• Aucun résultat trouvé

Conditional Markov chains and credit risk in the L´evy Libor model

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Partager "Conditional Markov chains and credit risk in the L´evy Libor model"

Copied!
26
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

Conditional Markov chains and credit risk in the L´evy Libor model

Zorana Grbac Universit ´e d’ ´Evry Val d’Essonne

Joint work with Ernst Eberlein

Colloque des jeunes probabilistes et statisticiens CIRM Marseille, 16-20 Avril 2012

(2)

I. Libor models and credit risk – main problems and tools

(3)

Short overview

In mathematical finance defaultable interest rate models are often obtained by adding the defaultable term structure to the existing default-free term structure models in an appropriate way

Various defaultable extensions of the Heath–Jarrow–Morton (HJM) modeling methodology are found in the literature, whereas credit risk in Libor market models isfar less studied(only papers by Lotz and Schl ¨ogl (2000), Sch ¨onbucher (2000), Eberlein, Kluge, and Sch ¨onbucher (2006), a series of papers by Brigo (2005, 2006, 2008), Li and Rutkowski (2010))

None of the existing defaultable Libor market models incorporatesratingsand credit migration

(4)

Libor market models – notation

Discrete tenor structure: 0=T0<T1< . . . <Tn=T, withδk =Tk+1−Tk

T0 T1 T2 T3 Tn−1 Tn=T

Default-freezero coupon bonds:B(·,T1), . . . ,B(·,Tn)

Forward Libor rateat timet≤Tk for the accrual period[Tk,Tk+1] L(t,Tk) = 1

δk

B(t,Tk) B(t,Tk+1)−1

(5)

Libor market models – notation

Discrete tenor structure: 0=T0<T1< . . . <Tn=T, withδk =Tk+1−Tk

T0 T1 T2 t T3 Tk Tk+1 Tn−1 Tn=T

Default-freezero coupon bonds:B(·,T1), . . . ,B(·,Tn)

Forward Libor rateat timet≤Tk for the accrual period[Tk,Tk+1] L(t,Tk) = 1

δk

B(t,Tk) B(t,Tk+1)−1

(6)

Libor market models – notation

Discrete tenor structure: 0=T0<T1< . . . <Tn=T, withδk =Tk+1−Tk

T0 T1 T2 t T3 Tk Tk+1 Tn−1 Tn=T

Defaultablezero coupon bonds:BC(·,T1), . . . ,BC(·,Tn)

Defaultableforward Libor rate at timet≤Tkfor the accrual period[Tk,Tk+1], defined on the set{τ >t}

LC(t,Tk) = 1 δk

BC(t,Tk) BC(t,Tk+1)−1

(7)

Defaultable bonds with ratings

Credit ratingsidentified with elements of a finite setK={1,2, . . . ,K}, where 1 is the best possible rating andK is the default event

Credit migrationis modeled by aconditional Markov chainCwith state spaceK, whereK is the absorbing state

Default timeτ:the first time whenCreaches stateK, i.e.

τ=inf{t>0:Ct =K}

Defaultable bonds with credit migration processCand fractional recovery of Treasury valueq= (q1, . . . ,qK−1)upon default:

BC(t,Tk) =

K−1

X

i=1

Bi(t,Tk)1{Ct=i}+qCτ−B(t,Tk)1{Ct=K}

(8)

Rating-dependent Libor rates

Theforward Libor rate for credit rating classi Li(t,Tk) := 1

δk

Bi(t,Tk) Bi(t,Tk+1)−1

, i=1,2, . . . ,K−1 We putL0(t,Tk) :=L(t,Tk)(default-free Libor rates).

