show how the

theinterestraterisdeterminedendogenously. Inwhatfollows,wenormalize

by setting=1.

3.1 Equilibrium loan contracts for entrepreneurs,

giv-en the interest rate on the safe asset

In equilibrium,pro twillbezero, andthe incentivecompatibility

constrain-t binds for each entrepreneur. It follows that, for given r, conditions (6)

and (7) determine the equilibrium contract for entrepreneurs with wealth

w. The following lemma characterizes the equilibrium contract, under the

assumption that is small:

LEMMA 1: (Equilibrium contract) In equilibrium, for given r, there

exists a lower bound w>0such that entrepreneurs with wealth w w will

belentthe amount 

k k(w)and willbe asked to pay the amountR (w)0

in the event of success, and h



k k(w) i

 0 in the event of failure, where

the pair (R (w);k(w)) satisfy the following conditions:

(i)the expectedpro t of the FIis zero

R = (  k k) p [r (1 p) ] for k   k (8)

and (ii) the incentive compatibility constraintholds with equality

v[(w k)r+a R ] v h (w k)r (  k k) i = 1 p q (9)

Proof: See the Appendix.

REMARK1: Equation(8)impliesthat,giventhe risklessrate ofinterest

r,the repayment tothe FI(in the event of success) perdollarborrowed isa

constant, independentof the amount borrowed:

r s  R  k k = 1 p [r (1 p) ]:

(16)

s

theeventoffailure,is perdollarborrowed.) Given , whichisexogenous

inour model, nancialinstitutions willbewillingtolend onlytoindividuals

whose wealth exceeds a certainlowerbound w>0:

REMARK2: Equation(8)isrepresentedinFigure1 by thedownward

s-lopingcurveKKinthe(k;R )space,withtheverticalintercept[ r (1 p) ]



k=p. Ifp q issuÆciently close toone, and is suÆciently small, then the

intercept of the secondcurve (de ned by (9) and denoted as the curve VV)

is below[r (1 p) ] 

k=p and hence the two curveswillhave an

intersec-tion (k(w);R (w))with k(w)>0 and R (w)>0,if w exceeds a certainlower

bound w>0.

PLEASE PLACE FIGURE 1HERE

LEMMA2: Entrepreneurswithgreaterwwillborrowless(i.e. 

k k(w)

decreases with wealth) and hence invest more (put more equity) in the risky

project, i.e. k 0

(w)>0, given that contracts must satisfy (8)and (9).

Proof: Note that the curve KK is independent of w. For any given k,

an increase in w will shift the curve VV down, resulting in an intersection

tothe rightof theformer intersection. Hencek 

increases, andR 

decreases.

This means the individual borrows less when hiswealth increases.

REMARK 3: One of the standard text-book results is that if the payo

per dollar invested in a risky asset in each state of nature is independent

of the amount invested in the risky asset, then the amount an individual

invests inthe risky assetisanincreasing functionof hiswealthif and onlyif

his absolute risk aversion is a decreasing function of wealth. Our result in

Lemma 2isdi erent,becausethe pay-o perdollarof equity inthe event of

success is Æ s = a R k = a k 1 pk [r (1 p) ](  k k)

which is dependent on k (decreasing in k). (And similarly, the pay-o per

dollar of equity in the event of failureincreases in k.) Lemma 1 states that,

with a concave utility function, but independently of whether absolute risk

aversion is a decreasing or increasing function, entrepreneurs with greater

wealth will contribute more equity inthe project.

LEMMA3: Giventhatcontractsmustsatisfy(8)and(9),entrepreneurs

withgreaterwwillinvest moreinthe risklessasset,(i.e., w k 

(w)increases

(17)

v 0 (s)(r )>[v 0 (u) v 0 (s) ] p (10)

where u is the nal wealth inthe failurestate,

uu(w)(w k(w))r ( 

k k(w)) (11)

and s isthe nal wealthin the success state,

ss(w)(w k(w))r+a R (w) (12)

Proof: From (8) and (9), weget

dk dw = [v 0 (u) v 0 (s)]pr [v 0 (u) v 0 (s)]pr+v 0 (s)(r ) [ v 0 (u) v 0 (s) ] p (13)

which isless than 1if and only if (10) holds.

