• Aucun résultat trouvé

Utility maximization for Lévy switching models

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Partager "Utility maximization for Lévy switching models"

Copied!
29
0
0

Texte intégral

(1)

HAL Id: hal-01844635

https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01844635

Preprint submitted on 19 Jul 2018

HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- entific research documents, whether they are pub- lished or not. The documents may come from teaching and research institutions in France or abroad, or from public or private research centers.

L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires publics ou privés.

Utility maximization for Lévy switching models

Lioudmila Vostrikova, Yuchao Dong

To cite this version:

Lioudmila Vostrikova, Yuchao Dong. Utility maximization for Lévy switching models. 2018. �hal- 01844635�

(2)

Utility maximization for Lévy switching models

Yuchao Dong

Université d’Angers, Département de Mathématiques,

2, Bd Lavoisier,

49045 Angers Cedex 01, France,

Lioudmila Vostrikova

Université d’Angers, Département de Mathématiques,

2, Bd Lavoisier,

49045 Angers Cedex 01, France,

July 19, 2018

Abstract

This article is devoted to the maximisation of HARA utilities of Lévy switching process on finite time interval via dual method. We give the de- scription of allf-divergence minimal martingale measures in initially enlarged filtration, the expression of their Radon-Nikodym densities involving Hellinger and Kulback-Leibler processes, the expressions of the optimal strategies in pro- gressively enlarged filtration for the maximisation of HARA utilities as well as the values of the corresponding maximal expected utilities. The example of Brownian switching model is presented to give the financial interpretation of the results.

Key words and phrases: Lévy switching models, utility maximisation, dual ap- proach, f-divergence minimal martingale measure, optimal strategy

MSC 2010 subject classifications: 60G07, 60G51, 91B24

1 Introduction

Regime switching processes are the processes whose parameters depend on some Markov process, taking a finite number of values. Those processes have been ap- plied successfully since more than 20 years to model the behaviour of economic time series and financial time series. Hamilton and al. in [18] considered regime switch- ing autoregressive conditional heteroskedastic models and proposed a way for their calibration. Cai in [1] considered regime switching ARCH models. So and al. in [28]

considered the so-called Markov switching volatility models to capture the changing of the behaviour of the volatility due to the economic factors.

Lévy switching processes was widely used for pricing due to their flexibility to reflect the real data and their comodity as mathematical tool. For two state variance

(3)

gamma model, Komkov and Madan in [26] have developed a method based on fast Fourier Transform to price the vanila options. Later, using the implementation of numerical methods of resolving PDE equations, Chordakis [8] has priced the exotic contracts, like barrier, Bermuda and American options. Then, Elliott and Osakwa in [9] used multi-state pure jump processes to price vanila derivatives. Later, Elliott and al. [10] considered Heston Markov switching model to price variance swap and volatility swap with probabilistic and PDE approaches. Hainaut [19]

gave an overview of the tools related to Lévy switching models, like moments and the conditions under which such processes are martingales, the measure transform preserving Lévy switching structure, and also the questions of option pricing and calibration.

The question of the optimal hedging in discrete time methodology that minimizes the expected value of given penalty function of the hedging error with general regime- switching framework was studied by So and al. [28]. Francois and al. [14] considered the question of the portfolio optimisation in affine models with Markov switching.

Escobar and al. [11] derive the optimal investment strategies for the expected utility maximization of terminal wealth.

The utility maximization problem of the Lévy switching models can be solved by the so-called dual method. The dual method for utility maximization has been deeply studied by Goll and Ruschendorf in [16] in general semi-martingale setting.

This method permits to find a semi-explicit NA conditions as well as a semi-explicit expression of the optimal (asymptotically optimal) strategies for utility maximiza- tion. This method was applied for pricing and hedging of exponential Lévy mod- els in Miyahara [27], Fujiwara and Myahara [15], Chouli and al. [6], [7], Essche and Schweizer[12], Hubalek and Sgarra [20], Jeanblanc and al.[24], Cawston and Vostrikova [3], [4]. This method was also efficient to determine the indifference prices in Ellanskaya and Vostrikova [13], Vostrikova [29]. Then, in Cawston and Vostrikova [5] the problem of utility maximization was solved for change-point ex- ponential Lévy models. The Lévy switching models are natural generalisations of change-point exponential Lévy models, permitting multiple changes of the behaviour of Lévy processes on the observed interval of time.

This article is devoted to the utility maximisation problem for Lévy switch- ing models. More precisely, we consider N independent Lévy processes X(j) = (Xt(j))0≤t≤T, j = 1,2, ..., N, on the interval [0, T], with values in Rd and starting from 0, which are defined on a probability space (Ω1,G, P1) with the natural fil- tration G = (Gt)0≤t≤T satisfying usual conditions. Each Lévy process X(j) has the characteristic triplet denoted by (b(j), c(j), ν(j))whereb(j) is the drift parameter, c(j) is the quadratic variation of its continuous martingale part andν(j) is Lévy measure which verifies the usual condition

Z

Rd

(kxk2∧1)ν(j)(dx)<∞ where k · k is euclidean norm in Rd.