The correspondingdiscrete-tenor forward inter-rating spreads Hi(t,Tk) := Li(t,Tk)−Li−1(t,Tk)

1+δkLi−1(t,Tk)

(9)

Libor modeling

Modeling underforward martingale measures, i.e. risk-neutral measures that use zero-coupon bonds as numeraires

On a given stochastic basis, construct a family of Libor ratesL(·,Tk)and a collection of mutually equivalent probability measuresQTk such that

B(t,Tj) B(t,Tk)

0≤t≤Tk∧Tj

areQTk-local martingales

In addition model defaultable Libor ratesLC(·,Tk)such that BC(t,Tj)

B(t,Tk)

0≤t≤Tk∧Tj

areQTk-local martingales

(10)

Risk-free Libor models

Let(Ω,FT,F= (Ft)0≤t≤T,PT)be a complete stochastic basis.

As driving process take any special semimartingaleX, which satisfies certain integrability conditions and has canonical decomposition

Xt = Zt

0

bsds+ Z t

0

√csdWsT+ Z t

0

Z

Rd

x(µ−νT)(ds,dx),

WTdenotes aPT-standard Brownian motion and

µis the random measure of jumps ofXwithPT-compensatorνT We assumeb=0.

(11)

Construction of Libor rates (backward induction)

General step:for eachTk

(i) Define the forward measurePTk+1via dPTk+1

dPT Ft

=

n−1

Y

l=k+1

1+δlL(t,Tl)

1+δlL(0,Tl) = B(0,T) B(0,Tk+1)

B(t,Tk+1) B(t,T) .

(ii) The dynamics of the Libor rateL(·,Tk)under this measure L(t,Tk) =L(0,Tk)exp

Z t

0

bL(s,Tk)ds+ Z t

0

σ(s,Tk)dXsTk+1

, (1)

where

XtTk+1= Z t

0

√csdWsTk+1+ Z t

0

Z

Rd

x(µ−νTk+1)(ds,dx) withPTk+1-Brownian motionWTk+1and

νTk+1(ds,dx) =

n−1

Y

l=k+1

δlL(s−,Tl)

1+δlL(s−,Tl)(ehσ(s,Tl),xi−1) +1

νT(ds,dx).

The drift termbL(s,Tk)is chosen such that L(·,Tk)becomes aPTk+1-martingale.

(12)

The backward induction construction was first proposed in Musiela and Rutkowski (1997)

The forward bond price processes B(t,Tj)

B(t,Tk)

0≤t≤Tj∧Tk

are martingales under the forward measurePTk associated with the dateTk by construction (for allj,k=1, . . . ,n).

The arbitrage-free price at timetof a contingent claim with payoffXat maturity TkXt , is given by

πtX=B(t,Tk)EPTk[X|Ft].

(13)

II. Rating based L ´evy Libor model

(14)

Adding credit risk to the L´evy Libor model

Take driving processX to betime-inhomogeneous L ´evy process(independent, but not stationary increments) with triplet(0,c,FT)

⇒L ´evy Libor model (Eberlein and ¨Ozkan (2005)) Enlarge probability space:(Ω,F,PT)→(Ω,e G,QT)

and construct the credit migration processCas a conditional Markov chain with stochastic,F-adaptedinfinitesimal generator[λij(t)]i,j=1,...,K

(canonical construction, Bielecki and Rutkowski (2002))

The processCis aconditional Markov chainrelative toF, i.e. for every 0≤t≤s and any functionh:K →R

EQT[h(Cs)|Ft∨ FtC] =EQT[h(Cs)|Ft∨σ(Ct)],

whereFC= (FtC)denotes the filtration generated byC

The enlarged filtration(Gt :=Ft∨ FtC)0≤t≤Tsatisfies the (H)-hypothesis (canonical construction + Br ´emaud and Yor (1978) or Elliot, Jeanblanc and Yor (2000))

(15)

Consequences:

X remainsa time-inhomogeneous L ´evy process with respect toQTandGwith thesamecharacteristics

Define on this space theforward measuresQTk by:

for each tenor dateTkQTk is obtained fromQTin the same way asPTk from PT(k=1, . . . ,n−1)

Then

dQTk

dQT

k, whereψk isFTk-measurable.