REMARK4: Condition(10) holds if issmall, which isassumed here.

3.2 An example: logarithmic utility

Let

v(y)=lny

then we obtain from(9)

ln " (w k)r+a R (w k)r (  k k) # = 1 p q hence wr kr+a (  k k)r s = h wr kr (  k k) i e 1=(p q) Thus h r s +(r )e 1=(p q) r i k= h r s e 1=(p q) i  k a+rw h e 1=(p q) 1 i (14) i.e., k(w)= h r s e 1=(p q) i  k a+rw h e 1=(p q) 1 i [r s +(r )e 1=(p q) r] (15)

(18)

dk dw = h e 1=(p q) 1 i r [e 1=(p q) 1]r+[r s e 1=(p q) ]

whichispositiveand less than1provided issmall. Thisis consistentwith

Lemmas 2 and 3.

3.3 To be or not to be an entrepreneur

So far, we have characterized contracts that the FIs o er to potential

en-trepreneurs with wealth w, which would make him choose e = 1, assuming

that he does want to be an entrepreneur. But depending on his wealth, an

individualmay nd that theutility of being alender;v(rw),may exceed the

expectedutilityofbeing anentrepreneur, i.e.,itispossiblethat, forsomew,

we have

v(rw)>EU pv(s)+(1 p)v(u) 1 (16)

Clearly, if w is close to zero, condition (16) will be satis ed, because

nancial institutions lend a positive amount only to individuals with w 

w > 0: Thus the curve v(rw) lies above the curve EU when w is small: At

some b

w >0, the curve EU cuts the curve v(rw) from below. The question

is whether there exists some value e w >

b

w such that the curve v(rw) again

overtakesthe curveEU. The answerturnsout todepends onthemagnitude

ofthecoeÆcientofprudence,aconceptintroducedbyKimball(1990),which

is inturn related tothe convexity of the followingfunction

(y) 1

v 0

(y)

which, in our model, measures the marginal rate of substitution between

e ort and income:

MR S ey = U e U y =  v 0 (y) = 1 v 0 (y)

The function (r) is convex if and only if the coeÆcient of prudence is

smaller than twice the coeÆcientof absolute riskaversion:

2v 00 v 0  v 000 v 00 (17)

(19)

1990). 4

LEMMA 4:

(i)If (y)is concave, then

p v 0 (s) + 1 p v 0 (u)  1 v 0 (ps+(1 p)u) (18)

and if (y)is convex, then

p v 0 (s) + 1 p v 0 (u)  1 v 0 (ps+(1 p)u) (19)

(ii)if is small, then

1 v 0 (ps+(1 p)u)  1 v 0 (rw) (20)

Proof: Part (i) follows from Jensen's inequality.The inequality in part

(ii)holds if and onlyif

rw<ps+(1 p)u (21)

Now, if is small, then ps+(1 p)u= rw rk(w)+pa ( 

k k(w))[r

(1 p) ( 1)]'rw+pa r 

k >rw because of (2).

LEMMA 5: If (y) is convex, then the curve EU may cut the curve

v(rw)from belowat some value b

w>0,and then from above,at some value

e w>

b

w. (see Figure 2).

Proof: see the Appendix and Figure2.

PLEASE PLACE FIGURE 2HERE.

The following propositionfollows immediatelyfromthe above lemma:

Proposition 1: if the coeÆcient of prudence is smaller than twice the

coeÆcientofabsoluteriskaversion,thenitispossiblethat,givenr,thereare

4

Notethat decreasingabsoluteriskaversionholdsi

v 000 v 00 > v 00 v 0

which is not inconsistentwith (17). For further resultson the role of v 000

, see Hartwick

(20)

twovaluesw(r)<w(r)suchthatonlyindividualswhosewealth liesbetween

them will choose to be entrepreneurs. Individuals with wealth exceeding

e

w(r),andthosewithwealthbelow b

w(r)willchoosetoinvestinthesafeasset

(i.e., lend to nancialintermediaries).

