• Aucun résultat trouvé

A planet without farmers? Food production, inclusive development and ecology: Historical evidences for a new deal

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "A planet without farmers? Food production, inclusive development and ecology: Historical evidences for a new deal"

Copied!
1
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

A Planet without

A Planet without Farmers?

Farmers?

Food Production, Inclusive Development and Ecology:

Food Production, Inclusive Development and Ecology:

Historical Evidences for a New Deal

Historical Evidences for a New Deal

The structural transformation

The structural transformation

Lewis path

Lewis path vs.

vs. Lewis trap

Lewis trap

Bruno DORIN

Bruno DORIN

1,21,2

& Jean

& Jean--Charles HOURCADE

Charles HOURCADE

22

1

1Centre International de Recherche Agronomique pour le Développement, 34398 Montpellier, FranceCentre International de Recherche Agronomique pour le Développement, 34398 Montpellier, France 2

2Centre International de Recherches sur l'Environnement et le Developpement, 94736 NogentCentre International de Recherches sur l'Environnement et le Developpement, 94736 Nogent--sursur--Marne, FranceMarne, France

There is an apparent disagreement between:

the “ecological critique” that accuses “modern agriculture” of jeopardizing many ecological services through monocultures and the overuse of freshwater, fossil energy and other industrial inputs such as chemical fertilizers and pesticides

the “techno-productivist approach” that led economists to recommend, after the 2007-08 food crisis, to “revitalize agricultural R&D investments” (Alston et al., 2009)so that agriculture plays “its role as an engine of growth” (FAO, 2009).

This poster provides materials to discuss the direction of future R&D efforts.

Ecology

Ecology vs.

vs. Poverty?

Poverty?

The direction of the effort could rest on the “structural transformation” paradigm that dominated development economics after World War II (Chenery & Srinivasan, 1988).

Only OECD and transition countries followed a “Lewis path” leading to a “world without agriculture”, while the greater part of humanity is falling into a “Lewis trap”.

Lewis path Farmers-excluding

path Farmers-inclusive

path Lewis trap

Labour income convergence between agriculture and others sectors

A g ri cu lt u ra l w o rkf o rce We identified four pathways of agricultural structural transformation Population (heads) Workforce (workers) Economic growth (1990-US$) Labour productivity (1990-US$) Income convergence

Total Total Agriculture Total Agriculture Total Agriculture S1 / S2

OECD 0.69% 1.11% –2.93% 2.81% 1.40% 1.68% 4.46% 2.75% TRAN 0.38% 0.38% –1.96% 1.91% 1.07% 1.50% 3.07% 1.67% LAC 1.89% 2.92% 0.30% 3.50% 3.03% 0.56% 2.73% 2.21% MENA 2.44% 3.00% 0.67% 4.10% 3.07% 1.08% 2.40% 1.36% SSA 2.75% 2.80% 2.05% 3.28% 3.09% 0.46% 1.01% 0.55% ASIA 1.75% 2.14% 1.40% 6.76% 3.69% 4.53% 2.27% –2.16% 1 9 7 0 -2 0 0 7 a v e ra g e a n n u a l g ro w th r a te s

Contact: bruno.dorin@cirad.fr

Contact: bruno.dorin@cirad.fr

A silent bifurcation

A silent bifurcation

Towards a new deal?

Towards a new deal?

This paradigm is anchored in historical experiences of “modern economic growth”

(Kuznets, 1966) and dual-economy theories of interrelated structural changes between the “traditional” (agriculture) and “modern” (non-agriculture) sectors (Lewis, 1954). In these models, high-yielding agriculture provides low-cost food and labour to the process of industrialization and urbanization which, in turn, raises labour productivity and wages of remaining farmers

until a “world without agriculture”

(Timmer, 2009)with a 2-3% share

of agriculture in GDP & workforce. The figure shows:

(x-axis)total value-added per

capita (GDP p.c. in 1990-US$ / day) of all countries from 1970 to 2007 and (y-axis)the respective:

share of agriculture in total value-added (S1) share of agriculture in total employment (S2) S1 – S2 (Timmer, 2009).

There is a growing gap between farmers who can expand their land and use moto-rized machineries to increase their labour productivity (incomes), and those who can’t. Farm labour productivity can be increased through:

“Intensification” (with irrigation, fertilizers, HYV, pesticides, etc.) to get higher yields per hectare “Motorization” (with tractors, combine harvesters, aeroplanes, etc.) to crop more land per farmer.

To follow a “Lewis path”, labour productivity in agriculture must grow faster than in other sectors and faster than the food demand.

Otherwise, when the absorption of labour from other sectors is insufficient to allow per farmer land acreage to increase and motorization to develop:

urban poverty grows fast as in North Africa poverty is trapped in rural areas as in Asia.

The “Lewis trap” is also an “ecological trap”: in the current system of prices and incentives, when land acreage per farmer can’t increase, farmers have no other choice but to overexploit natural resources (soil, water…) (Dorin, 2009).

