• Aucun résultat trouvé

The present study leaves room for improvement and further research. The theoretical background section develops hypotheses around the moderating effect of resource availability on the relationship between staging on the one hand and the number of newly started and abandoned innovation projects on the other hand. Whereas our argumentation for these hypotheses evolves around the differential presence of overoptimism and managerial discretion in resource-constrained and resource-abundant firms, we were unable to incorporate these mechanisms in our main model. Although supplementary analyses of additional survey waves confirm that resource-abundant firms have higher levels of overoptimism and managerial discretion, we hope future research will be able to develop a mediated moderation model that integrates all the relevant concepts and mechanisms. These endeavors would benefit from measuring the managerial biases of the individual managers involved in innovation project decisions, and from accounting for potential differences in management quality across firms, which we were unable to observe.

Also, in our hypothesis development, we argue that there is a causal relationship between a firm’s use of staging and the number of innovation projects its initiates and abandons. We believe that a reversed causal relationship in this respect is unlikely, and the robustness tests accounting for the possibility of endogeneity that we have conducted were reassuring.

Nevertheless, our empirical findings should be replicated in other settings than the one presented here, where panel data is more readily available or, e.g., particular institutional settings give rise to natural experiments.

In response to the recent call by Ragozzino et al. (2016) to focus on firm heterogeneity in order to better connect real options theory with strategic management, we deliberately chose the firm as the unit of analysis. Our dataset is large and covers a broad section of the economy, thereby allowing to investigate firm heterogeneity (and providing a higher degree of external validity than studies which focus on a specific firm or a specific sector alone). We believe that this ability to investigate heterogeneity in resource availability and staging at the level of the firm is an important advantage of our study. However, whereas this study focuses on a firm’s resource availability as an important moderator of the relationship between staging and project decisions, other firm characteristics may also be important. In particular, future studies may consider the potential moderating effect of the firm’s human capital (D’Este et al., 2012;

Leoncini, 2016), organizational practices and culture (Danneels and Vestal, 2020), size and age (D’Este et al., 2012; Ferriani, Garnsey, and Probert, 2008), performance (Desai, 2015) and strategic objectives (Ragozzino et al., 2016), as well as the characteristics of its project portfolio (Belderbos and Zou, 2009). Moreover, while this study deliberately investigated project staging, resource availability, behavioral biases, and project decisions at the level of the firm, it would be interesting to also study this phenomenon at the level of individual projects.

Finally, there is the question whether our findings are generalizable to other domains where real options reasoning has been applied, such as entrepreneurship, joint ventures and mergers

and acquisitions, and foreign direct investment. For example, future research may want to investigate whether resource availability, cognitive biases, and internal controls also moderate the effect of staging on internationalization decisions, or whether such decisions take place more outside the firm and are therefore less prone to, for example, cognitive biases (as suggested by Adner and Levinthal, 2004, and Adner, 2007). We hope our work can be a sound basis for these further research efforts.

REFERENCES

Adner R. 2007. Real options and resource reallocation processes. In Advances in Strategic Management: Real Options, Reuer JJ, Tong TW (eds). JAI Press: Oxford, UK; 363-372.

Adner R, Levinthal DA. 2004. What is not a real option: considering boundaries for the application of real options to business strategy. Academy of Management Review 29(1): 74–85.

Aerts K, Schmidt T. 2008. Two for the price of one? Additionality effects of R&D subsidies: a comparison between Flanders and Germany. Research Policy 37: 806–822.

Ai C, Norton EC. 2003. Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics Letters 80(1):

123-129.

Alvarez SA, Barney JB. 2005. How do entrepreneurs organize firms under conditions of uncertainty? Journal of Management 31(5): 776–793.

Baker T, Miner AS, Eesley DT. 2003. Improvising firms: bricolage, account giving, and improvisational competencies in the founding process. Research Policy 32(2): 255–276.

Baker T, Nelson RE. 2005. Creating something from nothing: resource construction through entrepreneurial bricolage. Administrative Science Quarterly 50(3): 329–366.

Bazerman M. 1997. Judgment in managerial decision making (2nd ed). Wiley: New York, NY.

Belderbos R, Zou J. 2009. Real options and foreign affiliate divestments: a portfolio perspective.

Journal of International Business Studies 40: 600–620.

Biazzo S. 2009. Flexibility, structuration and simultaneity in new product development. Journal of Product Innovation Management 26: 336–353.

Block Z, MacMillan IC. 1993. Corporate Venturing. Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA.

