• Aucun résultat trouvé

Law versus Regulation: A Political Economy Model of Instrument Choice in Environmental Policy

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "Law versus Regulation: A Political Economy Model of Instrument Choice in Environmental Policy"

Copied!
41
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

Forthcoming in A. Heyes, ed., Law and Economics of the Environment, Edward

Elgar Publishing Ltd, 416 pp. (July 2001)

Montréal

Novembre 2000

Série Scientifique

Scientific Series

Law versus Regulation:

A Political Economy Model of

Instrument Choice in

Environmental Policy

Marcel Boyer, Donatella Porrini

(2)

Le CIRANO est un organisme sans but lucratif constitué en vertu de la Loi des compagnies du Québec. Le

financement de son infrastructure et de ses activités de recherche provient des cotisations de ses

organisations-membres, d’une subvention d’infrastructure du ministère de la Recherche, de la Science et de la Technologie, de

même que des subventions et mandats obtenus par ses équipes de recherche.

CIRANO is a private non-profit organization incorporated under the Québec Companies Act. Its infrastructure and

research activities are funded through fees paid by member organizations, an infrastructure grant from the

Ministère de la Recherche, de la Science et de la Technologie, and grants and research mandates obtained by its

research teams.

Les organisations-partenaires / The Partner Organizations

•École des Hautes Études Commerciales

•École Polytechnique

•Université Concordia

•Université de Montréal

•Université du Québec à Montréal

•Université Laval

•Université McGill

•MEQ

•MRST

•Alcan Aluminium Ltée

•AXA Canada

•Banque Nationale du Canada

•Banque Royale du Canada

•Bell Québec

•Bombardier

•Bourse de Montréal

•Développement des ressources humaines Canada (DRHC)

•Fédération des caisses populaires Desjardins de Montréal et de l’Ouest-du-Québec

•Hydro-Québec

•Imasco

•Industrie Canada

•Pratt & Whitney Canada Inc.

•Raymond Chabot Grant Thornton

•Ville de Montréal

© 2000 Marcel Boyer et Donatella Porrini. Tous droits réservés. All rights reserved.

Reproduction partielle permise avec citation du document source, incluant la notice ©.

Short sections may be quoted without explicit permission, provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to

the source.

ISSN 1198-8177

Ce document est publié dans l’intention de rendre accessibles les résultats préliminaires

de la recherche effectuée au CIRANO, afin de susciter des échanges et des suggestions.

Les idées et les opinions émises sont sous l’unique responsabilité des auteurs, et ne

représentent pas nécessairement les positions du CIRANO ou de ses partenaires.

This paper presents preliminary research carried out at CIRANO and aims at

encouraging discussion and comment. The observations and viewpoints expressed are the

sole responsibility of the authors. They do not necessarily represent positions of CIRANO

or its partners.

(3)

Instrument Choice in Environmental Policy

*

Marcel Boyer

, Donatella Porrini

Résumé / Abstract

Nous analysons les conditions sous lesquelles les approches légale et

réglementaire peuvent être comparées dans le cadre d’un modèle d’économie

politique de l’implémentation de la politique environnementale. La première

partie de l’article décrit les caractéristiques essentielles des divers instruments à

comparer, à savoir un régime de responsabilité légale élargie aux prêteurs et un

régime de réglementation incitative, instruments typiquement utilisés aux

États-Unis et en Europe. Dans la deuxième partie, un modèle formel d’économie

politique est développé. La possibilité d’une capture de l’agence de

réglementation est introduite sous forme réduite par la surévaluation de la valeur

sociale de la rente informationnelle des entreprises. Nous montrons qu’un régime

de réglementation incitative peut être plus ou moins performant en termes de

bien-être qu’un régime de responsabilité élargie, stricte et solidaire. Nous

analysons en profondeur trois facteurs principaux de cette comparaison, à savoir

le différentiel de coût entre les niveaux faible et élevé de la protection

environnementale, le coût social des fonds publics et le facteur de surévaluation.

We analyze the conditions under which a legal intervention can be

compared to a regulatory framework in the context of a political economy model

of environmental policy. The first part of the paper describes the characteristics

of the different instruments we want to compare: first, an assignment of legal

liability, focusing on the case of extended lender liability, and second, an

incentive regulation framework. We briefly describe the application of those

instruments in the United States and Europe. In the second part a formal economy

model is presented where the possibility of capture of the regulatory agency is

modeled in a reduced-form fashion through an overvaluation of the social value

of the informational rent of the firms. We show that compared with an extended,

strict, joint and several liability system, a regulatory system may perform better or

worse from a welfare point of view. Three factors underlying this comparison are

discussed in some depth, namely the differential cost between low and high levels

*

Corresponding Author: Marcel Boyer, CIRANO, 2020 University Street, 25

th

floor, Montréal, Qc, Canada

H3A 2A5

Tel.: (514) 985-4002

Fax: (514) 985-4035

email: boyerm@cirano.umontreal.ca

We want to thank Claire Domenget, Patrick González, Yolande Hiriart, Ejan Mackaay and Stephen Shavell for their

comments. Donatella Porrini acknowledges financial support from MURST 1998 Project “Regulation and

Self-Regulation” (Università LIUC, Castellanza, Italy). We remain of course solely responsible for the content of this

article.

Department of Economics, Université de Montréal and CIRANO

(4)

overvaluation factor.

Mots Clés :

Politique environnementale, responsabilité élargie, CERCLA, capture des

régulateurs, instruments

Keywords:

Environmental policy, extended liability, CERCLA, regulatory capture,

instruments

(5)

1 Introduction

Fromalawand economicspointofview,theregulationofenvironmentally riskyactivities isan

alternativetoasystemofliabilityassignment. \Regulationandtortlawarealternativemethods

(though often used in combination) for preventing accidents. The former requires a potential

injurer to take measures to prevent the accident from occurring. The latter seeks to deter the

accidentbymakingthepotentialinjurerliableforthecostsofaccidentshoulditoccur." (Landes

and Posner, 1984, p. 417). We want here to review and characterize, in an incomplete

infor-mation political economy framework, the conditions under which an environmental regulation

approach issuperiorto an environmentalliabilityone.

We develop in this paper a formal analysis of the comparison between di erent policy

in-strumentstoimplementagivensetofenvironmentalprotectionobjectives, 1

includingapolitical

economy explanation of the choice of instruments. 2

The rst instrument we consideris the

as-signment of a CERCLA type liability, 3

that is, a strict, retroactive, joint and several liability

on theowners and operators of the rm responsiblefora catastrophic environmental disaster.

More precisely,wemodelan extended lenderliabilityrulewherebyprivatebanks nancingthe

responsible rm are consideredas liableoperators if the latter is unableto cover the damages

and compensation from its own assets. The second instrument in our comparison consists in

a regulation framework. After the environmental legislation of the 70s in the United States,

the federal government played an extensive role in regulating air pollution, water pollution,

hazardous and solid waste disposal, as wellas pesticideuse, among other environmental risks.

More precisely we consider here an incentive regulation system based on a menu of contracts

and subjectto capturebytheregulated rms.

BoyerandLa ont(1999)arguethattwotypesofmeaningfulcomparisonsofinstrumentsare

possible. Inthe rsttype,oneconsidersexogenousconstraintson instrumentsandthenvarious

constrained instruments can be compared. In the second type, instruments, equivalent in the

completecontractingframework,canbemeaningfullycomparedgivensomeimperfectionsinthe

economyoutsidethecontrolofthesocialorconstitutionalplanner. 4

Theoriginofthisimperfect

(6)

The extended lenderliabilityoption

Thecommonlawtortsystem,administeredbythecourtsandgovernedprincipallybystatelawin

the UnitedStates, provides a mechanism for creating incentivesforcare and forcompensating

victims, property losses and health injuries by a strict liability system. 5

Alongside the tort

system, there exist a systemof privateand public insurancebothfor theliabilityof rmsand

for theconsequences on individuals. In the80s, theUnitedStates Congress enacted CERCLA

andcreatedaSuperfundforthequickande ectivecleanupofdangerouswastesites. 6

Itgavethe

EnvironmentalProtectionAgency(EPA)thepowertobringdamageactionsto recovercleanup

costs againsttheowners andoperators of thefacilitydirectlyresponsibleforreleases.