REMARK: Proposition 1 may be explained as follows: given that the

marginalrate of substitutionbetween e ortand incomeis convex iny,

indi-viduals with very low wealth do not want to become entrepreneur because

they are not willing to take risks, and individuals who are very wealthy do

not wantto become entrepreneur because they do not want toexert e ort.

We now show how the two critical values b w(r) and e w(r) change when r increases. Proposition 2: b w 0 (r) > 0 and e w 0 (r) < 0 provided that (1 p) is

suÆciently small, where f(r )=(r )g 10

Proof: see the Appendix.

3.4 Endogenous determination of the interest rate on

the safe asset

So far, we have taken the interest rate r as given. Now we turn to its

determination. This is given by the condition that the the interest rate

must equate the aggregate lending by non-entrepreneurs (to the nancial

institutions)totheaggregateborrowingbyentrepreneurs(fromthe nancial

institutions). The former is given by

L(r)= Z b w (r) w L wf(w)dw+ Z w H e w(r) wf(w)dw

and the latteris

B(r)= Z e w (r) b w (r) (  k w)f(w)dw

The excess demand (function) forfund is

D(r)=B(r) L(r)=  k Z e w(r) b w (r) f(w)dw Z w H w L wf(w)dw=  k Z e w (r) b w (r) f(w)dw w

Clearly,ifrisveryhigh, thenD(r)<0,andififr =0,thenD(r)<0(recall

that 

k > w). By continuity, there exists a value r 

such that D(r 

(21)

Furthermore, such r is unique, because D(r) < 0: Thus we obtain the

followingresult:

Proposition3: There exists a unique r 

>0 such that the loan market

clears. Individuals with wealth exceeding e w(r



) lend all their wealth to the

nancial institutions,at the safeinterestrate r 

, and sodo individualswith

wealth below b w(r



). Individualswhosewealth liesbetween thesetwocritical

valueswillbeentrepreneurs, and they invest afraction oftheirwealth inthe

safeasset,theremainingfractionbeingusedasequitycapital,whichisalways

less than the total amount of capital invested in each risky project. The

equilibrium fraction of the population who choose to become entrepreneurs

is N M =  w  k = Z e w(r  ) b w (r  ) f(w)dw. (22) 4 Open Economies

4.1 International Borrowing Under the Moral Hazard

Case

Nowconsider twocountries withthesamepopulationsizeand thesamelevel

of per capita wealth, but di erent distributions of wealth. We will look at

theirautarkicequilibria,andexaminethe incentiveforinternational

borrow-ing. Letusassumetherearetwocountries,AandB. Thedensityfunctionsof

the twowealth distributionsarerespectivelyf A (w; A )andf B (w; B ),where  A and  B

are shift parameters. Now consider the autarkic equilibrium of

country A, and let r A

be the autarkic interest rate. Consider the following

thought experiment: Suppose the distribution f A (:)undergoes achange:  A now increases to   A , which makes f A (w;  A ) < f A (w; A

) for all w in the

interval [ b w(r A ); e w(r A

)]. Then clearly at the value r A

, the numberof willing

entrepreneurs willbeless than N. To restoreequilibrium,r A

must belower.

Tomakethe aboveargumentmoreprecise,letuswritethe equationthat

determines the equilibrium autarkicrate of interestas

F A [ e w(r A ); A ] F A [ b w(r A ); A ]=  w  k Then dr A d A =

(22)

 ( @ @w F A [ e w(r A ); A ] ) d e w(r A ) dr ( @ @w F A [ b w(r A ); A ] ) d b w(r A ) dr <0 by Proposition 2, and  ( @ @ A F A [ e w(r A ); A ] ) ( @ @ A F A [ b w(r A ); A ] ) = @ @ A Z e w(r A ) b w(r A ) f(w; A )dw = Z e w(r A ) b w (r A ) @ @ A f(w; A )dw<0 It follows that dr A d A <0.