Bowman EH, Hurry D. 1993. Strategy through the options lens: an integrated view of resource investments and the incremental-choice process. Academy of Management Review 18: 760–782.

Brown SL, Eisenhardt KM. 1997. The art of continuous change: linking complexity theory and time-paced evolution in relentlessly shifting organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly 42:

1–34.

Cameron CA, Trivedi PK. 2005. Microeconometrics: Methods and Applications. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, MA.

Cassiman B, Veugelers R. 2002. R&D cooperation and spillovers: some empirical evidence from Belgium. The American Economic Review 92(4): 1169–1184.

Chi T, McGuire DJ. 1996. Collaborative ventures and value of learning: integrating the transaction cost and strategic option perspectives on the choice of market entry modes. Journal of International Business Studies 27(2): 285–307.

Coad A, Segarra A, Teruel M. 2016. Innovation and firm growth: does firm age play a role?

Research Policy 45(2): 387–400.

Cohen WM, Levinthal DA. 1990. Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly 35(1): 128-152.

Cooper RG. 2008. Perspective: The stage-gate idea-to-launch process – update, what’s new, and NexGen systems. The Journal of Product Innovation Management 25: 213–232.

Crépon B, Duguet E, Mairesse J. 1998. Research, innovation and productivity: an econometric analysis at the firm level. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 7: 115–158.

Cyert R, March J. 1963. A behavioral theory of the firm. Prentice- Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

Czarnitzki D, Hottenrott H. 2011. Financial constraints: routine versus cutting edge R&D investment. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 20(1): 121–157.

Czarnitzki D, Toole A. 2011. Patent protection, market uncertainty, and R&D investment. The Review of Economics and Statistics 93(1): 147–159.

Danneels E, Vestal A. 2020. Normalizing vs. analyzing: drawing the lessons from failure to enhance firm innovativeness. Journal of Business Venturing 35(1): Article 105903.

Dasi A, Iborra M, Safón V. 2015. Beyond path dependence: explorative orientation, slack resources, and managerial intentionality to internationalize in SMEs. International Business Review 24(1): 77-88.

Denison CA. 2009. Real options and escalation of commitment: a behavioral analysis of capital investment decisions. The Accounting Review 84(1): 133–155.

D'Este P, Iammarino S, Savona M, von Tunzelmann N. 2012. What hampers innovation?

Revealed barriers versus deterring barriers. Research Policy 41(2): 482-488.

D’Este P, Marzucchi A, Renticchini F. 2017. Exploring and yet failing less: learning from past and current exploration in R&D. Industrial and Corporate Change 27(3): 525–553.

Desai V. 2015. Learning through the distribution of failures within an organization: evidence from heart bypass surgery performance. Academy of Management Journal 58(4): 1032-1050.

Dixit AK, Pindyck RS. 1994. Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton University Press:

Princeton, NJ.

Driouchi T, Bennett DJ. 2012. Real options in management and organizational strategy: a review of decision-making and performance implications. International Journal of Management Reviews 14: 39–62.

Du J, Leten B, Vanhaverbeke W. 2014. Managing open innovation projects with science-based and market-based partners. Research Policy 43(5): 828–840.

Dunning D, Meyerowitz JA, Holzberg AD. 1989. Ambiguity and self-evaluation: the role of idiosyncratic trait definitions in self-serving appraisals of ability. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 57: 1082–1090.

Durand R. 2003. Predicting a firm’s forecasting ability: the roles of organizational illusion of control and organizational attention. Strategic Management Journal 24: 821–838.

Ebbes P, Wedel M, Böckenholt U. 2009. Frugal IV alternatives to identify the parameter for an endogenous regressor. Journal of Applied Econometrics 24(3): 446–468.

Edmondson AC. 2011. Strategies for learning from failure. Harvard Business Review 89(3): 48-55.

Ferriani, S., Garnsey, E., Probert, D., 2008. Sustaining breakthrough innovation in large established firms: learning traps and counteracting strategies. In: Bessant, J., Venables, T. (Eds.), Creating Wealth from Knowledge: Meeting the Innovation Challenge. Edward Elgar, UK.

George G. 2005. Slack resources and the performance of privately held firms. Academy of Management Journal 48(4): 661–676.

Greene W. 2010. Testing hypotheses about interaction terms in nonlinear models. Economics Letters 107(2): 291–296.

Hauser J, Tellis GJ, Griffin A. 2006. Research on innovation: a review and agenda for marketing

science. Marketing Science 25: 687–717.