We want to concentrate here on an important aspect of a liability system that makes all

owners and operators retroactively, strictly, jointly and severally liable, namely the extension

of liabilityto the lenders. In spite of a secured interest exemption clause protecting nancial

institutions holding indicia of ownership on the rm's assets, 7

the United States courts have

repeatedly considered secured lenders as owners or operators under CERCLA,insofar as their

involvement intheoperationsof the rmexceededthelevelwarrantedto securetheirinterest. 8

A lenders'liabilitysystem wasde ned by thecourtsdecisions, forinstance inthefollowing

landmark cases involving the bankruptcy of the primary responsible rm: USA v. Mirabile, 9

USAv. MarylandBank&Trust, 10

USAv. Fleetfactors, 11

andBergsoeMetalv. EastAsiatic. 12

Butthesecasesappearedtoarticulatepotentiallycon ictingrulesofliabilityregardingthetype

and degree of involvement making the lenders jointly liable with the responsible rms. 13

To

clarifythisconfusedsituation,theEPA issuedin1992thesocalledFinal Rule 14

underwhicha

lender would be liableforcleanup costsif itparticipated inthe management of the borrower's

operationsbyexercisingmanagementcontrolovereitherthedaytodayoperationsofthefacility

or over its environmental compliance e orts. In the years following theEPA's nalrule, some

court decisionswere basedonthisstatement. 15

Butinthe1994 caseKelleyv. EPA, 16

theD.C.

CircuitCourtofAppealheldthatCongressinenactingCERCLAdidnotgivetheEPAauthority

to e ect theimpositionof liabilityand therefore invalidatedtheEPA's nalrule. 17

In 1996, theAsset Conservation, Lender Liability, and Deposit Insurance Protection Act 18

(7)

According tothisAct,lendersandsecuredcreditorsmust`participateinthemanagementofthe

facility'tobeheldliableasan`owneroroperator'ofacontaminatedsiteandasecuredcreditor's

simple nancingtransactionsshouldnotimplyajoint,several,retroactiveandstrictliabilityfor

environmentalcontamination. But,whiletheActprovideswelcomedreliefforsecuredcreditors,

it does not completely insulate lenders and duciaries from environmental liability and the

questionremainsregardingwhichprecise stepsmustbetaken to ensurealimitation ofliability

forlenders. 19

Inadditiontothelenderliabilityruledevelopedthroughthejurisprudence,theCERCLA

li-abilitysystemraisesotherissues. First,suingallthepotentiallyresponsiblepartiesortargeting

some `deeppocket'onestorecoverresponse, cleanupcostsanddamages, aswellascoordinating

numerous parties withcon icting interests and nding an agreement on a cost allocation plan

maygeneratevery hightransactioncosts. Second,theinvolvement ofmanypotentially

respon-sible parties impliesthatthe distribution among pollutingparties of the needed compensation

costs cancreate incentiveproblemssuchastheallocationof resourcesto legalstrategies rather

than to accident prevention. 20

Inadditiontothistransactioncostproblem,theCERCLAliabilitysystemwasnotsupported

by a signi cant development inthe insurance market. 21

The main problems are the following.

The standard insurance policies do not t the CERCLA retroactive liability system because

they do not cover claims made before or after the validity period of the insurance contract.

Moreover,becauseboththepremiumandthedeductibleinthepoliciesareextremelyhigh,only

a few insurance companiesin the United States issue them and many lending institutionsopt

forsel nsurance. 22

In Europe, a uni edregime of liability forenvironmental damages is still in themaking. 23

Theproblemofharmonizingdi erentnationallegalregimesfromthestandpointofbothmarket

integration and environmental protection that cuts across traditionaladministrative and legal

boundariesraisesdiÆcultissues. 24

Inthiscontext,theWhite Paper on Environmental Liability

of February 2000 aims at determining who shouldpay forthe cleanup and restoration costs of

theenvironmentaldamageresultingfromhumanacts. Thequestionwhetherthecostsshouldbe

(8)

opted essentially for a strict (no fault)liabilitysystem that is e ective only forfuture damage

wherepolluterscanbeidenti ed,damageisquanti ableanda causalconnection canbeshown.

Given the generalrulethat thepollutermust always be the rst actor a claim is addressed to,

the White Paper nevertheless recommends a form of extended liability rule. It states that the

persons who exercises control (the `operators') of an activity by which the damage is caused

shouldbetheliablepartyandit speci esthatlendersnotexercisingoperationalcontrolshould

not be liable. Furthermore, in the nal part of the White Paper that deals with the overall

economic impact of environmental liability in the European Community, it is stated that the

liabilitysystemgenerally protects economic operatorsin the nancialsectors, unless theyhave

operationalresponsibilities.

TheEC White Paper liabilitysystemwhilesimilarto theUnitedStatessystemdi ersfrom

it on manyimportant aspects. First, both of them arebased on a strict liabilityregime inthe

sense thatliabilitycomesfrom the causallink betweentheactor and thedamage and whether

the actor's behavior wasproperor negligent is irrelevant. Second, whilethe CERCLA system

is applied retroactively, the EC White Paper provides a non-retroactive application. 25

Third,

onlya mitigatedjoint and several liabilityregime isprovidedintheEuropean caseinthesense

that a party isallowed to provide convincing argumentsthat itis onlypartiallyliable. Fourth,

instead of covering every damage including the damage to natural resources, the European

system covers only traditional damages, such as personal injury and damage to property, and

the decontamination of sites. Fifth, the objective of the United States system of recovering

the environmental damage from liableparties is supported also bythecreation of a Superfund

whileno such fundis establishedbythe WhitePaper. Sixth, theset ofactors whocan be held

liableisthesame,namelythe`operators'of the rm,andbothsystemsspecifythatlendersnot

exercisingoperationalcontrolshouldnotbeheldliable,thesocalledsecuredinterestexemption

rule. 26

The regulation option

An alternative instrumentto implement theenvironmental policyisa regulatory systemwhere

(9)

andcontrolprocedureofsettingandimplementingpollutionstandards. Amorerecentapproach

restsonincentivemarketbasedinstruments,asemissiontaxation,marketablepermitsando set

trading. 27

In the command and control approach based on a mandatory technology or abatement

standard,theregulatorsuchtheUnitedStatesEnvironmentalProtectionAgencycan orderthe

rmsto limittheiremissions, toemitno morethanaspeci edamountofa pollutantand/orto

installaparticularabatement technology. Theregulatormonitorsoverthetimethecompliance

of rmswith the standards and emission limitsthrough the conduct of inspections, actions in

federal courtsand negotiated settlementswithpolluters. 28

Theincentivemarketbasedinstrumentsarealternativetoolsthataretypicallybasedonthe

menuofcontractsframeworkoronasystemofmarketablepermits. Thelatteressentiallyworks

in thefollowingway: theregulatorgrantsaplant orpublicutilityanumberofpermitsto emit

a given amount of a pollutant;if thefacilityis able to reduce its emissions, preferablythrough

the useofnewertechnologies, itcan sell itsremaining emissionpermitsto anotherfacilitythat

is unableto meet its quota.

Looking at the United States experience, air pollution control under the federalClean Air

Act (1970-1990) followed in its early stages a command and control approach but with the

increasing knowledge and experimentation of market based solutions switched to markets of

pollution`rights'. GiventhatthemaingoaloftheCleanAirActwastheattainmentofnational

ambient air qualitystandards, the Congressasked the EPA to establish theNational Ambient

Air Quality Standards (NAAQSs) for pervasive air pollutants. Later on, euent taxes and

marketableemissionrightsweretakenintoconsiderationinordertoovercometheshortcomings

of thecommandandcontrolinstrumentsintermsofmonitoring,enforcementcapabilities,their

high levelof administrativecosts.

IntheEC,theEuropeanEnvironmentalAgency(EEA)hasalimitedregulatoryrolefortwo

reasons. First,theEEAexercisesmainlytheroleofprovidingobjective,comparableandreliable

information that member States or the Community at large may use to develop measures to

protect the environment, to evaluate the results of said measures, and to educate the public

(10)

of addressing directly and credible the environmental problems of the Community. Therefore

in every single member State, the regulation follows the national legislation and the choice of

instrumentsis speci c to eachstate.

Liabilityversusregulation

To comparethe two policy instrumentswe can follow alawand economicsapproach analyzing

their impacts interms of socialwelfare. 29

This kind of analysis balances the bene ts from the

risky activitieswith thecostsofprecautionarycare, theexpected levelof damages(probability

and severity),theadministrativeexpensesassociatedwiththese policies,andthenetsocialcost

of theinformational rents.

Astrict liabilitysystemistypicallyappliedto riskscreatedbyabnormallyhazardous

activ-ities and against defendantsforall injuries caused by theirconduct. The victim lesan action

claiming acausallinkbetweenthedefendant's conductand theplainti 'sinjuryordiseaseand

the system relies on a case by case adjudication. Strict liabilityregime has the advantage of

internalizingenvironmentalrisksbothfrom theincentiveand thecompensationpointsof view.