(4)

As known, the law ofX(j) is entirely characterized by the characteristic function ϕ(j)t of Xt(j) with t >0, which is, forλ ∈Rd, given by

ϕ(j)t (λ) = exp{tψ(j)(λ)}

where ψ(j) is the characteristic exponent of X(j). We recall that ψ(j) is determined by the Lévy-Khinchin formula, namely

ψ(j)(λ) =ihλ, b(j)i − 1

2hλ, c(j)λi+ Z

Rd

eihλ,xi−1−ihλ, xiI{kxk≤1}

ν(j)(dx) where I(·) denotes the indicator function.

Let also α = (αt)0≤t≤T be a homogeneous Markov process with the values in the set {1,2,3, ..., N}, given on the probability space (Ω2,H, P2) with the natural filtration H= (Ht)t≥0 such that H0 = {∅,Ω}, which is independent from the Lévy processes X(1), X(2), ..., X(N).

Then on the product space (Ω,F,P) = (Ω1×Ω2,G × H, P1×P2)we can define two filtrations. One is the progressively enlarged filtration F= (Ft)0≤t≤T where for t < T

Ft=\

s>t

Gs⊗ Hs and FT =GT ⊗ HT

and the second one is the initially enlarged filtrationFˆ = ( ˆFt)0≤t≤T defined fort < T as

t=\

s>t

Gs⊗ HT and FˆT =GT ⊗ HT.

For technical reasons we will work in the initially enlarged filtration, and surprisingly at the first glance, we will obtain the results in progressively enlarged filtration for minimal martingale measures and the optimal strategies for utility maximisation.

Such phenomenon can be explained by the fact that firstly both filtrations coincide at the time T, and secondly, by the fact that the Lévy processes X(j), j = 1,· · ·N, remain independent from the Markov processα under any minimal martingale mea- sure.

On the defined above product space, we now introduce a Lévy switching process X such that the increments of this process coincide with the increments of X(j) when the process α states in the statej:

dXt=

N

X

j=1

dXt(j)It−=j} (1) or

Xt =

N

X

j=1

Z t 0

Is−=j}dXs(j).

(5)

More explicitly, if, for example, at t = 0, α0 =i0 and τ1 is the first time of change from the state i0 to another state i1 and τk = inf{t > τk−1t 6= ik−1} for k ≥ 1, then

Xt=

















Xt(i0), for t ≤τ1,

Xτ(i10)+Xt(i1)−Xτ(i11), for τ1 < t≤τ2, ...

Xτ(inn−1)+Xt(in)−Xτ(inn), forτn < t≤τn+1, ....

The characteristic function of X can be find easily since X is a process with, con- ditionally to α, independent increment. Due to the mutual independence of Lévy processes and α, we have

EP[exp(ihλ, Xti)] =EP[EP[exp(ihλ, Xti)|α]]

=EP[EP[exp(ihλ,

N

X

j=1

Z t 0

Is−=j}dXs(j)i)|α]]

=EP[

N

Y

j=1

EP[exp(ihλ, Z t

0

Is−=j}dXs(j)i)|α]].

We remark that for any real-valued deterministic function q = (qs)s≥0 such that Rt

0 qsdXs(j) exists, the characteristic function verifies EP[exp(ihλ,

Z t 0

qsdXs(j)i)] = exp(ihλ, b(j)i Z t

0

qsds− 1

2hλ, c(j)λi Z t

0

q2sds+

Z t 0

Z

Rd

eihλqs,xi−1−ihλqs, xiI{kxk≤1}

ν(j)(ds, dx).

If qs=Is−=j} for s ≥0, then q2s =qs and if Is−=j} = 1 then Z

Rd

eihλqs,xi−1−ihλqs, xiI{kxk≤1}

ν(j)(dx) = Z

Rd

eihλ,xi−1−ihλ, xiI{kxk≤1}

ν(j)(dx).

In addition, if Is−=j} = 0 then this integral is equal to 0. Finally, EP[exp(ihλ, Xti)] =EP[exp(

N

X

j=1

ψ(j)(λ) Z t

0

Is−=j}ds)].

We will consider the problem of the utility maximization for the process S = (St)t≥0such that the components ofS denoted byS(k),1≤k ≤d, are Doléans-Dade exponentials of the corresponding components of X, denoted by X¯(k), i.e. for all t ≥0

St(k) =S0(k)exp{X¯t(k)− 1

2hX¯(k),cit} Y

0<s≤t

e−∆ ¯Xs(k)(1 + ∆ ¯Xs(k))

(6)

where X¯(k),c is continuous martingale part of X¯(k) and hX¯(k),ci is its predictable quadratic variation.