Hayward ML, Hambrick DC. 1997. Explaining premium paid for large acquisitions: evidence of CEO hubris. Administrative Science Quarterly 42(1): 103–127.

Hilbe JM. 2014. Modeling Count Data. Cambridge University Press: New York, NY.

Hottenrott H, Lopes-Bento C. 2014. (International) R&D collaboration and SMEs: The effectiveness of targeted public R&D support schemes. Research Policy 43(6): 1055–1066.

Jensen MC, Meckling, WH. 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3(4): 305-360.

Julian, SD and Ofori-Dankwa, JC. 2013. Financial resource availability and corporate social responsibility expenditures in a sub-Saharan economy: the institutional difference hypothesis.

Strategic Management Journal 34(11): 1314-1330.

Kahneman D, Tversky A. 2000. Choices, values and frames. Cambridge University Press: New York, NY.

Keupp, MM and Gassman, O. 2013. Resource constraints as triggers of radical innovation:

longitudinal evidence from the manufacturing sector. Research Policy 42(8): 1457– 1468.

King G. 1989. S seemingly unrelated poisson regression model. Sociological Methods and Research 17: 235–255.

Klingebiel R, Adner R. 2015. Real options logic revisited: The performance effects of alternative resource allocation regimes. Academy of Management Journal 58(1): 221–241.

Klingebiel R, Rammer C. 2014. Resource allocation strategy for innovation portfolio management. Strategic Management Journal 35: 246–268.

Kogut B, Kulatilaka N. 1994. Options thinking and platform investments: investing in opportunity. California Management Review 36: 52–71.

Laursen K, Salter A. 2006. Open for innovation: The role of openness in explaining innovation performance among UK manufacturing firms. Strategic Management Journal 27(2): 131–150.

Leiponen A, Helfat CE. 2010. Innovation objectives, knowledge sources, and the benefit of breadth. Strategic Management Journal 31: 224–236.

Leiponen A, Helfat CE. 2011. Location, decentralization, and knowledge sources for innovation.

Organization Science 22(3): 641–658.

Leoncini R. 2016. Learning-by-failing. An empirical exercise on CIS data. Research Policy 45(2): 376-386.

Lewbel A. 2012. Using heteroskedasticity to identify and estimate mismeasured and endogenous regressor models. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 30(1): 67–80.

Lewbel A. 2018. Identification and estimation using heteroskedasticity without instruments: the binary endogenous regressor case. Economics Letters 165: 10–12.

Li Y, James BE, Madhavan R, Mahoney JT. 2007. Real options: taking stock and looking ahead.

In Real Options Theory (Advances in Strategic Management, Volume 24), Reuer JJ, Tong TW (eds). Emerald Group Publishing Limited. 31–66.

Loch C. 2000. Tailoring product development to strategy: case of a European technology manufacturer. European Management Journal 18(6): 246–258.

Majd S, Myers SC. 1990. Abandonment value and project life. Advances in Futures and Options Research 4: 1–21.

McGrath RG. 1997. A real options logic for initiating technology positioning investments. The Academy of Management Review 22(4): 974–996.McGrath, RG. 1999. Falling forward: real options reasoning and entrepreneurial failure. Academy of Management Review 24(1): 13–30.

McGrath RG, Nerkar A. 2004. Real options reasoning and a new look at the R&D investment

strategies of pharmaceutical firms. Strategic Management Journal 25: 1–21.

Miller KD, Arikan AT. 2004. Technology search investments: evolutionary, option reasoning, and option pricing approaches. Strategic Management Journal 25: 473–485.

Miller KD. and Friesen P. 1983. Strategy-making and environment: the third link. Strategic Management Journal 4: 221-235.

Miller KD, Shapira Z. 2004. An empirical test of heuristics and biases affecting real option valuation. Strategic Management Journal 25: 269–284.

Nisbett R, Ross L. 1980. Human inference: Strategies and shortcomings of human judgment.

Prentice-Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ.

OECD. 2005. Oslo Manual: Guidelines for Collecting and Interpreting Innovation Data. 3rd edn. OECD: Paris.

Pellegrino G, Savona M. 2017. No money, no honey? Financial versus knowledge and demand constraints on innovation. Research Policy 46(2): 510-521.

Peters B, Rammer C. 2013. Innovation panel surveys in Germany. Gault F, ed. Handbook of Innovation Indicators and Measurement (Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK), 135–177.