But it has some practical disadvantages: inmany cases the victimsare widely dispersedwith

noneofthemsuÆcientlymotivatedtoinitiatealegalaction,harmmayappearonlyafteralong

delay, speci callyresponsiblepolluters may be diÆcultto identify,determiningthe causallink

maybediÆcult,inconsistentverdictsmayemerge,delaysincourtproceedingsmaybeverylong

and the systemmaybe morepro table forlawyers and experts thanforthe victims.

Ontheotherhand,aregulationsystemistypicallycharacterized bya centralizedstructure.

Its advantages are based on the fact that it is wellsuited to set policies regarding the

de ni-tion and implementationof standards. The centralizedsearch facilities,thecontinualoversight

of problems and a broad array of regulatory tools can make the regulation system capable of

systematically assessing environmental risksand of implementing a comprehensive set of

poli-cies. But,regulatory agencies may be not very exibleinadapting to changingconditionsand

centralized commandstructurerelyingon expertadvicemaybe subjectto politicalpressureas

wellasto collusionand capturebytheregulated rms. 30

(11)

privateknowledgeoftheparties regardingthecausalfactorsofaccidentprobabilityandtherisk

of captureorcollusion.

The cost of a liabilitysystem includes theadministrative expenses incurredbythe private

and the public parties, namely the cost of optimally controlling the probability of accidents,

the legal expenses and the public expenses for maintaining legal institutions. The cost of the

regulatory systemincludesthepublicexpensesformaintainingtheregulatory agenciesand the

privatecosts of compliance. One advantage of the liabilitysystem is that a signi cant part of

the administrative costsisincurredonlyifasuitoccurs. Ontheother handtheadministrative

costs of a regulation system are incurredwhether or notthe harm occurs because the process

of regulationiscostly byitself andtheregulatorneedsto collect informationabouttheparties,

their activitiesand therisks.

A second element of thecomparison refersto whobears thecost of environmental damage.

In aregulation system,thecosts areusuallydirectlyorindirectlycovered bythepublicparties

when duecare wasexercised bythe rmsaccording to thestandards de nedbythe regulatory

agency. Ina liabilityregime, these costsare imposed on theresponsible privateparties, ifand

when a suit occurs, given their capacity to pay and their limited liability. Both systems may

require some form ofcompulsoryinsuranceforthe losses inexcess of theassetsof the rmbut

the liabilitysystem can also rely on an extended liabilityassignment according to which most

or all deep pocket stakeholders (suppliers, partners and nanciers) of the rm may be made

strictly,jointlyand severallyresponsibleforthedamages.

Athirdimportantelementofthecomparisonisthedistributionofknowledgeamongparties

regardingthebene tsofactivities,thecostofreducingrisksandtheprobabilityandtheseverity

of accidents. Sometimes the nature of the activities carried out by the rms is such that the

privatepartieshavebetterknowledgeofthebene tsandcostsofreducingrisks. Insuchacasea

liabilitysystemhastheadvantageofmakingtheprivatepartiesresidualclaimantsofthecontrol

of riskswhilearegulation systemsu ersfrom thelackofinformationleadingto overestimation

orunderestimationofthecostsandbene tsoftherisks(probabilityand/orseverity). Butitmay

also happenthat theregulatorhasbetter knowledgeof those risksbecause ofthe possibilityof

centralizing informationanddecisions,inparticularwhenabetterknowledgeoftheriskfactors

(12)

Afourthrelevantfeatureinthecomparisonisthepossibilityofcaptureandcollusionbetween

the enforcers and the parties. The enforcers may be in uenced by external pressure in both

systems, butone may reasonablyargue that thecourts are less likelyto be capturedthan the

regulating agencies.

On the basis of theses di erences between the two policy instruments, we will present in

the next section a model based on the stylized features of an extended lender liabilitysystem

and ofanincentiveregulationsystemwheretheasymmetricinformationbetweenparties(moral

hazard) andthe possibilityof captureare explicitlypresent.

2 The model

We consider a two period context where a rm can, in each period, invest an amount F to

generate a lowpro t levelof L

withprobabilityora highpro t levelof H

with probability

(1 ), withexpected pro t = L

+(1 ) H

. 32

Thestochastic revenuesare i.i.d. and the

discountrateiszero. The rmcanchooseself-protectionactivitiesethatreducetheprobability

p(e) of a major environmental accident generating damages of d >  H

. Therefore if a major

environmental disaster occurs in period 2, it sends the responsible rm into bankruptcy. We

will assume thatthe self-protectionactivities are exerted in period 1 and that an accident can

happeninperiod 2only, ifitdoesoccur. The self-protectionactivities can be at thehigh level

e h

or at thelow levele `

; we willassume forsimplicity that thecost of the low level e `

is zero

and that the (di erential)cost of the highlevel is . Letp(e h ) =p h and p(e ` ) =p ` . We will assume that  <(p ` p h

)d and therefore it is socially optimal ina rst best sensethat the

rm chooses thehighlevelof self-protectionactivities.

We willassume forsimplicitythatthe rmhasno equityand must borroweach periodthe

fullamountF inorder to remaininbusiness. Weconsidertwo regimes. Inthe rst regime,the

rm interacts witha privatebankerwho istheresidualliablepartyforenvironmentaldamages

caused bythe rm,thatis fordamagesabove theassets ofthe rm. The rmis assumedto be

risk neutral butwith limited liability. The bank is assumed to be a deep pocket private bank

whoselimitedliabilityisirrelevant. Inthesecondregime,the rminteractswitharegulatorwho

(13)

the rmborrows fromtheprivatebank. Under theregulatoryregime,weassume forsimplicity

thatthe rmborrowsfromtheregulator. Clearly,arealregulatordoesnot nancethe rmbutin

hercomplexrelationshipwiththe rm,shewouldworryaboutthe nancialviabilityofthe rm

and also theimpactof nancial contracts onincentivesforself-protectionactivities. Creatinga

direct nancial linkbetweenthe regulatorand the rm isa reducedform representationof the

structural relationshipbetween theregulator,the rmand the nancial markets.

We want to concentrate here on the prevention of environmental accidents and so, the

in-formation structurewe consideris asfollows: althoughtherealizedpro tlevel isobservable by

everyone, thelevelof self-protectionactivities is aprivateinformationof the rmand is

there-fore observable neither bythe regulatornor by thebank. The timingof theinterplaybetween

the principal(eitherthepublicregulatorortheprivatebank) and the rmisasfollows inboth

regimes considered. The principal o ers a nancial contract to the rm making explicit the

payments to be made in each period if the rm is nanced. If the contract is accepted, the

rm invests F and chooses the carelevel e. The pro t levelof the rst periodisthen observed

and a payment is made to the principal according to the nancial contract. In period 2, the

rm is re nancedornot andif re nanced, itinvests F again,thepro t level isobserved and a

catastrophic accident occursornot. Apaymentismadeto theprincipalaccording tothe

nan-cial contract and,if an accident occurs, cleanup costsare distributedaccording to theliability

system inforce.

We willcharacterize and compare three solutions. The benchmark solutionwillcorrespond

to the casewhere abenevolent regulator, notsubject to capture,chooses the nancialcontract

o eredtothe rminordertomaximizeautilitariansocialwelfarefunction. Thesecondsolution

will be obtained when a privatebank, under an extended lender liabilitysystem, chooses and

o ers a nancial contract that maximizes its own expected pro t functionin which the

infor-mational rent ofthe rmis notpresent. Thethirdsolutionwillbe obtainedwhen thecaptured

regulator chooses the nancial contract o ered to the rm. In so doing, she maximizes a

dis-tortedsocialwelfarefunctioninwhichtheinformationalrentofthe rmwillbeovervalued. Ina

sense, therearethree possibleprincipalsinthiscontext: thebenevolent regulator,thecaptured

(14)

3 Moral hazard in environmental protection

Clearly, the asymmetric information structure and the limited liabilityof the rm makes the

internalizationofexternalitiesadiÆcultproblem. Ifamajorenvironmentaldisasteroccurs,the

rm willbe `judgment-proof' for damages above its value, that is here, its pro t level. Under

limited liability,moralhazard variablescannotbecostlesslycontrolledbyimposingappropriate

penaltiesontheriskneutral rmandthelatterwillingeneralbeabletocaptureaninformational

rent. Accident-preventingactivities bythe rmmustthenbeinducedbyhigherrewardsrather

than sti penaltiessincethelimitedliabilityconstraintimposes a limitonthose penalties.

Given thatthepro t levelisobserved byallparties,theprincipalis ableto o era nancial

contract wheretherepaymentlevelisafunctionofthepro tlevel. Butbecausethelevelof

self-protectionactivitiesisnotobserved,therepaymentlevelmustbeindependentofthoseactivities.