As utility functions, we consider HARA utilities, which are logarithmic, power and exponential utilities, defined as

u(x) = ln(x) with x >0, u(x) = xp

p with x >0 and p∈(−∞,0)∪(0,1), u(x) = 1−exp(−x) with x∈R.

Let us denote byAa set of self-financing admissible strategies. We recall that an admissible strategy is a predictable processΦ = (η, φ)taking values inRd+1 whereη represents the quantity invested in the non-risky asset B and φ= (φ(1), φ(2), ..., φ(d)) are the quantities invested in the risky assetsS(1), S(2), ..., S(d) respectively such that η is B-integrable and there exists a∈R+ such that fort∈[0, T]

d

X

k=1

Z t 0

φ(k)s dSs(k) ≥ −a.

We say that a strategy φˆ∈ A is u-optimal on[0, T] if

E[u(x0+

d

X

k=1

Z T 0

φˆ(k)s dSs(k))] = sup

φ∈A

E[u(x0 +

d

X

k=1

Z T 0

φ(k)s dSs(k))]

where x >0 is initial capital. A sequence of admissible strategies ( ˆφn)n≥1 is said to be asymptotically u-optimal on [0, T] if

n→∞lim E[u(x0+

d

X

k=1

Z T 0

φˆ(k),ns dSs(k))] = sup

φ∈A

E[u(x0+

d

X

k=1

Z T 0

φ(k)s dSs(k))].

The article is organized in the following way. In Section 2 we give a short description of the known results on dual method for the utility maximisation of Lévy processes (see Propositions 2 and 3). In Section 3 we summarize the useful information on Hellinger and Kulback-Leibler processes (see Proposition 4). In Section 4 we give a description of all f-divergence minimal martingale measures for HARA utilities in progressively enlarged filtration (see Propositions 5,6 and Theorem 1). Then, in Propositions 7, 8, 9 of Section 5 we give the expressions for the optimal strategies in progressively enlarged filtration and we calculate the value of the maximal expected utility. In section 6 we apply our results to Brownian switching model and we give the financial interpretation of our results.

(7)

2 Dual approach for utility maximisation of expo- nential Lévy models

The idea of this method is to replace the problem of utility maximization by the prob- lem of minimization of the correspondingf-divergence over the set of all, equivalent to the law PT of the process X, martingale measures QT where T is time horizon.

The function f is nothing else as the dual function of u, which can be obtained by Fenchel-Legendre transform :

f(y) = sup

x∈R

(u(x)−xy) Simple calculations show that

f(x) =−ln(x)−1, x >0 if u is logarithmic, f(x) =−p−1

p xp−1p , x > 0if u is power,

f(x) = 1−x+xln(x), x >0 if u is exponential.

We recall that for two equivalent measuresQT and PT thef-divergence ofQT w.r.t.

PT is defined as

f(QT|PT) =EP

f

dQT

dPT

.

We mention now some useful definitions and results on the f-divergence prob- lem and optimal investment problem in exponential Lévy models. For that, we take a Lévy process L = (Lt)0≤t≤T with the values in Rd, given on probability space (Ω,F, P) with the filtration F satisfying usual properties. We denote the charac- teristic triplet of the process L by (bL, cL, νL) wherebL is drift parameter, cL is the predictable variation of the continuous martingale part ofL, andνLis Lévy measure.

We denote byP the law ofLand we suppose that Lis integrable, i.e. EP(|Lt|)<∞ for t∈[0, T].

Definition 1. We say that QT is an f-divergence minimal equivalent martingale measure for Lévy process L= (Lt)0≤t≤T if

1. the measure QT is equivalent to PT, i.e. QT ∼PT, 2. the process L is a martingale w.r.t. (F,QT), 3. f(QT|PT)<+∞ and

f(QT|PT) = inf

QT∈Mf(QT|PT)

where M is the set of all equivalent martingale measures QT.

(8)

Definition 2. We say that an f-divergence minimal martingale measure QT is in- variant under scaling if for all x∈R+,

f(xQT|PT) = inf

QT∈Mf(xQT|PT)

Definition 3. We say that anf-divergence minimal martingale measureQT is time horizon invariant if for all t ∈]0, T]

f(Qt|Pt) = inf

Qt∈Mf(Qt|Pt)

Definition 4. We say that an f-divergence minimal martingale measure QT pre- serves the Lévy property if L remains a Lévy process under QT.

Proposition 1. (cf. [3],[4]) LetLbe an integrable Lévy process,f be one of the three dual functions above and QT the corresponding f-divergence minimal martingale measure. Then this measure is time horizon invariant, it is invariant under scaling and it preserves Lévy property of the process L.