(16)

Conditional Markov chain C under forward measures

Theorem

Let C be a canonically constructed conditional Markov chain with respect toQT. Then C is a conditional Markov chain with respect to every forward measureQTk and

pijQTk(t,s) =pQijT(t,s)

i.e. the matrices of transition probabilities underQTandQTkare the same.

Theorem

The(H)-hypothesis holds under allQTk, i.e. every(F,QTk)-local martingale is a (G,QTk)-local martingale.

(17)

Recall that the Libor rate for the ratingican be expressed as 1+δkLi(t,Tk) = (1+δkLi−1(t,Tk))(1+δkHi(t,Tk))

=(1+δkL(t,Tk))

| {z }

default-free Libor i

Y

j=1

(1+δkHj(t,Tk))

| {z }

spreadj−1→j

Hence:modelHj(·,Tk)as exponential semimartingales and thus ensure automatically themonotonicityof Libor rates w.r.t. the credit rating:

L(t,Tk)≤L1(t,Tk)≤ · · · ≤LK−1(t,Tk)

=⇒worse credit rating, higher interest rate

(18)

Introduction Interest rate and credit risk markets

Credit spreads

Maturities in years

Interest rate

0 2 4 6 8 10

0.00.050.100.150.20

Aaa Caa

B3

B2 B1

Ba3 Ba2 Ba1 Baa3 Baa1 A1

Government−Bond

Euro Corporate Spreads (Banking sector); Dec. 20, 2002

1

Figure: Term structure of Euro corporate spreads, Dec 20 2002

4 / 45

(19)

Pre-default term structure of rating-dependent Libor rates

For each ratingiand tenor dateTkwe modelHi(·,Tk)as Hi(t,Tk) =Hi(0,Tk)exp

Z t

0

bHi(s,Tk)ds+ Z t

0

γi(s,Tk)dXsTk+1

(2) with initial condition

Hi(0,Tk) = 1 δk

Bi(0,Tk)Bi−1(0,Tk+1) Bi−1(0,Tk)Bi(0,Tk+1)−1

.

XTk+1 is defined as earlier andbHi(s,Tk)is the drift term (we assumebHi(s,Tk) =0, fors>Tk ⇒Hi(t,Tk) =Hi(Tk,Tk), fort≥Tk).

⇒the forward Libor rateLi(·,Tk)is obtained from relation 1+δkLi(t,Tk)=(1+δkL(t,Tk))

i

Y

j=1

(1+δkHj(t,Tk)).

(20)

Theorem

Assume that L(·,Tk)and Hi(·,Tk)are given by (1) and (2). Then:

(a) The rating-dependent forward Libor rates satisfy for every Tk and t≤Tk

L(t,Tk)≤L1(t,Tk)≤ · · · ≤LK−1(t,Tk), i.e. Libor rates are monotone with respect to credit ratings.

(b) The dynamics of the Libor rate Li(·,Tk)underPTk+1is given by Li(t,Tk) = Li(0,Tk)exp

Z t

0

bLi(s,Tk)ds+ Z t

0

√csσi(s,Tk)dWsTk+1

+ Z t

0

Z

Rd

Si(s,x,Tk)(µ−νTk+1)(ds,dx)

.

(21)

L(t,Tn−1)

//Li−1(t,Tn−1)

Hi(t,Tn−1)

//Li(t,Tn−1)

L(t,Tk)

//Li−1(t,Tk)

Hi(t,Tk) //Li(t,Tk)

L(t,Tk−1)

//Li−1(t,Tk−1)

Hi(t,Tk−1)

//Li(t,Tk−1)

L(t,T1) //Li−1(t,T1) Hi(t,T1) //Li(t,T1)

Default-free Ratingi−1 Ratingi

Figure: Connection between subsequent Libor rates

(22)

No-arbitrage condition for the rating based model

Recall the defaultable bond price process with fractional recovery of Treasury valueq BC(t,Tk) =

K−1

X

i=1

Bi(t,Tk)1{Ct=i}+qCτB(t,Tk)1{Ct=K}.