So wewillassume thatthe nancial contract stipulatesthatin period t, theprincipalwilllend

theamountF andaskforrepaymentlevelsofR t L ifrealizedpro tis L andR t H ifrealizedpro t is  H

. A nancial contract is therefore a 4-tuple of repayments forloans of F in each period:

(R 1 L ;R 1 H ;R 2 L ;R 2 H

). The objective function of theprincipal will depend on the setting, that is,

on whether theprincipalis abenevolentregulator, acaptured regulatororaprivatebank,and

whether the principal haspriorityor not over the rm's pro t in case of bankruptcy. We will

assume here that if an accident occurs, the rm must pay for the damages at least up to the

maximalamount madepossiblebyitslimitedliability. Sinced> H

,itmeansthatallits pro t

willbe taken awayifan accident occursandno payment isthen madeto theprincipal.

Under ourassumptions, the fullinformation rst best allocationentails clearlya high level

of self-protectionactivities e h

and aloan/investment F in bothperiodsi

2 2F p h

d  0; (1)

aconditionwhichissatis edifwehaveabenevolentregulatororacapturedregulator. Thetwo

regulators di er by their treatment of the rm's informational rent but since the rent is zero

under full information, this di erential treatment has no impact. In the absence of extended

lender liability,theprivatebanklendsineach periodi

(15)

leading to overinvestment because of the partial, rather than full, internalization of the

exter-nality. With the extended liabilityof the deep pocket private bank, the full information rst

bestallocationis alsoachieved at theNashequilibriumof thegameplayedbythe rmand the

bank. The bank'sliabilityinducesit to fullyinternalizethe externalityand being riskneutral,

it prefers the optimal level of e ort e h

. Hence, one may suggest that a possible solution to

thefullinternalizationoftheexternalitycreatedbyenvironmentalaccidentsisto makethe

pri-vate bank responsiblefordamages if thejudgment-proof rm it nances causesa catastrophic

environmentalaccident. 33

But when the principal, whether it is the benevolent regulator, the captured regulator or

the privatebank,su ers from agency problemsin its relationshipwiththe rm,thepossibility

of achieving the rst best must be quali ed. As mentioned before, we consider in this paper

that the rm's pro t is observable by the regulators and the private bank but that they all

face a moral hazard problem regarding the level of the rm's accident preventing activities.

We will characterize rst the social optimum to be used as a benchmark. This benchmark

corresponds to the case of the benevolent regulator who maximizes the proper social welfare

functionbutinsodoingmusttake intoaccounttheprivateinformationofthe rmregardingits

self-protectionactivities. Next,wewillcharacterizetheNashequilibriumobtainedforthegame

involving the rm and the privatebank under the extended lender liabilityregime. Then, we

willcharacterizethesolutionobtainedwhen theregulatoris captured. Finally,wewillcompare

the three solutions and derive some propositions on therelative socialeÆciency of the regime

of incentive regulationimplementedbya capturedregulatorand theregime of extendedlender

liability.

The socialoptimumundermoral hazard.

Because of asymmetric information, thefull information rst best allocation is not achievable

anymore. Theproperbenchmarkforouranalysisisthesocialoptimumundermoralhazard

be-causeeventhebenevolentregulatorwhoseobjectiveistomaximizesocialwelfaremusttakeinto

account the agency costs. We willassume thatthe socialwelfare function(SWF) is utilitarian

and that there is a socialcost of publicfunds(1+) comingfrom distortionsdue to taxation:

(16)

rm to the benevolent regulator acting here as a nancier together with the cost F invested

by the benevolent regulator will enter the social welfare function with a weight of (1+), in

the rstcase becausethey allowa reductionintaxation and inthesecondcase because the

in-vestment F mustbe nanced throughtaxation, directlyorindirectly. We willassumealso that

the expected damage of an accident enters thesocial welfare functionwith a weight of (1+)

becausethegovernmentwillhavetocoverthatcostinonewayoranotherand nanceitthrough

taxation. Giventhat the rm's netutility(rent)is notobservable by thebenevolent regulator,

and therefore nottaxable, thisnetutilityenters thesocialwelfarefunction witha weight of 1.

It willtherefore be eÆcient that the benevolent regulator recuperates any observable pro t of

the rm. 35

The rm willbe left with its unobservable informational rent which will thenhave

a weight of 1 in the social welfare function. The socially optimal program of the benevolent

regulator willtherefore minimize the rent left to the rm because of its smaller weight in the

social welfare function. The existence of a social cost of public funds is an important and

re-alistic feature ofregulatory frameworks. It makes incomedistribution relevant, althoughin an

unusualsense, forenvironmentalprotection. Werethat cost equalto zero, theregulator would

not care whetherthe rmmakes monopoly pro ts orcapturesigni cant informationalrentsas

long astheeÆcient productionlevelisrealized. Theexistence ofapositive togetherwiththe

assumption of a regulator acting as nancier will allow us to develop a tractable yet realistic

modelof instrumentchoice inenvironmental protectionpolicy.

The social optimum under moral hazard maximizes the expected social welfare under the

incentive compatibility, limited liabilityand individual rationality constraints of the privately

informed rm. The rmwillchooseahighlevelofself-protectionactivitiesi it ndspro table

to incurthedi erentialcost  ,thatis, i its expected netutilityinthe islarger withe=e h than withe=e ` ,thatis i : (1 p h )[ (R 2 L +(1 )R 2 H )]  (1 p ` )[ (R 2 L +(1 )R 2 H )]

whichcan be rewrittenas

  R 2 L (1 )R 2 H   p ` p h ; (3)

which is the incentive compatibility constraint to be satis ed if the principal wants to induce

(17)

repay-ment levels notexceedthe corresponding pro t levels. Finally,the rm'sindividualrationality

constraint is that its net utility be non negative (assuming an exogenous utilitynormalized at

zero). The rm's expected net utility is 0 under e = e `

and given by its informational rent

undere=e h :  R 1 L (1 )R 1 H  +(1 p h )  R 2 L (1 )R 2 H  . Distortionscreated

by the presence of moral hazard will occur only when the combination of the limited liability

constraintsandtheincentivecompatibilityconstraint(3)requiretogiveupa(costly)renttothe

rm. The existence of a socialcost of public fundsrequires that R 1 L = L , R 1 H = H and that

(3) be satis edwithastrict equality: because>0,itissociallybetter to usethepro tofthe

rm to reduce the generaldistortionary taxes. Therefore, the netutilitylevelor informational

rent ofthe rm is R  +(1 p h )  p ` p h >0: (4)

Under the socially optimal nancial contract, the benevolent regulator collects an expected

amount of  +(1 p h )(R 2 L +(1 )R 2 H ) p h [(d R 2 L )+(1 )(d R 2 H )] 2F: (5) Proposition1: If  1+ R+ (p ` p h )d; (6)

thesocialoptimum(thebenevolentregulatorsolution)ischaracterizedbyahighlevelofaccident

preventing activities andan investment F inbothperiodsi

2 2F p h d   1+ R0: (7)

If (6) is notsatis ed, thesocial optimumis characterized bya low levelof accident preventing

activities and an investmentin bothperiodsi

2 2F p `

d0: k (8)

Proof: Let us rst derive the social welfare when e h

is induced. We must solve the following

program Maxf(1+)[R 1 L +(1 )R 1 H +(1 p h )(R 2 L +(1 )R 2 H ) 2F] (1+)p h (d ) +[( R 1 (1 )R 1  )+(1 p h )( R 2 (1 )R 2 )]g 9 > > > > > = > > > > > ; (9)

(18)

subjectto the incentivecompatibilitycondition(3)and theindividualrationalitycondition   R 1 L (1 )R 1 H  +(1 p h )( R 2 L (1 )R 2 H )0: (10)

The solutionentails R 1 L

+(1 )R 1 H

=and (3)satis edwithastrict equalitybecause ofthe

di erent weightsinthe SWF.Accordingly,the socialwelfare(9)can be writtenas

(1+)[ 2F+(1 p h )(  p ` p h ) p h (d )] +[(1 p h )  p ` p h  ]; hence as (1+)[2 2F p h d  ] [(1 p h )  p ` p h  ]; that is, (1+)[2 2F p h d  ] R: (11)

Therefore, investment shouldtake place if (7) issatis ed. If e=e `

, no rent is left to the rm,

the socialwelfarebecomes

(1+)(2 2F p `

d) (12)

and investmentmusttake placeinbothperiodsif(12)ispositive. Comparingthesocialwelfare

levels (11) and (12), we obtainthate=e h mustbe inducedif  1+ R+ (p ` p h )d; (13)

where the right hand side is the incremental value and the left hand side is the incremental

cost, includingthesocialcostof theinformationalrent,of thehighlevelof accident preventing

activities. This completesthe proof. }

Proposition 1 di ersfrom the rst best fullinformation rulebecause of the presence of R,

the rent to be given up to the rm when thebenevolent regulator wantsto induceahigh level

of accident prevention activities. The benevolent regulator cannot avoid giving up that rent

to inducea high levelof accident preventing activities and willtherefore take into account the

net social cost of that rent, namely R. If that cost is large, the benevolent regulator may

prefer, in maximizing the SWF, to induce a low level of care e `

generating a high probability

p `

(19)

investment decision and deciding on the optimal level of care activities, the socialcost of this

rent must be accounted for. Asdecreases, thenet socialcost of the rm's informationalrent

decreases andcondition(13)converges totheconditionfore=e h

under fullinformation. As

increases,thenetsocialcostofgivinguparenttothe rmgoesupandcondition(13)converges

to thecondition,to bederivedbelow,fore=e h

under extendedlenderliabilitysince=(1+)

converges to 1as !1.