From Girsanov theorem (see [23], Ch. 3, Theorem 3.24, p.159) we can also easily get the following.

Proposition 2. The Radon-Nikodym process Z = (Zt)0≤t≤T of the measure QT w.r.t. PT verify:

Zt = dQt dPt

=Z0E(m)t

where E(·) is Doléans-Dade exponential and m = (mt)0≤t≤T is a martingale with mt =

Z t 0

βdYsc + Z t

0

Z

Rd

(Y(x)−1)(µL−νL)(ds, dx)

where µL and νL are jump measure of the process L and its compensator under (P,F). The so-called Girsanov parameters (β, Y) for the change of the measure PT into QT are independent of (ω, t). Moreover, the drift bQL of the processL under QT is:

bQL =bL+cLβ+ Z

Rd

x·(Y(x)−1)νL(dx)

Proposition 3. (cf.[16],[3]) Let ZT be Radon-Nikodym derivative of f-divergence minimal martingale measure QT with respect to PT. Let x0 >0be the initial capital.

We suppose that for λ0 >0 such that

−EP(ZT f0ZT)) =x0 (2) we have

EP(|f(λ0ZT)|)<∞, EP(ZT |f0ZT)|)<∞.

(9)

Then there exists an optimal (respectively asymptotically optimal) strategy φˆ such that

−f0ZT) =x0+

d

X

k=1

Z T 0

φˆ(k)s dSs(k) where (R·

0φˆ(k)s dSs(k)) are QT-martingales, 1≤k ≤d. If we choose φˆ0t such that Btφˆ0t =x0+

d

X

k=1

Z t 0

φˆ(k)s dSs(k)

d

X

k=1

φˆ(k)t St(k)

then the strategy Φ = ( ˆφ0,φˆ(1),· · · ,φˆ(d)) is self-financing and it is optimal for loga- rithmic and power utility and asymptotically optimal for exponential utility. More- over, the maximal expected utility

UT(x0) = EP[u(−f0ZT))].

3 Hellinger integrals, Kulback-Leibler informations and the corresponding processes

We recall here some useful results on Hellinger integrals and Kulback-Leibler in- formations and corresponding processes. As known, these notions was introduced in semi-martingale setting and one can find the details about these processes in [23], [25]. For convenience of the readers we will restrict ourself to the case of the processes with independent increments.

Let V be the process with independent increments which is a semi-martingale without predictable jumps, observed on the interval [0, T]. We denote the triplet of the semi-martingale characteristics by (B, C, ν) where B stands for the drift part, C is the predictable variation of the continuous martingale part, and ν is the compensator of the jumps of the process V. We denote PT the law of V which is entirely defined by the triplet (B, C, ν) (see for the details [23], Ch.2, p.114).

Let QT ≪ PT and ZT = dQdPT

T with the Girsanov parameters (β, Y). We recall that the Hellinger integral of order γ ∈]0,1[ of the measure QT w.r.t. the measure PT

H(γ)(QT |PT) =EP[ZTγ]

and this definition can be extended for γ < 0 when the integral exists. We define the Hellinger process H(γ) = (Ht(γ))0≤t≤T of the order γ via the expression

Ht(γ) = 1

2γ(1−γ) Z t

0

βsdCsβs− Z t

0

Z

Rd

[Ysγ(x)−γYs(x)−1 +γ]ν(ds, dx) The Kulback-Leibler information of the measureQT w.r.t. the measurePT is defined as

K(QT |PT) = EP[ZT ln(ZT)]

(10)

The Kulback-Leibler process K = (Kt)0≤t≤T is defined as Kt = 1

2 Z t

0

βsdCsβ+ Z t

0

Z

Rd

[Ys(x) ln(Ys(x))−Ys(x) + 1]ν(ds, dx)

Proposition 4. (see [13]) For the process with independent increments V and Gir- sanov parameters (β, Y) of the change of the measure P into Q, which depend only on (t,x), we have:

H(QT |PT) = exp(−HT(γ)), K(QT |PT) =KT.

4 F-divergence minimal martingale measures

First of all we describe the set of all equivalent martingale measures living on the space of càdlàg functions (D2([0, T]),D2([0, T]))of the trajectories of the couple of the processes (X, α). Let PT denote the law of (X, α) and let PTX and PTα are the laws of X and α respectively, on [0, T]. We denote also by PTX(· |α) the regular conditional law of X given α.