Note that in the above argument, the condition @ @ A f(w; A ) < 0 over [ b w(r A ); e w(r A

)] issuÆcient, but not necessary, for tobe negative.

Itfollowsfromtheabove reasoningthatif thedensityfunctionf B (w; B ) di ers fromf A (w; A )in that f B (w; B )<f A (w; A ) for allw2[ b w(r A ); e w(r A )]

then country B will have a higher autarkic gross rate of return: r B

> r A

.

Under these conditions, the opening ofworld nancialmarkets willresultin

capital owfrom A toB. We obtainthe following proposition:

Proposition 4: Two countries with identical per capita wealth and

i-dentical individual utilityfunction may engage inintertemporaltradeif the

distributions of wealth are di erent.

Corollary: A marginal redistribution of wealth away from the

enter-preneurial class of a country can turn that country status from being a net

lender toa net borrower.

4.2 Bailouts

In this section, we set up a framework for studying the implications of

gov-ernment policies that seek to help bankrupt entrepreneurs. Suppose the

government taxes successful entrepreneurs, collecting from them amount T

each, and pay the unsuccessful ones an amount : Balanced budgetrequires

that pT Z e w (r) b w(r) f(w)dw=(1 p) Z e w (r) b w (r) f(w)dt (23)

(23)

where [w(r);w(r)] are solutionsof the equation v(rw)=pv[(w k)r+(a R ) T]+(1 p)v h (w k)r (  k k)+ i 1

Doesthis bailoutpolicyresult inalowerorhigherequilibriuminterest rate?

What is its implicationon the country's net borrowing?

First,note that (23) implies that

dT

d =

1 p

p

Thecontractbetweenthe nancialintermediary(FI)andtheentrepreneur

with wealth w must nowsatisfy

(p q)[v(s) v(u)]=1 (24) and pR=   k k  [r (1 p) ] (25) where now s(w k)r+(a R ) T and u(w k)r (  k k)+

From (24) and (25), we have

@k @T = pv 0 (s) pv 0 (u)(r )+(1 p)v 0 (s)(r ) and @k @ = pv 0 (u) pv 0 (u)(r )+(1 p)v 0 (s)(r ) Hence dk d = @k @T dT d + @k @ = (1 p)v 0 (s)+pv 0 (u) pv 0 (u)(r )+(1 p)v 0 (s)(r )

To nd the respose of theintersectionpoints e

w(r) and b

w(r)with respect

to , we use the equation of indi erence, whichis now

q p q +v h (w k  )r (  k k  )+ i =v(wr) (26)

(24)

where k =k (w;T;(T)). From (26) we get dw d =  1   (1 p)v 0 (u)v 0 (s) ( 1) (1 p)v 0 (s)(r )+pv 0 (u)(r ) (27) where =v 0 (s) " r (r ) @k @w # v 0 (NE)r (28) which is positive at b w(r) and negative at e

w(r). Hence, for a given r, b w(r)

increasesand e

w(r)decreaseswhenthereisanincreasein. Thisimpliesthat

thenumberof entrepreneursincreases, leadingtoanincreases inthe demand

for fund. Torestore equilibrium,the rate of interestr must increase.

Proposition5: Bail-outpoliciesofthetypedescribed abovewillleadto

an increase in the equilibriumrate of interest. In a two-country world, this

means that the country with such bail-out policies will become the debtor

country.

REMARK: The role of the bankuptcy cost factor < 1 is crucial here.

If =1, then bailoutshave noe ect onthe equilibriuminterestrate.