The Nash equilibriumwhen the rm faces aprivatebank.

We now considerthecase wherethe rm facesa privatebankerwho isliableforenvironmental

damages caused by the rm when the latter is unable to cover those damages from its assets,

here its pro ts. Clearlyas in the above case of a benevolent regulator actingas nancier, the

privatebank can o er a care-inducing contract to the rm but inso doing will concede a rent

to the rm asexpressed by (3). Otherwise,thebank can capture thewholepro t. The bank's

expected pro tunder acontract inducingahigh levelof careactivities e h is,using(3),  +(1 p h )(  p ` p h ) p h (d ) 2F that is 2 2F p h d (1 p h )  p ` p h ; (14)

whileunder thealternative contract inducingthelowlevelof caree `

,its pro tis

2 2F p `

d: (15)

Proposition2: Underextended lenderliability,theprivatebankinducesahighlevelofaccident

preventing activities less often than thebenevolent regulator does. When the bank decides to

induce e=e h

conceding a rent Rto the rm,it lendsless oftenthan thebenevolent regulator

does. When, inspite of lenderliability,thebank opts to induce thelow level of care activities

e `

leavingno rent to the rm,it lendsasoften asthebenevolent regulatordoesinthatcase. k

Proof: Comparing(14) and (15), theprivatebankopts forinducinge=e h i R+ <(p ` p h )d (16)

(20)

because



1+

R+ <R+ :

Considering (14)and using(4), theprivatebankwilllend withe h

i

2 2F p h

d  R0: (17)

Comparing(17)and(7),obtainedinthecaseofthebenevolentregulator,showsthattheprivate

bank lends less often thanthe benevolent regulator does. Similarly,since (15) and (8) are the

same thentheprivatebanklendsasoftenasthebenevolentregulatordoesinthatcasesinceno

rent isleft to the rmand the bankinternalizescompletelythecost of an accident. }

TheintuitionbehindProposition2 isthatundertheextendedlenderliability,thecostof an

accidentforthebankisthesameasforthebenevolentregulatorandsothecomparisonbetween

thetwosolutionsrestsontheirdi erentevaluationofthe rm'srentwhene=e h

isinduced. For

the bank,thecost of therent is equalto thevalue of therent itself Rwhileforthe benevolent

regulator the net cost is smaller, namely  1+

R, because she considers the socialvalue of that

rent in the SWF. This makes the bank less willing than the benevolent regulator not only to

lend but also to induce a high level of accident preventing activities. Hence this unavoidable

informational rent leads to insuÆcient nancing and too little care activities induced by the

bank. If the bank chooses to induce e = e `

, there is no rent and therefore the bank lends as

often asthebenevolent regulator.

The biasedoptimumwhenthe regulatoriscaptured

If theregulatoris captured,shewillina sensebene tfrom the rm'srentone way oranother,

that is, throughbribes, collusive interests, perks, future employment opportunities and so on.

It willbeasifsheputstoo muchweight (overvaluation) onthe rm's informationalrent inthe

objective function, thatis,asifshe undervaluesthesocialcost of thatrentincomparison with

thebenchmarkcaseofthebenevolentregulator. Thiswillmakethecapturedregulatorlesskeen

to reduce thisrentto its minimum.

We will assume that the rent R of the rm, when e = e h

is induced, enters the captured

regulator's objective function with a weight of K, where 1 < K < (1+). The captured

(21)

is induced, (1+)[ 2F +(1 p h )(  p ` p h ) p h (d )] +KR;

that is,using(3),

(1+)[2 2F p h d  ] (1+ K)R (18) and, when e ` isinduced, (1+)[2 2F p ` d]: (19) We have:

Proposition3: The captured regulator induces a high level of accident preventing activities

more often than the benevolent regulator does. When she induces e = e h

conceding a rent

to the rm, she lends more often than called for, conditionallyon e= e h

, by the second best

optimalinvestmentrule. Whenthecapturedregulatorinducesalowlevelofaccidentpreventing

activities e `

leavingnorentto the rm,shelendsasoftenascalledfor,conditionallyone=e `

,

bythesecond bestoptimalinvestment rule.k

Proof: Comparing(18) and (19), we obtainthatthecaptured regulatorinducese=e h i 1+ K 1+ R+ <(p ` p h )d

whichcompared with(6) showsthat thecapturedregulatorinduces e h

too oftensince

1+ K 1+ R+ <  1+ R+ : When e h

is induced,thecaptured regulator'sobjective function(18) ispositivei

2 2F p h d  1+ K 1+ R0: Since 1+ K 1+ <  1+

, the social cost of the rent is undervalued and therefore, the capture of

the regulator leads to overinvestment, conditionally on e = e h

, in the environmentally risky

activities. When e `

is induced, we observe from (12) and (19) that theinvestment rules of the

captured regulatorand ofthe benevolentregulatorare thesame. }

4 The choice of instruments

LetSWF CR

bethevalueoftheSWF(9)withthesolution,levelofcareactivitiesandinvestment

(22)

valueoftheSWFwiththesolution,levelofcareactivitiesandinvestment rule,implementedby

the private bankunder extended lender liability,as de nedin proposition2. Let usde ne the

correspondences;; asfollows: SWF CR > SWF PB i  2() SWF CR = SWF PB i  2() SWF CR < SWF PB i  2 ():

We now turn to the characterization and illustrationof those correspondences. 36

But rst, let

us recallthemainresult ofour analysissofar.

When e = e `

is induced, the investment rules are the same in the three cases considered,

namely thebenevolent regulator, theprivatebank and thecapturedregulator.

When the benevolent regulatoris the principal,we obtainthat theprobabilitythat e=e h

will be induced is theprobability that  1+ R+ is less than (p ` p h

)d and the probability

that an investment 2F willbe made in the rm is the probability that  1+

R+ is smaller

than2 2F p h

d. Thisisthebenchmarkcasecorrespondingto thesecondbestsolution,that

is, thesocialoptimumunder moralhazard.

Whentheprivatebankistheprincipal,theprobabilitythate=e h

willbeinducedisnowthe

probabilitythatR+ islessthan(p `

p h

)dandtheprobabilitythataninvestment2F willbe

made inthe rm isnowtheprobabilitythatR+ issmallerthan2 2F p h

d. Compared

with thebenchmark case, thissolutionrepresentsalossof socialwelfarebecauseof notenough

incentive forcare,hencetoomanyaccidents,andnot enoughinvestmentintheenvironmentally

risky operations of the rm. The loss in welfare is due to the bank's overvaluation of the net

socialcostoftheinformationalrentcapturedbythe rm,thatistothebank'sfailuretoconsider

the socialvalue of therent.

Whenthecapturedregulatoristheprincipal,wethenobtainthattheprobabilitythate=e h

willbeinducedistheprobabilitythat

1+ K 1+ R+ islessthan(p ` p h

)dandtheprobability

that an investment 2F will be made in the rm is then the probabilitythat

1+ K 1+

R+ is

smallerthan2 2F p h

d. Again,comparedwiththebenchmarkcase,thissolutionrepresentsa

(23)

the rm. Thelossinwelfareisdueto thecaptured regulator'sundervaluationof thenetsocial

costoftheinformationalrentcapturedbythe rm,thatisthecapturedregulator'soverweighing

of thesocialvalue ofthe rent.

Theinvestment rulesinthethree contextsarethesame ife=e `

isinduced. Butthey di er

ife=e h

isinduced. Moreovertheconditionsunderwhiche h

isinduceddi erbetweenthethree

contexts.