Phillips W, Noke H, Bessant J, Lamming R. 2006. Beyond the steady state: managing discontinuous product and process innovation. International Journal of Innovation Management 10(2): 175–196.

Powell TC, Lovallo D, Caringal, C. 2006. Causal ambiguity, management perception, and firm performance. The Academy of Management Review 31(1): 175–196.

Prahalad CK, Bettis R. 1986. The dominant logic: a new linkage between diversity and performance. Strategic Management Journal 7(6): 485–502.

Ragozzino R, Reuer JJ, Trigeorgis L. 2016. Real options in strategy and finance: current gaps

and future linkages. Academy of Management Perspectives 30(4): 428–440.

Reymen I, Andries P, Berends H, Mauer R, Stephan U, van Burg E. 2015. Understanding dynamics of strategic decision making in venture creation: A process study of effectuation and causation. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 9(4): 351-379.

Ries, E. 2011. The lean startup: How today's entrepreneurs use continuous innovation to create radically successful businesses. New York: Crown Business.

Rivoli P, Salorio E. 1996. Foreign direct investment and investment under uncertainty. Journal of International Business Studies 27(2): 335–357.

Ross J, Staw B. 1993. Organizational escalation and exit: Lessons from the Shoreham nuclear plant. Academy of Management Journal 36: 701–732.

Rumelt RP, Schendel DE, Teece DJ. 1994. Fundamental issues in strategy: a research agenda.

Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA.

Sarasvathy SD. 2001. Causation and effectuation: toward a theoretical shift from economic inevitability to entrepreneurial contingency. Academy of Management Review 26(2): 243–263.

Schumpeter J. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper & Row: New York.

Simsek Z, Veiga JF, Lubatkin MH. 2007. The impact of managerial environmental perceptions on corporate entrepreneurship: towards understanding discretionary slack's pivotal role. Journal of Management Studies 44(8): 1398-1424.

Sutcliffe KM, Huber GP. 1998. Firm and industry as determinants of executive perceptions of the environment. Strategic Management Journal 19(8): 793–807.

Tong TW, Reuer JJ. 2006. Firm and industry influences on the value of growth options.

Strategic Organization 4(1): 71–95.

Tong TW, Reuer JJ. 2007. Real options in strategic management. In Advances in Strategic

Management: Real Options, Reuer JJ, Tong TW (eds). JAI Press: Oxford, UK; 3–28.

Van Yperen NW. 1992. Self-enhancement among major league soccer players: the role of importance and ambiguity on social-comparison behavior. Journal of Applied Social Psychology 22: 1186–1198.

Veugelers R, Cassiman B. 1999. Make and buy in innovation strategies: evidence from Belgian manufacturing firms. Research Policy 28: 63–80.

Winkelmann R. 2000. Seemingly unrelated negative binomial regression. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 62(4): 553–560.

Wood RE, Bandura B. 1989. Social cognitive theory of organizational management. Academy of Management Review 14(2): 361–384.

APPENDIX

In this section, we formally prove the existence of a “value in learning” and “value in abandoning” in a mathematical real options model, which provides the full-rationality benchmark on which we base our hypothesis development in Section 2.2. Consider a firm contemplating to invest in an innovation project. The total sunk costs, I>0 , can be split up in

S discrete stages, indexed by s . Each stage costs a fraction of I , i.e., I=

s S

is , and takes one period to complete. Until completion of all stages the innovation project creates no cash-flow. Its expected value is denoted by V and follows the stochastic process

Vs=Vs−1+ɛs , (1)

with E

[

ɛs

]

=0. After incurring is the random variable ɛs is realized and becomes known to the firm.12 Consequently, uncertainty resolution is endogenous in this model and contingent on the investment behavior of a firm (McGrath, 1997; Tong and Reuer, 2007).13 The firm has either the possibility to invest sequentially (staging) and make subsequent investments contingent on the realization of ɛ , or it can decide to complete all stages at once (non-staging). In this case,

s S

ɛs is realized at once at the end of period S (i.e., we assume away time advantages in project completion due to non-staging).

Consider the case of V following a continuous-state random walk and two stages required for completion, S=2 . Let total costs be I=i1+i2=α ∙ I+(1−α)∙ I with α∈(0,1) . The project’s value is initially normalized to zero, V0=0. We assume risk-neutrality, no discounting of future profits, and standard normal profitability shocks, ɛs N(0,1) . Because the sum of normal random variables is normal again, it follows from equation (1) that

VS=V0+

s=1 S

ɛs N(V0, S) .