5 Concluding remarks

We have set up a model to show that a country's wealth distribution

in- uences the occupational choice of individuals: to be or not to be an

en-trepreneur. We have alsoshowed that, under certain assumptions, only the

middle-class individuals choose to be entrepreneurs. An implication is that

countries that have the same level of per capita wealth and the same

indi-vidualutilityfunction mayengage inmutualintertemporaltrade, aslongas

they havedi erent wealth distributions. The key elements inour modelare

(i) the tension between consumption smoothing across states of nature on

the one hand, and contract design to overcome moral hazard on the other

hand, (ii) the relationship between of the coeÆcients of prudence and risk

aversion, and (iii)bankruptcy cost and partial liability.

Thereareseveral directions ofgeneralization,whichwewish topursuein

ourfuturework. Anobviousextensionistheprocessofcapitalaccumulation.

One would thenbeable tosee howmoralhazardand initialwealth

distribu-tions in uencegrowthrates, andtodetermine conditionsunderwhichcycles

may occur. Taxation policies, including transfers, may be studied in the

(25)

PROOF OF LEMMA 1

Consider the problem

max R;k G(R ;k;w;1)=pv((w k)r+a R )+(1 p)v((w k)r (  k k)) 1 subjectto v((w k)r+a R ) v((w k)r (  k k)) 1 p q (29) and pR (  k k)[r (1 p) ]0 (30)

In the (k;R ) space, the feasible set isthe intersection of area abovethe line

R= (  k k) p [r (1 p) ] (31)

withtheareabelowthe(positivelysloped)curvede nedby(29),seeFigure2.

The absolutevalueof theslopeof theline(31),dR =dp, isapproximatelyr=p

if issmall. NowitiseasytoverifythattheobjectivefunctionG(R ;k;w;1)

isstrictlyconcaveanddecreasing in(k;R ). Thismeansthattheiso-expected

utility curves are concave inthe (k;R ) space, with negativeslope given by

@R @k = G k G R

If issmall,theabsolutevalueofthisslopeisapproximately(r=p)[v 0

(u)=v 0

(s)]>

(r=p). It follows that the maximum occurs at the point where both

con-straintshold with equality.

PROOF OF LEMMA 5:

Let (w)  v(rw) EU(w) be the di erence between the utility of a

pure lender with wealth w and the expected utility of an entrepreneur

hav-ing the same wealth. We wish to nd conditions which imply that (w) is

a U shaped curve, taking positive values for small w, negative values for

intermediatevalues of w,and positivevalues again forlarge values of w.

Byde nition

(26)

(w)=v(rw) [v(u)+q=(p q)] (33)

We want toshow that  0

(w) <0 for small w and  0 (w)> 0 for large w. Now  0 =rv 0 (rw) v 0 (u)[r(1 k 0 (w))+ k 0 (w)] where @k @w = pr[ v 0 (u) v 0 (s)] pv 0 (u)(r )+(1 p)v 0 (s)(r ) (34)  0 (w) isnegative i H v 0 (u) " r (r ) @k @w # rv 0 (rw)>0 (35) which isequivalent to r (r ) @k @w > rv 0 (rw) v 0 (u) i.e., " 1 v 0 (rw) v 0 (u) # r>(r ) @k @w i.e., " v 0 (u) v 0 (rw) v 0 (u) # >(r ) p[v 0 (u) v 0 (s)] pv 0 (u)(r )+(1 p)v 0 (s)(r ) i.e., " v 0 (u) v 0 (rw) v 0 (u) # > p[v 0 (u) v 0 (s)] pv 0 (u)+(1 p)v 0 (s)f(r )=(r )g (36)

Let 1+ =f(r )=(r )g1. Inequality (36) holds i

" v 0 (u) v 0 (rw) v 0 (u) # > p[v 0 (u) v 0 (s)] pv 0 (u)+(1 p)v 0 (s)(1+ ) (37)

(27)

" pv 0 (u)+(1 p)v 0 (s)(1+ ) v 0 (u)v 0 (s) # [v 0 (u) v 0 (rw)]> p[v 0 (u) v 0 (s)] v 0 (s) (38) Let Z = pv 0 (u)+(1 p)v 0 (s) v 0 (u)v 0 (s) (39) Then (38) holds i 1+ (1 p) " 1 v 0 (rw) v 0 (u) # >Zv 0 (rw) (40) i [Zv 0 (rw) 1] (1 p) " 1 v 0 (rw) v 0 (u(w)) # <0 (41)