Proposition 5. The law QT ≪PT if and only if there exists a regular conditional law of X, denoted by QXT(· |α) such that QXT(· |α) ≪ PTX(· |α) (PTα-a.s.) and the law of α, denoted QαT, such that QαT ≪PTα. Moreover, PT-a.s.

dQT

dPT

= dQXT(· |α) dPTX(· |α)

dQαT dPTα Proof. For all A, B ∈ D([0, T])

PT(A×B) = Z

B

PTX(A|α=y)dPTα(y) = Z

A×B

dPTX(x|α=y)dPTα(y) and

QT(A×B) = Z

B

QXT(A|α=y)dQαT(y) = Z

A×B

dQXT(x|α=y)dQαT(y) At the same time, the conditionQT ≪PT is equivalent to the existence of a density f(x, y)such that

QT(A×B) = Z

A×B

f(x, y)dPT(x, y) = Z

A×B

f(x, y)dPTX(x|α =y)dPTα(y) In addition, obviously QT ≪PT implies the condition QαT ≪PTα and

QT(A×B) = Z

A×B

dQXT(x|α=y)ξT(α)(y)dPTα(y)

(11)

where ξT(α) = dQdPαTα

T. Since these relations hold for all A, B ∈ D([0, T]) we get that PT-a.s.

dQT

dPT

(x, y) =f(x, y) = dQXT(x|α=y)

dPTX(x|α=y)ξT(α)(y)

Conversely, if QXT(· |α)≪PTX(· |α)(PTα-a.s.) andQαT ≪ PTα, then evidently P(A× B) = 0 implies Q(A×B) = 0. Since the σ-algebra D2([0, T]) can be generated by countable set of the events of the type A×B, it gives the claim.

Let us suppose that the Lévy processes X(j), j = 1,· · · , N, are integrable, i.e.

for t∈[0, T], EP

h|Xt(j)|i

<∞. We denote by M(j) the set of equivalent martingale measures for X(j). Let Q(j) ∈ M(j) and let (β(j), Y(j)) be the Girsanov parameters for the change of the measure P(j) into Q(j).

Let M denote the set of equivalent martingale measures for X such that the Girsanov parameters for the change of the measure P into Qverify the conditions:

Z t

0 |Ys(x)−1|νX(dx)ds <∞ and Z t

0sk2ds <∞,

where νX is the compensator of the measure of jumps of the process X. We put then for all t≥0and x∈Rd

βt =

N

X

j=1

βt(j)It−=j}, (3)

Yt(x) =

N

X

j=1

Yt(j)(x)It−=j}. (4) We introduce also a process m = (mt)0≤t≤T such that

mt = Z t

0

βsdXsc+ Z t

0

Z

Rd

(Ys(x)−1)(µX −νX)(ds, dx) (5) where µX and νX are jump measure of X and its compensator respectively.

Proposition 6. The set M 6= ∅ if and only if for all j = 1,2, ..., N, M(j) 6= ∅. Moreover, if QT ∈ M, the corresponding Girsanov parameters satisfy (3) and (4) and

dQT

dPT

T(α) E(m)T

with m defined by (5) and ξT(α) = dQdPαTα T.

(12)

Proof. Since the Lévy processesX(1), X(2), ..., X(N)are integrable, forj = 1,2, ..., N, we have

Xt(j) =a(j)t+Mt(j), where a(j) =b(j)+R

RdxI{kxk>1}ν(j)(dx)and Mt(j)=√

c(j)Wt(j)+ Z t

0

Z

Rd

x(µ(j)−ν(j))(ds, dx) with the symetric matrix √

c(j) such that (√

c(j))2 = c(j), and µ(j) the measure of jumps of X(j). We recall thatM(j) in this case is a martingale with respect to the filtration G. But, since Lévy processes and the Markov process α are independent, it is also a martingale with respect to the filtration Fˆ (cf. [2]) since the immersion property holds. Moreover, from (1) we get

Xt=

N

X

j=1

a(j) Z t

0

Is−=j}ds+

N

X

j=1

Z t 0

Is−=j}dMs(j)

=At+Mt

It is clear thatM = (Mt)0≤t≤T is a local martingale as a sum of integrals of bounded functions w.r.t. martingales. Since St(k) = E( ¯X(k))t, k = 1,2, ..., d, the martingale measures for S(k) and X¯(k) coincide, and they are the measures which remove the drift A = (At)0≤t≤T of the process X. The canonical decomposition of X in the initially enlarged filtration coincide with the canonical decomposition of X condi- tionally to α, as the maps on Ω1×Ω2. Then the drift of X under Q is equal as a map to the drift of X under QXT(·|α).