ASIA 1.75% 2.14% 1.40% 6.76% 3.69% 4.53% 2.27% –2.16% - South 2.13% 2.28% 1.49% 5.17% 2.76% 2.82% 1.25% –1.56% - East 1.49% 2.07% 1.35% 7.61% 4.38% 5.44% 3.00% –2.31% World 1.61% 1.95% 1.18% 3.10% 2.25% 1.13% 1.06% –0.07% 1 9 7 0 a v e ra g e a n n u a l g ro w th r a te s

A “world without agriculture”

-80% -60% -40% -20% 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% 0 1 10 100 GDP p.c. (1990 US$) Share

is not possible without mass-migration and mega-urbanization is costly: food & social safety nets for poor urban dwellers won’t solve the huge asymmetry with large-scale motorized agricultures (our “Lewis path”

scenario for India: ≈5 ha/farmer in

2050 with 1.3 billion city-dwellers). in populous developing countries in industrialized countries

is costly: the “protection problem” of high-income economies (T. Shultz, 1953) is less competitive: few agro-food complexes with oligopolistic positions

is less efficient: agriculture is normally subject to diseconomies of scale (Binswanger et al., 2010; Wiggins et al., 2010)

is less resilient to economic & climatic shocks: productions are concentrated on few products in few regions.

We need a paradigm shift.

La n d p ro d u ct iv it y Q/A Q/La Labour productivity (isocurves) In te n si fi ca ti o n Inco me La n d p ro d u ct iv it y Q/A Q/La Labour productivity (isocurves) In te n si fi ca ti o n Inco me

References

References

Alston J.M., Beddow J.M., Pardey P.G., 2009. Agricultural Research, Productivity, and Food Prices in the Long Run. Science, 325, pp. 1209-1210

Binswanger-Mkhize H.P., McCalla A.F., Patel P., 2010. Structural Transformation and African Agriculture. Global Journal of Emerging Market Economies, 2, pp. 113-152

Chenery H., Srinivasan T.N., 1988. Handbook of Development Economics, Volume 1, Part 2: Structural Transformation. Elsevier, Eastbourne, pp. 197-465

Dorin B., Landy F., 2009. Agriculture and Food in India, a Half-Century Review. Manohar, New Delhi, 280 p. FAO, 2009. The State of Food Insecurity in the World. Economic crises, impacts and lessons learned. Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations, Rome, 61 p.

FAO, 2010. FAOSTAT, Internet web portal and database. Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations, Rome

Kuznets S., 1966. Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure and Spread. Yale University Press, New Haven and London, 529 p.

Lewis W.A., 1954. Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour. Manchester School of Economic and Socal Studies, 22, pp. 139-191

Schultz T., 1953. Economic Organization of Agriculture. McGraw Hill, New York, 374 p.

Timmer C.P., 2009. A World without Agriculture. The Structural Transformation in Historical Perspective. The American Enterprise Institute, Washington D.C., 96 p.

UNSTAT, 2010. National Accounts Main Aggregate Database. United Nations, Statistical Division Wiggins S., Kirsten J., Llambi L., 2010. The Future of Small Farms. World Development, 38, pp. 1341-1348.

aeroplanes, etc.) to crop more land per farmer. The TALA identity: Q / A A / La= Q / La

A novel consolidation of existing data: from FAO (2010), we converted & aggregated in kilocalories (kcal)all plant food harvested during a year (one crop or more), in almost all countries of the world and over a 47-year period (1961-2007).

We show that levels and growths of labour productivity (kcal/worker)are strongly driven par motorization (ha/farmer), not by yields (kcal/ha).

Technology (yield) Affluence (of land) Labour productivity TRAN OECD LAC MENA World SSA ASIA 0 5,000 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000 30,000 35,000 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 12,500 50,000 25,000 100,000 6,250 800,000 kcal.worker-1.day-1 Yield (kcal.ha-1.day-1 of plant food)

Acreage per farmer

(ha.worker-1) 400,000 kcal.worker-1.day-1 200,000 kcal.worker-1.day-1 Food productivity pathways (1961-2007)

R&D policies should help to increase production (Q) and farmers’ wealth (θa) without downsizing in large proportions their number (La):

a a na a=(pQY )/L

θ

In this labour-intensive agriculture, some agricultural inputs from the non-agricultural sector ( ) are saved for economic and ecological reasons, while prices paid to producers (p) are increased with the co-delivery of ecological and social services.

a na

Y

A 2050 vision: science & farmers managing a mosaic of agro-ecosystems boosting local synergies amongst many plant and animal species above & below ground.

© C ir a d , U m r C ir ed : B ru n o D O R IN , M a rc h 2 0 12 La n d p ro d u ct iv it y A/La Land affluence Motorization In te n si fi ca ti o n La n d p ro d u ct iv it y A/La Land affluence Motorization In te n si fi ca ti o n

Références

Documents relatifs

Coût d’un système électrique optimal sans émissions de CO2 pour la France, avec et sans nucléaire Centre international de recherche sur l’environnement et

La présente invention concerne un récipient pour la culture in vitro de matériel végétal, par immersion temporaire, lequel récipient (1 ) comprend, d'une part, une chambre

Cela concerne encore plus les produit horticoles d’exportation , vers lesquels on s’oriente aujourd’hui, qu’ils soient maraîchers ou fruitiers : cf l’expérience en cours

Fiche détaillée existante, soumise au PDIAIM (« Recherche / Développement pour la diversification des systèmes de production agricole irriguée dans la vallée et le delta du fleuve

Pression foncière et stratégies paysannes dans la zone ouest du Burkina

Dans cette classe d'altitude, les pentes sont souvent fortes à très fortes (versant Na Godéa) et les gros cablis nombreux : ceci explique sans doute en partie le peu de gros

L'élaéiculture au Cameroun est soutenue par un important programme de recherche concer- nant: - la pédologie (recherche de sols favorables au palmier, étude de

Mais avant d’en arriver là, nous voudrions poursuivre la clarification de l’activité de diagnostic agronomique. D’une façon générale, cette activité comprend