Note that v(rw) = v(u)+q=(p q) implies that rw > u(w) and hence

1 v 0 (rw) v 0 (u(w))

>0: We want the inequality (41) to hold for small w and to be

reversed for large w. Now, from Lemma 4,if is small and (w) isconvex,

then p v 0 (s) + 1 p v 0 (u) > 1 v 0 (rw) and hence Zv 0

(rw)>1, and (w) may be U-shaped if (1 p) h 1 v 0 (rw) v 0 (u(w)) i

is larger [respectively, smaller] than [Zv 0

(rw) 1] for small w; and smaller

[respectively, larger] than itfor large w.

It follows that if (w) is convex, then the EU curve may cut the v(rw)

curve from belowat some b

w,and then fromabove, atsome e w>

b w.

PROOF OF PROPOSITION 2

From (8)and (9), we have

@k @w = 1  [v 0 (u) v 0 (s)]pr>0 and @k @r = 1  h fv 0 (u) v 0 (s)g(w k)p+v 0 (s)(  k k) i where =pv 0 (u)(r )+(1 p)v 0 (s)(r )>0

(28)

r,we get dw dr = 1 H " wv 0 (NE) v 0 (u)(w k)+(r )v 0 (u) @k @r # (42)

where H, de ned in (35) above, is positive at b

w(r) and negative at e w(r).

The numerator in(42)must now besigned. It can be written as

wv 0 (NE)+v 0 (u) " p(w k)fv 0 (u) v 00 (s)g+v 0 (s)(  k k) pv 0 (u)+(1 p)v 0 (s)(1+ ) (w k) #

The term inside the square brackets can be writtenas

v 0 (s)(w k) "  k k w k 1 (1 p) # or v 0 (s)(w k) "  k w w k (1 p) #

Now, since w k(w)is increasing in w,we have

 k w w k(w) >  k w w H k(w H ) >  k w H w H k(w H ) which ispositiveif  k >w H

and is suÆciently small.

References

[1] Aghion, P. and P.Bolton,1997, ATheory of Trickle-Down Growth and

Development, Review of Economic Studies 64, pp151-172.

[2] Banerjee, A. and A. Newman, 1993, OccupationalChoice and the

Pro-cess of Economic Development, Journal of Political Economy 101, pp.

274-98.

[3] de Meza, D. and D. Webb, 1997, Wealth, Enterprise and Credit Policy,

Economic Journal 109, pp 133-65.

[4] Dixit,Avinash,(1987),TradeandInsurancewithMoralHazard,Journal

(29)

Review of Economic Studies 60, pp. 35-52.,

[6] Gertler, Mark and Kenneth Rogo , 1990, North-South Lending and

Endogenous DomesticCapitalMarketIneÆciency,Journal of Monetary

Economics 26,pp 245-266.

[7] Grossman, Gene, (1984), International Trade, Foreign Investment, and

theFormationoftheEntrepreneurialClass,AmericanEconomicReview

74(4), 605-14.

[8] Grossman, Gene, and Giovanni Maggi, (2000), Diversity and Trade,

American EconomicReview 90(5),1255-75.

[9] Hartwick, J.M. , 1999, Insuring and u 000

(y), Economics Letters 65,

205-212.

[10] Kimball,M.S.,1990,Precautionarysavinginthesmallandinthelarge,

Econometrica 58,53-73.

[11] Kanbur, S. M. , 1979, Of Risk Taking and the PersonalDistribution of

Income, Journal of Political Economy 87(4), 769-797.

[12] Kihlstrom R. E. and J.-J. La ont, 1979, A General Equilibrium

En-trepreneurial Theoryof FirmFormationBased onRiskAversion,

Jour-nal of PoliticalEconomy87(4), 719-748.

[13] Newman,A.,1995,RiskBearingandKnightianEntrepreneurship,

type-script.