Note: the forward bond price process

BC(·,Tk) B(·,Tj) is aQTj-local martingalefor everyk,j=1, . . . ,n−1

(23)

No-arbitrage condition for the rating based model

Recall the defaultable bond price process with fractional recovery of Treasury valueq BC(t,Tk) =

K−1

X

i=1

Bi(t,Tk)1{Ct=i}+qCτB(t,Tk)1{Ct=K}.

iff the forward bond price process BC(·,Tk)

B(·,Tj) = BC(·,Tk) B(·,Tk)

B(·,Tk) B(·,Tj)

| {z }

dQTk dQTj

is aQTk-local martingalefor everyk=1, . . . ,n−1.

(24)

No-arbitrage condition

Theorem

Let Tk be a tenor date. Assume that the processes Hj(·,Tk), j=1, . . . ,K−1, are given by (2). Then the process BB(·,TC(·,Tk)

k) is a local martingale with respect to the forward measureQTk and filtrationGiff:

for almost all t ≤Tkon the set{Ct 6=K} bH(t,Tk,Ct) +λCt(t) = 1−qCt e

Rt 0λCt(s)ds

H(t−,Tk,Ct)

!

λCtK(t) (3)

+

K−1

X

j=1,j6=Ct

1− H(t−,Tk,j)eR0tλj(s)ds H(t−,Tk,Ct)e

Rt 0λCt(s)ds

! λCtj(t).

Sketch of the proof:Use the fact that the jump times of the conditional Markov chain Cdo not coincide with the jumps of anyF-adapted semimartingale, use martingales related to the indicator processes1{Ct=i},i∈ K, and stochastic calculus for

semimartingales.

(25)

Pricing and defaultable forward measures

Defaultable forward measureQC,Tkfor the dateTk is defined on(Ω,GTk)by dQC,Tk

dQTk

Gt

:= B(0,Tk) BC(0,Tk)

BC(t,Tk) B(t,Tk)

This corresponds to the choice ofBC(·,Tk)as a numeraire.

Defaultable Libor rates aremartingaleswrt corresponding defaultable forward measures

Pricing formulae for defaultable bonds, credit default swaps, caps/floors on the defaultable Libor rates (under defaultable forward measures)

(26)

The talk is based on:

E. Eberlein and Z. Grbac (2010). Rating-based L ´evy Libor model. To appear in Mathematical Finance.

Références

Documents relatifs

keywords: Value-at-Risk; Conditional Value-at-Risk; Economic Capital; Credit Risk; Gauss hypergeometric function; Beta-Kotz distribution..

Using both the Wiener chaos expansion on the systemic economic factor and a Gaussian ap- proximation on the associated truncated loss, we significantly reduce the computational

Dans ce chapitre, nous étudions empiriquement le lien entre les fondamentaux macroéconomiques et le risque de crédit souverain pour certains pays de la Zone euro, à savoir:

stochastic risk-free interest rate (Longstaff and Schwartz, 1992); connection of debt value to firm risk, taxes, bankruptcy cost and bond covenants (Le- land, 1994); valuation of

Section 1 and 2 provide a detailed derivation of the hedging portfolio in a pure jump dynamics for the risky bond, whereas Section 3 deals with the more realistic case of a

Comvariance was first introduced to economics by Deardorff (1982), who used this measurement to correlate three factors in international trading. Furthermore, we

Key Words: LIBOR Market Model, lattice model, tree model, shifted forward measure, drift approximation, risk management, calibration, callable exotics, callable bond,

Key words: bilateral defaultable derivatives, credit asymmetry, market models, Black model, LIBOR market model, reduced-form model, credit valuation adjustment,