 In thebenevolent regulator(BR) solution:

e=e h i  1+ R+ (p ` p h )d;

that is,using(4), i

  (1+)(p ` p h )d 1+ 1 p h p ` p h : (20)

Investment 2F willtake place i

2 2F p h d   1+ R0; that is,i   (1+)(2 2F p h d) 1+ 1 p h p ` p h : (21)

 Intheprivatebank (PB) solution:

e=e h i R+ (p ` p h )d; thatis,i   (p ` p h ) 2 d 1 p h : (22)

Investment 2F willtake place i

2 2F p h d  R0; that is,i   (p ` p h )(2 2F p h d) 1 p : (23)

(24)

 In thecapturedregulator(CR)solution: e=e h i 1+ K 1+ R+ (p ` p h )d; that is,i   (1+)(p ` p h )d K+ (1 p h )(1+ K) p ` p h : (24)

Investment 2F willtake place i

2 2F p h d  1+ K 1+ R0; that is,i   (1+)(2 2F p h d) K+ (1 p h )(1+ K) p ` p h : (25)

Supposethat=0. Inthatcase, theBRimplementsthe rst bestsolutionsince,althoughthe

rm cancaptureaninformationalrent, thatrenthasnosocialcost. SotheBRinducese h since by assumption  < (p ` p h

)d and nances the rm i 2 2F p h

d   0. The PB

solution isindependent of thevalueof . Using(4), weobtainthat thePB inducese h ,leaving a rent R to the rm,i   p ` p h 1 p h (p ` p h )d:

Otherwise, thePBinduces e `

,leavingno rent to the rm. Conditionallyon e=e `

,theprivate

bank lends asoften ascalled forbythe rst bestrulesince there is no rent. The social lossin

welfarein thiscase is thewelfare lossdueto inducinge `

ratherthan e h

. Moreover, even when

the PBprefersto inducee h

,itdoesnotfollowthat it nancesthe rm. In fact, if

 >(2 2F p h d) p ` p h 1 p h ;

the PBwillnot nancethe rm withe=e h

,contraryto the rstbestrule. It maystill nance

the rm with e = e ` . But (2 2F p h d) p ` p h 1 p h > p ` p h 1 p h (p ` p h )d, as in Figure 1 below, i 2 2F p `

(25)

-(=0and 2 2F p ` d>0)  0 A p ` p h 1 p h (p ` p h )d B (2 2F p h d) p ` p h 1 p h C (p ` p h )d D  In A, we have e PB = e h and e BR = e h

, and nancing occurs in both the BR and PB

solutions: no welfarelossin thePBsolution.

 In Band C, we have e PB =e ` and e BR = e h

, and nancingoccurs inboth the BRand

PB solutions: thewelfarelossin thePBsolution corresponds to thehigherthan eÆcient

level ofaccidents.  In D, we have e PB = e ` and e BR = e `

, and nancing occurs in both the BR and PB

solutions, since 2 2F p `

d 0, independentlyof  which is notpaid since e= e `

:

there is nowelfarelossinthePBsolution. 37

If 2 2F p `

d<0, thenwe have thefollowing:

-FIGURE 2 (=0and 2 2F p ` d<0)  0 A 0 p ` p h 1 p h (p ` p h )d B 0 (2 2F p h d) p ` p h 1 p h C 0 (p ` p h )d D 0  In A 0 , we have e PB = e h and e BR = e h

, and nancing occurs in both the BR and PB

solutions: no welfarelossin thePBsolution.

 In B 0 ,we have e PB =e h and e BR =e h

,but nancingoccursonlyintheBRsolution: the

welfarelossinthePB solutioncorrespondsto notrealizing theinvestment.

 In C 0 , we have e PB = e ` and e BR = e h

(26)

 InD 0 ,wehavee PB =e ` ande BR =e `

,and nancingoccursinneithertheBRnorthePB

solutions: no welfarelossin thePBsolution.

Similarly,comparingthesolutionsunderBRandCRforthecase2 2F p ` d>0,weobtain: -FIGURE 3 (=0and 2 2F p ` d>0)  0 E (p ` p h )d G p ` p h 1 p h K(1 p ` ) (p ` p h )d H  In E, we have e CR = e h and e BR = e h

, and nancing occurs in both the BR and CR

solutions: no welfarelossin theCRsolution.

 In G, we have e CR

=e h

, leaving arent to the rm,and e BR

=e `

,leavingno rent to the

rm, and nancing occursin boththe CRand theBRsolutions. The welfareloss inthe

CR solution corresponds to a levelof accidents that is too low (fromthe level of care e h

generatinga rent forthe rm)!

 InH,wehavee CR =e ` ande BR =e `

,and nancinginboththeCRandtheBRsolutions:

no welfarelossintheCRsolution.

Ratherthanproceedwithageneralanalysisofthecaseswith>0,letusconsiderthefollowing

illustrative numericalexample:

 L =5;  H =10; =0:5; F =5; p ` =0:1; p h =0:05; d=20; K=1:2

for which  =7:5and (p `

p h

)d=1. For thiscase, we can graph thefrontiers(20) to (25) as

(27)

-FIGURE4 [2 2F p ` d0]  6 0  1 1 (p ` p h )d (22)(20)(24) (23) (21) (25)  

Conditions (20), (22) and (24) relate to the decisionabout the level of care activities, namely

e BR

=e h

i  is to the left of (20) fora given , that is,i  is below (20) fora given  ,

e PB

=e h

i  is to the left of (22), irrespective of thevalue of , and e CR

=e h

i  is to

the left of (24) for a given , that is,i  is below (24) fora given  . Conditions(21), (23)

and (25) relate to thedecisionaboutthe investment inthe rm,namely BRinvests withe h

i

 isto theleftof (21),PBinvestswith e h

i  isto theleftof (23)and CRinvests withe h

i  is to theleft of (25). Therefore, fortheexampleconsidered, all three principalsinvestif

indeed they decide to induce e h

from the rm. When they inducee `

, they all follow thesame

rule since there is then no rent left to the rm, namely they all invest i 2 2F p `

d  0.

If we assume that this last condition is satis ed, then there will always be investment in the

rm. The di erence between the three solutions comes from the di erent decisions regarding

theinducement ofcareactivities. ConsiderFigure4. Fora situation( ;)to theleftof(22),

(28)

situation( ;)between(22)and (20),e BR =e CR =e h bute PB =e `

,whiletheyall investin

the rm: inthisregion, thecapturedregulatorsolutionispreferredtotheprivatebanksolution.

For a situation ( ;) between (20) and (24), e BR = e PB = e ` but e CR = e h

, while they all

investinthe rm: inthisregion,theprivatebanksolutionispreferredtothecapturedregulator

solution, even if there willbe more accidents in theformer solution. The larger number, more

preciselythehigherprobability,ofaccidentsismore thancompensatedbythefactthatthere is

no (costly) rent left to the rm. Finallyfora situation( ;) above (24), allthree principals

inducee `

and investinthe rm: thethree solutions arethesame. Therefore:

Proposition4: If2 2F p `

d0,that is,ifthe rmis sociallypro table witha lowlevel of

care, thenthe`extendedlenderliability'regimeandthe`regulatorsubjecttocapture'regimeare

equivalentinstrumentsforimplementingtheenvironmentalpolicyifthedi erentialcostbetween

high and low levels of accident prevention activities is relatively smallor relatively large (as a

function ofthesocial costof publicfunds), that is,if

 2() " 0; (p ` p h ) 2 d 1 p h # [ 2 6 4 (1+)(p ` p h )d K+ (1 p h )(1+ K) p ` p h ; 1 3 7 5 [ f (1+)(p ` p h )d 1+ 1 p h p ` p h g:

The `regulator subjectto capture'regime is abetter instrumentifthe di erentialcost between

high and low levels of accident prevention activities is inthe lower intermediate range, thatis,

if  2() 0 B @ (p ` p h ) 2 d 1 p h ; (1+)(p ` p h )d 1+ 1 p h p ` p h 1 C A :

The `extendedlenderliability'regime isabetterinstrumentifthedi erentialcostbetweenhigh

and lowlevels ofaccident prevention activities isinthehigherintermediaterange,that is,if

 2 () 0 B @ (1+)(p ` p h )d 1+ 1 p h p ` p h ; (1+)(p ` p h )d K+ (1 p h )(1+ K) p ` p h 1 C A : k

If investing in the rm is not socially desirableor pro table unless e= e h

is induced, that

is, if2 2F p `

d<0,we obtaina con gurationrepresentedinFigure 5, wherep `

=0:3, for

(29)

-FIGURE5 [2 2F p ` d<0]  6 0  1 5 (p ` p h )d (22) (23) (21) (25) (20) (24) ^  ^ ^ ^ 

We observe the following. Fora situation ( ;) to theleft of (23), all three principalsprefer

to inducee h

and invest inthe rm: the three solutions arethe same. To the right of (23), the

privatebank doesnotinvestanymorebecause  istoo high. Forasituation( ;)between

(23)and(21), e BR =e CR =e h

andbothinvestinthe rm: inthisregion,thecapturedregulator

solutionispreferred totheprivatebanksolution. Totheright of(21), thebenevolentregulator

doesnotinvestanymore. Althoughshewouldprefertoinducee h

[for( ;)between(21)and

(20)],  is too high and therefore the rent to be left to the rm is too costly. Note that as

expected,thenoinvestment triggervalueisdecreasingin: thehigherthesocialcost ofpublic

funds, thefaster the benevolent regulatorstops investing as thedi erentialcost  increases.