If VS turns out to be negative in the final period S , both staging and non-staging firms can drop the project such that no negative cash-flows are realized. Therefore, as projects with negative ex-post value are abandoned, a firm considers the distribution of V2 truncated at zero. For a non-staging firm, the decision to invest in a project at time 0 is then given by the net present value investment rule,

12 After stage 𝓢 all uncertainty about the project’s value is resolved. Stages cannot be completed in arbitrary order but have to follow the natural order of 1,2, …S . This captures the fact that, e.g., a market acceptance test usually comes after the prototyping stage and not vice versa.

13 Endogenous uncertainty resolution is a novel feature of our model compared to other approaches in the literature, since the random variable of project value moves independently of firms’ actions in standard real options models (Dixit and Pindyck, 1994). We think that this assumption better captures the context of innovation project staging, where firms do not gain any further information if they decide to kill or stall a project indefinitely at a certain stage.

V2

πnon−stage=E¿ | V20¿−I>0 , (2)

with V2

E¿ | V20¿ being the mean of a truncated normal distribution.14

By contrast, a staging firm will decide to abandon a project already after the first stage if the realization of V1 is too low, such that the expected profit of follow-on investment is negative:

V2

E¿ | V20,V1¿−(1−α)× I ≤0 . (3) This assumption captures the go-versus-kill decision – or “gate” – a project has to pass at every stage (Cooper, 2008). If we denote the value of V1 for which the above equation holds with equality by v1 , then the expected profit under staging is given by

V2

πstage=

(

1−ϕ

(

v1

) )

×{E¿ | V20,V1>v1¿ – I } + ϕ

(

v1

)

×(−αI) (4)

with ϕ(∙) being the standard normal cumulative distribution function (of the per-period project value increment εs¿ . The first summand on the right-hand side represents the case when follow-on investment is optimal; whereas the second summand is the loss that a staging firm incurs if it abandons a project after stage one.

We can now prove that – all else equal – staging firms will start more new innovation projects than non-staging firms. This will hold if the expected (a priori) profit of a single innovation project is weakly larger under staging than under non-staging. We hence need to show that

(

1−ϕ

(

v1

) )

× I−ϕ

(

v1

)

× I

The second line follows from rearranging and expanding the terms on the right-hand side. The third line follows from eliminating terms that appear on both sides. Finally, the last line follows from gathering all terms containing I on the left and dividing by ϕ

(

v1

)

.

The last inequality of equation (5) holds by construction, given how v1 has been defined in light of condition (3). Thus, expected profits of a project are larger under staging than if total investment costs are incurred upfront (for a given distribution of project costs I ). This, in turn implies that firms which stage (some of) their innovation projects will start more new innovation projects than firms that commit all investments upfront. This completes the proof.

We can also demonstrate that, in this model, firms which stage (some of) their innovation projects will abandon more projects than staging firms. Recall that both staging and non-staging firms abandon projects that turn out to have a negative value after all uncertainty is resolved, i.e., if V20 . To prove that staging firms have a higher propensity to abandon projects than non-staging firms, it suffices to show that there are projects with positive V2 (i.e., that are not abandoned by non-staging firms), but which nonetheless fulfill the condition for abandonment by staging firms in (3):

V2

E¿ | V20,V1¿−(1−α)× I ≤0 .

A staging firm will abandon these projects after the first stage, whereas a non-staging firm will complete them, as total project costs I are sunk and the projects’ return is positive.

Recall that v1 was defined as the value of V1 for which (3) holds with equality. Thus, for V1=v1−ε , with ε>0 being arbitrarily small, the left-hand side of (3) will be smaller and staging firms will thus abandon the project. However, even for V1=v1−ε , there is a strictly positive probability that V2 turns out to be positive:

Pr

(

V2>0

|

V1=v1ε¿=1−Pr

(

V2≤0

|

V1=v1ε¿>0.

The last inequality follows from the fact that the normal distribution has positive probability mass over the entire range of R , so that Pr

(

V20

|

V1=v1ε¿ is never exactly equal to one. Consequently, we have shown that there is a positive probability for projects to occur that would be abandoned by a staging firm but completed by a non-staging firm. At the same time, all projects that are abandoned by a non-staging firm are also abandoned by a staging firm. This completes the proof that staging firms will abandon more projects than non-staging firms.

Having demonstrated the value in learning and abandoning under full rationality, we can now

Having demonstrated the value in learning and abandoning under full rationality, we can now

Documents relatifs