Let Z = (Zt)0≤t≤T be the Radon-Nikodym process of an equivalent conditional measure QX(·|α)w.r.t. PX(·|α). It can be always written as

Zt=E(m)t,

where m = (mt)t≥0 is a local martingale of the form (5). According to Girsanov theorem, the drift AQ of the process X under QX(·|α) is equal to:

AQt =At+ Z t

0

csβsds+ Z t

0

Z

Rd

x·(Ys(x)−1)νX(dx, ds)

wherec= (cs)s≥0 is the density w.r.t Lebesgue measure of the quadratic variation of the continuous martingale part ofXandνX is the compensator of the jump measure of X w.r.t. (P,F).ˆ

Let us calculate ct and νX. Since the continuous martingale part Xc of X is equal in law to (PN

j=1

Rt

0 Is−=j}

c(j)dWsj)0≤t≤T with independent standard Brownian motions W(j), the quadratic variation of Xc at t is equal to

Ct =

N

X

j=1

c(j) Z t

0

Is−=j}ds

(13)

and its density w.r.t. Lebesgue measure is ct=

N

X

j=1

c(j)It−=j} (6)

At the same time,

∆Xt= ∆

N

X

j=1

Z t 0

Is−=j}dXs(j)

!

=

N

X

j=1

It−=j}∆Xt(j) and since It−=i} ∩It−=j} = 0 fori6=j,

µX(dt, dx) =

N

X

j=1

It−=j}µ(j)(dt, dx) (7) and

νX(dt, dx) =

N

X

j=1

It−=j}ν(j)(dt, dx) =

N

X

j=1

It−=j}ν(j)(dx)dt. (8) Finally,

AQt =

N

X

j=1

Z t 0

a(j)+c(j)βs(j)+ Z

Rd

x·(Ys(j)(x)−1)ν(j)(dx)

Is−=j}ds.

Thus, X = (Xt)0≤t≤T is a martingale w.r.t. QX(·|α)if and only ifAQt = 0 for all t ≥ 0. We take the derivative in the previous expression to obtain that on the set {αs− =j} we have that

a(j)+c(j)βt(j)+ Z

Rd

x·(Yt(j)(x)−1)ν(j)(dx) = 0.

As a conclusion, on the set {αt− = j} the Girsanov parameters for the change of the measure PX(·|α) into QX(·|α) , denoted (β, Y), are equal to the Girsanov parameters (β(j), Y(j)) of an equivalent martingale measure for X(j). This proves (3) and (4), and we conclude using the Proposition 5.

For allt ∈[0, T] due to the relations (7) and (8) mt=

N

X

j=1

m(j)t (9)

with

m(j)t = Z t

0

Is=j}β(j) q

(c(j))dWs(j) (10)

(14)

+ Z t

0

Z

Rd

Is−=j}(Y(j)(x)−1)(µ(j)−ν(j))(ds, dx).

Let us denote Zt(j) = E(m(j)t ). Now, since the processes X(j), j = 1,2,· · · , N, are independent and cannot jump at the same time with probability 1, we conclude that

Zt =E(m)t = exp{mt− 1

2 < mc >t

Y

0<s≤t

e−∆ms(1 + ∆ms)}

=

N

Y

j=1

E(m(j)t ) =

N

Y

j=1

Zt(j).

(11)

Theorem 1. Suppose M(j) 6= ∅ for all j = 1,2, ..., N. Then for HARA utilities, the minimal martingale measure QT exists and its Radon-Nikodym derivative w.r.t.

P is given by

ZTT(α),∗

N

Y

j=1

ZT(j),∗

where ZT(j),∗ = E(m(j),∗)t with m(j),∗ defined by (10) with replacement of (β(j), Y(j)) by Girsanov parameters (β(j),∗, Y(j),∗) of the minimal martingale measure and ξT(α),∗

is the Radon-Nikodym density of an equivalent to Pα measure which minimise f- divergence. For logarithmic utility ξ(α),∗T = 1, for power utility it is given by the formula (14), and for exponential utility it is defined via (15).

Proof. 1) First of all we prove that for any density ξ(α) EP[f(ZT)] =EP

"

f(ξ(α)T

N

Y

j=1

Zt(j))

#

≥EP

"

f(ξT(α)

N

Y

j=1

Zt(j),∗)

# .

Since the Radon-Nikodym density process Z = (Zt)0≤t≤T of the conditional martin- gale measure QXT(·|α) w.r.t. PTX(·|α) isZt=E(m)t wherem is defined by (10), and P

k=0Ik≤t<τk+1} = 1 for each t >0 and τ0 = 0, we get mT =

X

k=0

Z τk+1∧T τk∧T

βt(jk)dXt(jk),c+ Z

Rd

(Yt(jk)(x)−1)(µ(jk)−ν(jk))(dt, dx)

where (β(jk), Y(jk)) are the Girsanov parameter of the mentioned change of the measure for the Lévy process X(jk). The last formula means that on the set {τk ≤T < τk+1} with fixed k

mT =

k−1

X

m=0

Z τm+1 τm

[βt(jm)dXt(jm),c+ Z

Rd

(Yt(jm)(x)−1)(µ(jm)−ν(jm))(dt, dx)

+ Z T

τk

[βt(jk)dXt(jk),c+ Z

Rd

(Yt(jk)(x)−1)(µ(jk)−ν(jk))(dt, dx)