Forasituation( ;) between(21)and(25), e CR

=e h

and thecapturedregulatoristheonly

principal still interested in investing in the rm: in this region, the private bank solution is

(30)

cost of the rent left to the rm. In thisregion of parameter space, it is socially better not to

nance the rm. Finallyfora situation ( ;) above (25), noneof thethree principalsinvest

in the rm: the three solutions are the same. We obtain a comparison similarto the case of

proposition4 butwithdi erent boundaries. We have:

Proposition5: If 2 2F p `

d 0, that is, if the rm is socially pro table only with a high

level of care, then the`extended lender liability' regime and the `regulator subject to capture'

regime areequivalent instrumentsforimplementing theenvironmentalpolicy ifthedi erential

cost betweenhighandlowlevels ofaccidentpreventionactivitiesisrelativelysmallorrelatively

large, that is,if

 2 ^ ()   0; (p ` p h )(2 2F p h d) 1 p h  [ 2 6 4 (1+)(2 2F p h d) K+ (1 p h )(1+ K) p ` p h ; 1 3 7 5 [ f (1+)(2 2F p h d) 1+ 1 p h p ` p h g:

The `regulator subjectto capture'regime is abetter instrumentifthe di erentialcost between

high and low levels of accident prevention activities is inthe lower intermediate range, thatis,

if  2 ^ () 0 B @ (p ` p h )(2 2F p h d) 1 p h ; (1+)(2 2F p h d) 1+ 1 p h p ` p h 1 C A :

The `extendedlenderliability'regime isabetterinstrumentifthedi erentialcostbetweenhigh

and lowlevels ofaccident prevention activitiesis inthehigherintermediaterange,that is,if

 2 ^ () 0 B @ (1+)(2 2F p h d) 1+ 1 p h p ` p h ; (1+)(2 2F p h d) K+ (1 p h )(1+ K) p ` p h 1 C A : k

Proposition6: The regionin( ;)-space over whichthecapturedregulatorsolutionis better

thantheextendedlenderliabilitysolutionisindependentofK whiletheregionin( ;)-space

over whichthe captured regulator solutionis worse thanthe extended lender liabilitysolution

(31)

5 Conclusion and policy implications

We analyzedinthispaperasimplemodelallowinga comparisonbetweendi erentinstruments

for implementing an eÆcient environmental protection policy. More precisely,we considered a

moral hazard context in which rms can take preventing actions to reduce the probability of

environmental disasters. Those actions being a private informationof the rm concerned will

giverisetoinformationalrentswhosenetsocialcostispositivebecauseoftheexistenceofasocial

cost of publicfunds. We rst characterized theoptimal rulesa benevolent welfare maximizing

regulator would choose regarding the level of care activities a given rm should be exercising

and the condition for nancing the rm. Those rules di er from the rst best rules because

the maximizationof socialwelfarerequires thatthe regulatorminimizesthe informationalrent

of the rm. We thencompared the benevolent regulatorsolution rulesto those rulesa private

bank would applyunder the extended lenderliabilityof the CERCLA type and to those rules

a captured regulator, overestimating the contribution of the informational rent of the rm to

socialwelfare, wouldchoose.

The comparison of thethree sets of rules led usto identifythe region inthe ( ;)-space

wherethecapturedregulatorrulesandtheCERCLA-liableprivatebankrulesareequivalentto

thebenevolentregulatorrules,theregionwherethecapturedregulatorrulesarebetterinterms

ofsocialwelfareattainedtotheCERCLA-liableprivatebankrules,and nallytheregionwhere

the CERCLA-liable privatebankrulesare better.

Our main results are summarized in proposition 4 for the case where the rm is socially

pro table when thelevelof care ishighorlow and inproposition5forthe casewherethe rm

is sociallypro table onlyifthelevel ofcare ishigh. Ingeneral, thecapturedregulatorsolution

is better if the deterministic characteristic location of the economy in the ( ;)-space falls

in the lower intermediate range, that is if 2 () [or  2 ^

()] and theCERCLA-liable

privatebank solutionis better if the deterministic characteristic location of the economy falls

in thehigherintermediate range,that isif  2 ()[or  2 ^

()]. It is interesting to note

that the former region is independent of the capture parameter K while the latter region is

(32)

boundaryof the regionin ( ;)-space wherethe CERCLA-liable privatebank solutionrules

arebetterthanthecapturedregulator'srules[condition(24)inproposition4andcondition(25)

in proposition5]moves up.

Themainconclusionofthispaperisthereforethatchoosingbetweenaregulationframework

and a legal framework to implementan environmentalprotection policy is notan easy matter.

Butouranalysisprovidessome preliminarystepsindeterminingawaytoanalyzesuchachoice.

So the answer to the question regarding which instrumentsshould be employed by the policy

makers isthatacasebycaseexaminationisrequired. But,someoftheimportantdeterminants

oftherelativeeÆciencywithwhichdi erentpolicyinstrumentsmaximizesocialwelfarefunction

(33)

References

[1] BianchiA.(1994), `TheHarmonizationof Laws on LiabilityforEnvironmentalDamagein

Europe: AnItalian Perspective',Journal of EnvironmentalLaw 6,21-42.

[2] Boyd J. and D. Ingberman (1997), `The Search of Deep Pocket: is "Extended Liability`

Expensive Liability?',Journal ofLaw, Economics, and Organization13,233-258.

[3] Boyer M. (1979), `Les e ets de la reglementation', Canadian Public Policy / Analyze de

Politiques4,469-474.

[4] Boyer M., Lewis T.R. and W.L. Liu (2000), `Setting Standards for Credible Compliance

and LawEnforcement', Canadian Journalof Economics,(forthcoming).

[5] Boyer M. and J.J. La ont (1996), `Environmental Protection, Producer Insolvency and

LenderLiability',inA.Xepapadeas(ed.),EconomicPolicyfortheEnvironmentandNatural

Resources, EdwardElgar, 1-29.

[6] Boyer M. and J.J. La ont (1997), `Environmental Risk and Bank Liability', European

Economic Review41,1427-1459.

[7] BoyerM. andJ.J.La ont(1999), `TowardaPoliticalTheoryoftheEmergence of

Environ-mentalIncentiveRegulation',RandJournalof Economics41, 137-157.

[8] Boyer M.,PorriniD.(2000),`ThePoliticalEconomyofLawversusRegulationin

Environ-mentalPolicy', mimeo,Universite de Montreal andUniversitadiMilano.

[9] BuchananJ.M.andG.Tullock(1975),`Polluters'Pro tsandPoliticalResponse',American

Economic Review65,976-978.

[10] Buchanan J.M. (1969), `External Economies, Corrective Taxes and Market Structure',

AmericanEconomic Review59, 174-177.

(34)

[12] ChaddC.M.,Satinoven T., BergesonL., NeumanR.W.and C.R.Briant (1991),`Avoiding

Liability for Hazardous Waste: RCRA, CERCLA, and Related Corporate Law Issues',

Corporate Practice Series57, Washington DC,Bureauof National A airs.

[13] Chiancone A.and D. Porrini(1998), Lezioni di Analisi Economica del Diritto, IIIed.,

Gi-appichelli.

[14] ColeD.H. andP.Z. Grossman (1999), `Whenis Command-and-ControlEÆcient?

Institu-tions, Technology, and the Competitive EÆciency of Alternative Regulatory Regimes for

EnvironmentalProtection',WisconsinLawReview, 887-938.

[15] CooterR.and T. Ulen (1999),Lawand Economics, IIIed.Addison Wesley.

[16] Cropper M.L. and W.E. Oates (1992), `Environmental Economics: A Survey', Journal of

Economic Literature XXX,1675-740.

[17] DionneG. and S.Spaeter(1998),`EnvironmentalRisks andExtended Liability: TheCase

of GreenTechnologies', mimeo, 

Ecole desHEC (Montreal).

[18] GobertK.andM.Poitevin(1998),`EnvironmentalRisks: ShouldBanksbeLiable?',mimeo,

CIRANO,Universite de Montreal.

[19] Gobert K. (1999), `Responsabilite des creanciers en matiere environnementale', mimeo,

CIRANO.