[14] Rogerson, W.,1985,RepeatedMoralHazard,Econometrica 62,pp

459-465.

[15] Thiele, Henrik and Achim Wambach, 1999, Wealth E ects in the

(30)

Liste des publications au CIRANO*

Série Scientifique / Scientific Series (ISSN 1198-8177)

2001s-35

Comparaison des politiques de rémunération en fonction des stratégies

organisationnelles / Michel Tremblay, Denis Chênevert

2001s-34

Déterminants et efficacité des stratégies de rémunération : Une étude internationale

des entreprises à forte intensité technologique / Michel Tremblay, Denis Chênevert

et Bruno Sire

2001s-33

La multiplicité des ancres de carrière chez les ingénieurs québécois: impacts sur

les cheminements et le succès de carrière / Yvon Martineau, Thierry Wils et

Michel Tremblay

2001s-32

The Impact of Interface Quality on Trust in Web Retailers / Marie-Christine Roy,

Olivier Dewit et Benoit A. Aubert

2001s-31

R&D and Patents: Which Way Does the Causality Run? / Hans van Ophem, Erik

Brouwer, Alfred Kleinknecht and Pierre Mohnen

2001s-30

Contracting under Ex Post Moral Hazard and Non-Commitment / M. Martin

Boyer

2001s-29

Project Financing when the Principal Cannot Commit / M. Martin Boyer

2001s-28

Complementarities in Innovation Policy / Pierre Mohnen et Lars-Hendrick Röller

2001s-27

Bankruptcy Cost, Financial Structure and Technological Flexibility Choices /

Marcel Boyer, Armel Jacques et Michel Moreaux

2001s-26

Inflation as a Strategic Response / M. Martin Boyer et Pierre Thomas Léger

2001s-25

Simulation-Based Finite-Sample Tests for Heteroskedasticity and ARCH Effects /

Jean-Marie Dufour, Lynda Khalaf, Jean-Thomas Bernard et Ian Genest

2001s-24

The Role of Organizational Commitment and Citizenship Behaviors in

Understanding Relations between Human Resources Practices and Turnover

Intentions of IT Personnel / Guy Paré, Michel Tremblay et Patrick Lalonde

2001s-23

A Resource-Based Analysis of Outsourcing: Evidence from Case Studies / Vital

Roy et Benoit Aubert

2001s-22

Short and Long Memory in Equilibrium Interest Rate Dynamics / Jin-Chuan Duan

et Kris Jacobs

2001s-21

Unemployment Insurance and Subsequent Job Duration: Job Matching vs

Unobserved Heterogeneity / Christian Belzil

2001s-20

Estimating the Intergenerational Education Correlation from a Dynamic

Programming Model / Christian Belzil et Jörgen Hansen

2001s-19

The Bootstrap of the Mean for Dependent Heterogeneous Arrays / Sílvia

Gonçalves et Halbert White

Références

Documents relatifs

“Three cycles of aural lineage instructions” (sNyan brgyud skor gsum) by the 15 th - century yogin gTsang smyon Heruka, also known as the author of Mi la ras pa’s rnam thar

Such interval estimates take into account the uncertainty due to sampling and total nonresponse, to imprecise knowledge of the value of the parameters among a parametric class of

Short-term impatience and non family altruism are found no to affect wealth but, contrarily to recent results of behavioural analysis, the three other parameters

First, the positive relationship between inequality and volatility is obtained when individual wealth is distributed according to a Pareto distribution and agents have

In the 19th century, theories of international economic phenomena became one of the most important branches of political economy. After the marginalist revolution

When the initial conditions v i (0) are not set in line with the stationary wealths given by equation (14), a certain time is needed to redistribute the excessive wealth levels over

The maximum likelihood estimates for the parameters of the GEL-S distribution for the studied nerve data and the corresponding reached log-likelihood are presented in Tab..

Conventional diffusion term in the equation for the population density describes random motion of the individuals while the second diffusion terms corresponds to the migration of