(15)

and the Radon-Nikodym densityZT of the measureQT w.r.t. the measurePT verifies

ZTT(α)

k−1

Y

m=1

ξτ(jmm)

ξτ(jm−1m)

! ξT(jk) ξτ(jkk)

where (ξ(jm))0≤m≤k, are Radon-Nikodym densities of the mentioned change of the measure for (X(jm))0≤m≤k. We denote the value of ZT on the set {τk ≤ T < τk+1} by ZT(k). Then for any f-divergence corresponding to HARA utility

EP[f(ZT)] =

X

k=0

EP

f(ZT)Ik≤T <τk+1}

=

X

k=0

EP

Ik≤T <τk+1}EP[f(ZT(k))|α]

When we take the conditional expectation w.r.t. α, the random variables ξT(α) and (τm, jm),m≥1, become to be fixed, and the dependence onα will also disappear in all couple (β(jm), Y(jm)) of the Girsanov parameters. Then we take the conditional expectation w.r.t. the processes X(j1),· · ·, X(jk−1):

EP[f(ZT(k))|α] =EP

EP

f(ZT(k))|α, X(j1),· · · , X(jk−1)

Using the scaling property of the f-divergence for Lévy processes together with the fact that conditionally to α, X(j1),· · · , X(jk−1)

ξ(jTk) ξτ(jkk)

=d ξT(j−τk)

k

we can replaceξ(jk) by the corresponding densities forf-divergence minimal martin- gale measuresξ(jk),∗and this procedure will decreasef-divergence. Then, we take the conditional expectation w.r.t. the processes (X(j1),· · · , X(jm−1), X(jm+1),· · ·X(jk)) and use the scaling property of f-divergence and the identity in law saying that conditionally to α, X(j1),· · ·, X(jm−1), X(jm+1),· · ·X(jk)

ξτ(jmm)

ξτ(jm−1m)

=d ξτ(jmm−τ) m−1,

to replace ξ(jm) by ξ(jm,∗). Finally, EP[f(ZT)]≥

X

k=0

EP

"

Ik≤t<τk+1}f ξT(α)

k−1

Y

m=1

ξτ(jmm),∗

ξτ(jm−1m),∗

! ξT(jk),∗

ξτ(jkk),∗

!#

=EP

"

f(ξT(α)

N

Y

j=1

ZT(j),∗)

#

(16)

2) Now we will obtain the expression forξ(α),∗ minimizing eachf-divergence. For logarithmic utility f(x) =−ln(x)−1we get that

EP[f(ZT)] = −EP[ln(ξT(α))]−

N

X

j=1

EP[ln(ZT(j),∗)]−1 By Jensen inequality we deduce that

−EP[ln(ξT(α))]≥ −ln(EPT(α)]) = 0, so the minimum is achieved for ξT(α),∗ = 1.

3) For power utilityu(x) = xpp we put γ = p−1p . Then f(x) =−1γxγ. We write EP[f(ZT)]≥ −1

γEP

"

T(α))γ

N

Y

j=1

(Zt(j),∗)γ

#

=−1 γEP

"

T(α))γ

N

Y

j=1

EP

((Zt(j),∗)γ

α #

since conditionally to α the processes Z(j),∗, j = 1,· · · , N, are independent. Now, let us denote by Q(j),∗T the f-divergence minimal measure of the individual Lévy process X(j), byPT(j) its law underPand byHt(j),∗(γ)the value of the corresponding Hellinger process at t. We recall that due to the homogeneity of the Lévy process X(j) we have

Ht(j),∗(γ) = t

γ(1−γ)

2 hc(j)β(j),∗, β(j),∗i − Z

Rd

((Y(j),∗(x))γ−γY(j),∗(x)−1 +γ)ν(j)(dx)

.

We denote the derivative of the Hellinger process w.r.t. t by h(j),∗(γ), i.e.

h(j),∗(γ) = γ(1−γ)

2 hc(j)β(j),∗, β(j),∗i − Z

Rd

((Y(j),∗(x))γ−γY(j),∗(x)−1 +γ)ν(j)(dx) and we put

Tj(α) = Z T

0

Is−=j}ds (12)

Using Proposition 4 we find that EP[(Zt(j),∗)γ|α] = exp

− Z T

0

Is−=j}dHs(j),∗(γ)

= exp

−Tj(α)h(j),∗(γ)

(13) and that

EP[f(ZT)] = −1 γEP

h(ξT(α))γ exp

−Tj(α)h(j),∗(γ)i

Finally, the Lagrange method for the minimisation of the expectation under the restriction that EPT(α)) = 1, performed in ω by ω way, gives that

ξT(α),∗ =

exp

1 γ−1

PN

j=1Tj(α)h(j),∗(γ) EP

hexp

1 γ−1

PN

j=1Tj(α)h(j),∗(γ)i (14)