[20] HahnR.W. (1990),`The Political Economyof EnvironmentalRegulation: Towards a

Uni-fyingApproach', PublicChoice65, 21-47.

[21] Henderson, D.A. (1997), `Congressional Reform of Lender and Fiduciary Liability under

CERCLAand RCRA:Is Fleet FactorsFinallyDead?',Banking LawJournal,210-218.

[22] HeyesA. (1996),`Lender Penalty forEnvironmental Damageand theEquilibriumCost of

Capital',Economica 63, 311-323.

(35)

[24] La ont J.J. (1995), `Regulation, Moral Hazard and Insurance for Environmental Risk',

Journal ofPublicEconomics 58,319-336.

[25] La ont,J.J.andD. Martimort(1999), `SeparationofRegulatorsAgainstCollusive

Behav-ior', RandJournalof Economics30,232-262.

[26] Landes W. and R. Posner (1984), `Tort Law as a Regulatory Regime for Catastrophic

PersonalInjuries', Journalof Legal Studies13,417-434.

[27] LandesW.andR.Posner(1987),TheEconomicStructureofTortLaw,HarvardUniversity

Press, Cambridge, 1987.

[28] Lewis T.R. (1996), `Protecting the Environment when Costs and Bene ts are Privately

Known',RandJournalof Economics27, 819-847.

[29] Menell P.S. (1991), `The Limitations of Legal Institutions for Addressing Environmental

Risks', Journalof Economic Perspectives5,93-113.

[30] Noll R. (1983), `The Political Foundations of Regulatory Policy', Journal of Institutional

and TheoreticalEconomics 139,377-404.

[31] Pitchford R. (1995), `How Liable Should a Lender Be?', American Economic Review 85,

1171-1186.

[32] Poli S.(1999), `ShapingtheEC Regime onLiabilityforEnvironmentalDamage: Progress

orDisillusionment?',EuropeanEnvironmentalLawReview11, 299-309.

[33] Posner R.(1998),Economic Analysis ofLaw, V ed., LittleBrown andCompany.

[34] Segerson K. (1996), `Issues in the Choice of Environmental Instruments', inJ.B. Braden,

H.Folmer,T.S.Ulen(eds), EnvironmentalPolicywithPoliticalandEconomicIntegration,

Brook eld: EdwardElgar.

[35] ShavellS.(1984),`LiabilityforHarmsversusRegulationofSafety',JournalofLegalStudies

(36)

[36] Shavell S. (1987), Economic Analysis of Accident Law, Harvard University Press,

Cam-bridge.

[37] Simons R.P. (1994), `The Consequences of the Overturning of the EPA Lender Liability

Rule', Journalof CommercialLending4, 43-47.

[38] Staton D.S.(1993),`EPA'sFinalRuleonLenderLiability: LendersBeware', TheBusiness

Lawyer49, 163-185.

[39] Strasser K.A. and D. Rodosevich (1993), `Seeing the Forest for the Trees in CERCLA

Liability',YaleJournal onRegulation10, 493-560.

[40] YoheG.W.(1976), `Polluter'sPro tsandPoliticalResponse: DirectControlVersusTaxes:

(37)

NOTES

*.WewanttothankClaireDomenget,PatrickGonzalez,YolandeHiriart,EjanMackaayandStephen

Shavellfortheircomments. Weremainofcoursesolelyresponsibleforthecontentofthisarticle.

1.SeeCropperand Oates(1992), Segerson(1996) and Lewis(1996).

2.SeeBuchanan and Tullock(1975), Yohe (1976), Boyer(1979), Noll(1983), Hahn(1990), La ont

(1995) and Boyer and La ont (1999).

3.CERCLA:ComprehensiveEnvironmentalResponse, Compensationand LiabilityAct1980, 1985,

1996.

4.This is the case in Buchanan's (1969) example of a polluting monopolist when the subsidies

required to correctthemonopolisticbehaviorare notavailable: Pigouvian taxesarethen

dom-inatedbya quota which implementsthe secondbest tax.

5.SeeCalabresi(1970), Landes and Posner (1984, 1987), Shavell(1987), Menell (1991) and Boyer,

Lewisand Liu(2000).

6.TheSuperfundenabledthegovernmenttobeginthecleanupofprioritysitesplacedontheNational

PriorityList(NPL) withmoney generatedprincipallyby taxeson crude oil,corporate income,

petrochemical feedstocks,and motorfuels.

7.`The term \owner or operator" does not include a person, who, without participating in the

management of a vessel or facility, holdsindiciaof ownership primarilyto protect his security

interestinthevesselorfacility' (42USAC., par. 9601, (21), 1988)

8.See Strasser and Rodosevitch (1993), Pitchford (1995), Heyes (1996), Boyer and La ont (1996,

1997), Boyd and Ingberman (1997), Dionne and Spaeter (1998), Gobert and Poitevin (1998)

and Gobert(1999).

9.15,Environmental Law Reports 20,994 (E.D.Pa1985).

10.632 F. Supp. 573 (d. Md. 1986).

11.901 F. 2d1550 (11th Circuit 1990)cert. denied, 498USA 1046 (1991).

12.910 F. 2d668 (9th Circuit1990).

13.SeeChaddetalii(1991).

14.National Oil and Hazardous Substances Pollution Contingency Plan; Lender Liability under

(38)

15.Publicker Indus., Inc. v. USA(In reCuyahoga Equip. Corp.), 980 F. 2d 110, 118-119 (2d Cir.

1992); Kelley ex rel. Mich. Natural Resources Comm'n v. Tisconia, 810 F. Supp. 901, 907

(W.D. Mich. 1993); Ashaland Oil, Inc. v. Sonford Prods. Corp., 810,F. Supp. 1057, 1060 (d.

Minn. 1993), and others.

16.Kelleyv. USEPA,15 F. 3d1100 (DCcircuit1994), cert. denied;American Bankers Assoc. and

Others v. Kelley, 115 S.Ct. 900 (1995).

17.SeeSimons(1994).

18.H11766SubtitleE,xx2501to2505-AssetConservation,LenderLiability,andDepositInsurance

Protection Actof 1996 (HR3610).

19.SeeHenderson(1997).

20.SeeKornhauserand Revesz (1994).

21.SeeStaton (1993).

22.Formore on thisissue,see A. Johnson & Co. v. Aetna Casualty & Sur. Co., 933 F.2d 66 (1st

Cir. 1991); USAFidelity &Guar. Co. v. George W. Whitesides Co.,932 F..2d 1169 (6thCir.

1991).

23.In 1993, the European Commission published the Green Paper on Remedying Environmental

Damage (COM(93)47 nal,Brussels,14may1993,OJ1993 C149/12). It presentedthebroad

concepts on which a liability system could be built and contained a description of the issues

relevant to designing a Community-wide liability system. It led to discussions on the future

EC liabilityregime througha debate aimed at collecting the opinionsof the interested sectors

and parties. It focused on the liability criteria, the de nition of environmental damage, the

right ofnon governmentalorganizationsto bringlegalactions(thelegalstandingdoctrine),the

insurabilityof environmentaldamage, the limitationsof liability,theproblemof reinstatement

of the environment, the possibility of compensation funds nanced by industries. In the same

year, the Commission explored the possibility of joining the 1993 Council of Europe Lugano

Convention, but a decision did not follow because of the intention to issue a speci c White

Paper and a Directive proposal. In November 1997, the Working Paper on Environmental

Liability outlined the key elements of a proposed Directive on environmental liability and in

Références

Documents relatifs

Pour cela, nous utilisons un corpus parallèle entre une langue bien dotée et une autre langue moins bien dotée, pour assigner aux mots du corpus parallèle (appartenant aux

In this work, we showed that established methods from TDA could be used to provide an analysis support for the detailed investiga- tion of high velocity compressible turbulent

Where the authorities of a state party have detained a vessel flying the flag of another State and it is alleged that the detaining State has not complied with the

While ‘rationalist’ aims might have contributed to the EIB’s entrepreneurial promotion of PPPs, this paper argues that there is stronger evidence that norms

To cite this article: Richard Balme &amp; Tang Renwu (2014) Environmental governance in the People’s Republic of China: the political economy of growth, collective action and

A deeper focus on how regulatory concepts “shape the content and structure of human cognition itself” (Carpenter 2010a) also helped connect studies on the politics of regulation

(2003) Reinventing Contract. Murdoch University Electronic Journal of Law, 10. Policy conclusions of the European Consumer Law Group. Institute for Information Law, University

Unite´ de recherche INRIA Lorraine, Technoˆpole de Nancy-Brabois, Campus scientifique, 615 rue de Jardin Botanique, BP 101, 54600 VILLERS LE`S NANCY Unite´ de recherche INRIA