(17)

4) For exponential utility u(x) = 1−exp(−x) with f(x) = 1−x+xln(x) we write

EP

"

f(ξT(α)

N

Y

j=1

ZT(j),∗)

#

=EP

h

ξT(α)ln(ξT(α))i +EP

"

ξ(α)T

N

X

j=1

EP

h

ZT(j),∗ln(ZT(j),∗)|αi

#

since EPh

ZT(j),∗|αi

= 1 and since the processes Z(j),∗, conditionally to α, are inde- pendent for j = 1,2,· · ·n. We apply now Proposition 4 to deduce that

EP

h

ZT(j),∗ln(ZT(j),∗)|αi

=Tj(α)KT(j),∗

where KT(j),∗ is the value of the Kulback-Leibler process at T which corresponds to the Lévy process X(j) and defined as

KT(j),∗ =T 1

2 < c(j)β(j),∗, β(j),∗ >+ Z

Rd

[Y(j),∗(x) ln(Y(j),∗(x))−Y(j),∗(x) + 1]ν(j)(dx)

To simplify the notation we denote the derivative intof this Kulback-Leibler process by κ(j),∗, i.e.

κ(j),∗ = 1

2 < c(j)β(j),∗, β(j),∗ >+ Z

Rd

[Y(j),∗(x) ln(Y(j),∗(x))−Y(j),∗(x) + 1]ν(j)(dx) So, finally we have to minimize the expression

EP

h

ξ(α)T ln(ξT(α))i +EP

"

ξT(α)

N

X

j=1

Tj(α)κ(j),∗

#

under the constraint EPT(α)) = 1. Again, using Lagrange method of the minimisa- tion of the integrals and performing the minimisation in ω by ω way, we get that

ξT(α),∗ = exp

−Pn

j=1Tj(α)κ(j),∗

EP

hexp

−PN

j=1Tj(α)κ(j),∗i (15)

this ends the proof of this theorem.

5 Utility maximising strategies for Lévy switching models

In this section we will find the optimal strategies for the utility maximisation. These strategies will be automatically adapted to the progressive filtration, but for the

(18)

technical reason we will search them in the initially enlarged filtration as it was mentioned in the introduction.

To find the optimal strategy we will use Proposition 3 and also the representation of EQ

h

f(λZT) Fˆti

as a sum of the stochastic integrals using the Ito formula. For that we change the measure in the conditional expectation :

EQ

f(λZT)

t

=EP ZT

Ztf(λZT)

t

Since the processX, conditionally to the processα, has independent increments, ZZT t

and Zt are also conditionally to the process α independent for eacht ∈[0, T]. As a conclusion,

EQ

f(λZT)

t

=EP ZT

Ztf(λ xZT Zt)

t x=Zt

Let us introduce the shifted processαt as αt(s) =α(s+t) and let also put

Zt =EP

h ZT

ti

(16) and

Zt(α) = Zt

Z0 (17)

Then, since the processes X(1),· · ·X(N) and α are independent, and the processes X(1),· · ·X(N) are homogeneous in time,

ZT Zt

=d ZT−tt) Finally,

EQ

h

f(λZT) Fˆti

=EP

h

ZT−tt)f(λ x ZT−tt)) Fˆti

x=Zt

Now, we will give the expression for the optimal strategy for each HARA utility and also the corresponding maximal expected utility.

To avoid the complicated notations we will omit ∗ for the Girsanov parameters (β, Y) corresponding to the f-divergence minimal martingale measure. So, for the rest of the paper we put for all t ≥0 and x∈Rd:

βt=

N

X

j=1

βt(j),∗It−=j} (18)

Yt(x) =

N

X

j=1

Yt(j),∗(x)It−=j} (19)

Références

Documents relatifs

In study of the central limit theorem for dependent random variables, the case of martingale difference sequences has played an important role, cf.. Hall and

It’s possible my social circle is just wildly unrepresentative, but among people I know, taking work home to complete in the evening and at weekends is the

We shall thus rather establish Theorem 1.1 by an adaptation of the arguments of Lyons [Lyo97] for proving Biggins’ martingale convergence for branching random walks, using a version

Our objective is to maximize the utility of recommending a list of items to a group of users subject to the diversity of their tastes.. Items with high utility are expected to

We define a minimal model semantics and a notion of minimal entailment for the resulting logic, SHIQ R T, and we show that the inclusions belonging to the rational clo- sure of a

In this paper, we exhibit a new algebra C 0 which is a refinement of C and we prove that having a C 0 -valued model is still a sufficient semantic condition of strongly

To solve the problem (19) and give the expression of the value function in the non compact case, we need to solve the same BSDE with parameters (f , B) and with f always given by

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we introduce our financial market model. In Section 3 we first derive a verification theorem in terms of a FBSDE